Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-m6dg7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T22:44:48.625Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An Empirical Spatial Model of Congressional Campaigns

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2017

Abstract

Testing and estimating formal models of political behavior has not advanced as far as theoretical applications. One of the major literatures in formal theory is the spatial model of electoral competition which has its origins in the work of Black (1948) and Downs (1957). These models are used to make predictions about the policy positions candidates take in order to win elections. A lack of data on these candidate positions, especially challengers who never serve in Congress, has made direct testing of these models on congressional elections difficult.

Recently, researchers have begun to incorporate campaign finance into the standard Downsian model. These models of position-induced contributions examine the tradeoff that candidates make between choosing positions favorable to interest group contributors and positions favorable to voters. A major premise of these models is that interest group contributions are based on the policy positions of candidates. This has been borne out empirically in the case of incumbents, but not challengers.

To test key hypotheses of these models, we develop a simple spatial model of position-induced campaign contributions where the PAC's decision to contribute or abstain from each race is a function of the policy distance between the PAC and the candidates. We use data from political action committee contributions in order to estimate the locations of incumbents, challengers and PACs. Our model reliably estimates the spatial positions as well as correctly predicts nearly 74 percent of the contribution and abstention decisions of the PACs. Conditional upon making a contribution, we correctly predict the contribution in 94 percent of the cases. These results are strong evidence for position-induced campaign contributions. Furthermore, our estimates of candidate positions allow us to address issues of platform convergence between candidates.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Society for Political Methodology 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Austen-Smith, David. 1987. “Interest Groups, Campaign Contributions, and Probabilistic Voting.” Public Choice 53: 123–39.Google Scholar
Banks, Jeffrey and Roderick Kiewiet, D. 1989. “Explaining Patterns of Candidate Competition in Congressional Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 33: 9911015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, David P. 1994. “Electoral Competition with Informed and Uninformed Voters.” American Political Science Review 88: 4357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernt, E. K., Hall, B. H., Hall, R. E., and Hausman, J. A. 1974. “Estimation and Inference in Nonlinear Structural Models.” Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 3–4: 653–66.Google Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1948. The Theory of Committees. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Efron, Bradley. 1979. “Bootstrap Methods: Another Look at the Jackknife.” Annals of Statistics 7: 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enelow, James M., and Hinich, Melvin J. eds. 1990. Advances in the Spatial Theory of Voting. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enelow, James M., and Hinich, Melvin J. 1984. The Spatial Theory of Voting: An Introduction. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hinich, Melvin J., and Munger, Michael C. 1994. Ideology and the Theory of Political Choice. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Londregan, John, and Romer, Thomas. 1993. “Polarization, Incumbency, and the Personal Vote.” In Barnett, William A., Hinich, Melvin J., and Schofield, Norman J. (eds.), Political Economy: Institutions, Competition, and Representation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
McCarty, Nolan, and Rothenberg, Lawrence S. 1996. “Commitment and the Campaign Contribution Contract.” American Journal of Political Science 40: 872904.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morton, Rebecca. 1993. “Incomplete Information and Ideological Explanations of Platform Divergence.” American Political Science Review 87: 382–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morton, Rebecca, and Cameron, Charles. 1992. “Elections and the Theory of Campaign Contributions: A Survey and Critical Analysis.” Economics and Politics 4: 79108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poole, Keith T., and Romer, Thomas. 1985. “Patterns of Political Action Committee Contributions to the 1980 Campaigns for the United States House of Representatives.” Public Choice 47: 63111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poole, Keith T., Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1987. “Revealed Preferences of Political Action Committees.” AEA Papers and Proceedings 77: 298302.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 1985. “A Spatial Model for Legislative Roll Call Analysis.” American Journal of Political Science 29: 357–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 1991. “Patterns of Congressional Voting.” American Journal of Political Science 35: 228–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 1997. Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Sabato, Larry. 1984. PAC Power: Inside the World of Political Action Committees. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Snyder, James. 1992. “Artificial Extremism in Interest Group Ratings.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 27: 319–46.Google Scholar
Wright, John R. 1985. “PACs, Contributions, and Roll Calls: An Organizational Perspective.” American Political Science Review 79: 400414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar