Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T18:52:17.207Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Zero Interest Rate Floor (ZIF) and its Implications for Monetary Policy in Japan

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 March 2020

Douglas Laxton*
Affiliation:
International Monetary Fund

Abstract

This paper uses the IMF's macroeconomic model MULTIMOD to examine the implications of the zero interest rate floor (ZIF) for the design of monetary policy in Japan. Similar to findings in other studies, targeting rates of inflation lower than 2.0 per cent significantly increases the likelihood of the ZIF becoming binding. Systematic monetary policy strategies that respond strongly to stabilise output and inflation, or that incorporate some explicit price-level component, can help to mitigate the implications of the ZIF.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 2004 National Institute of Economic and Social Research

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the International Monetary Fund. The authors would like to thank Charles Collyns, Amadou Dem, Peter Isard, Guy Meredith, Papa N'Diaye and Jonathan Ostry for helpful comments. We are indebted to Susanna Mursula for tireless technical assistance and to Dawn Heaney for preparing the tables and charts.

References

Ando, A. (2000), ‘On the Japanese economy and Japanese national accounts’, NBER Working Paper No. 8033, December.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benhabib, J., Schmitt-Grohé, S. and Uribe, M. (2001), ‘Avoiding liquidity traps’, Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buiter, W.H. and Panigirtzoglou, N. (1999), ‘Liquidity traps: how to avoid them and how to escape them’, paper available at: http://www.nber.org./~wbuiter/public.htm.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clouse, J., Henderson, D., Orphanides, A., Small, D. and Tinsley, P. (2000), ‘Monetary policy when the nominal short-term interest rate is zero’, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Finance and Economic Discussion Series, No. 2000-51, November.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fuhrer, J.C. and Madigan, B.F. (1997), ‘Monetary policy when interest rates are bounded at zero’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 79, November, pp. 573585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hunt, B. and Laxton, D. (2001), ‘The zero interest rate floor (ZIF) and its implications for monetary policy in Japan’, IMF Working Paper 01/186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isard, P. (2000), ‘The role of MULTIMOD in the IMF's policy analysis’, IMF Policy Discussion Paper No. 00/5.Google Scholar
Khan, M.S. and Senhadji, A.S. (2000), ‘Threshold effects in the relationship between inflation and growth’, IMF Working Paper No. 00/110, Washington, International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Kieler, M. (2003), ‘The ECB's inflation objective’, IMF Working Paper No. 03/91, Washington, International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Krugman, P.R. (1998a), ‘Japan's trap’, paper available at: http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www.Google Scholar
Krugman, P.R. (1998b), ‘Further notes on Japan's liquidity trap’, paper available at: http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www.Google Scholar
Laxton, D., Isard, P., Faruqee, H., Prasad, E. and Turtelboom, B. (1998), ‘MULTIMOD Mark III: the core dynamic and steadystate models’, IMF Occasional Paper No. 164.Google Scholar
Laxton, D. and Prasad, E. (1997), ‘Possible effects of European Monetary Union on Switzerland: a case study of policy dilemmas caused by low inflation and the nominal interest rate floor’, IMF Working Paper No. 97/23, and forthcoming in the Journal of Policy Modeling.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laxton, D. and Prasad, E. (2000), ‘International spillovers of macroeconomic shocks: a quantitative exploration’, in Moser, T. and Schips, B. (eds), EMU, Financial Markets and the World Economy, Nowell, MA, Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
Lebow, D. (1993), ‘Monetary policy at near zero interest rates’, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Working Paper/Economic Activity Section, No. 136, July.Google Scholar
McCallum, B.T. (2001), ‘Inflation targeting and the liquidity trap’, NBER Working Paper No. 8225.Google Scholar
Meredith, G. (1999), ‘REPMOD: a smaller sibling for MULTIMOD’, IMF Working Paper No. 99/8, Washington, International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Morck, R. and Nakamura, M. (1999), ‘Japanese corporate governance and macroeconomic problems’, Harvard Institute of Economic Research Discussion Paper No. 1893, February.Google Scholar
Orphanides, A. and Wieland, V. (1999), ‘Efficient monetary policy design near price stability’, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Finance and Economic Discussion Series, No. 1999-67.Google Scholar
Orphanides, A. and Wieland, V. (1998), ‘Price stability and monetary policy effectiveness when nominal interest rates are bounded at zero’, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Finance and Economic Discussion Series, No. 1998-35.Google Scholar
Ramaswamy, R. and Rendu, C. (2000), ‘Japan's stagnant nineties: a vector autoregression retrospective’, IMF Staff Papers, 47, 2, pp. 259277.Google Scholar
Reifschneider, D.L. and Williams, J.C. (1999), ‘Three lessons for monetary policy in a low inflation era’, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Finance and Economic Discussion Series, No. 1999-44, August.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Summers, L.H. (1991), ‘How should long-term monetary policy be determined’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 23, 3, pp. 625631.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, L. (2000), ‘The zero bound in an open economy: a foolproof way of escaping from a liquidity trap’, paper available at: http://www.iies.su.se/leosven/.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, J.B. (1993), ‘Discretion versus policy rules in practice’, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, No. 39, December, pp. 195214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uhlig, H. (2000), ‘Should we be afraid of Friedman's Rule?’, CEPR Working Paper No. 2548, pp. 153.Google Scholar