Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dsjbd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-01T09:16:31.501Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Labour costs and employment policy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 March 2020

Abstract

Under the Government's New Deal proposals to help create jobs for the young unemployed, employers are offered marginal employment subsidies. Such interventions involve relative changes in the firm's fixed and variable labour costs. In turn, cost changes have implications for both employment and hours of work. This study examines possible strengths and weaknesses of employment policies that are designed to price young unemployed into jobs by reducing related labour costs. It focuses on one such intervention, the major restructuring of employers' National Insurance Contributions (NICs) in the 1985 Budget. This is then linked to the New Deal measures.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 1998 National Institute of Economic and Social Research

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We are grateful to Dan Hamermesh, Martin Lunnon, Mike Marland and a referee for useful comments. Helpful information was provided by Adrian Gallop, Neil Millward, Jane Mitchinson, Clive Singleton and Ann White. None of these individuals is responsible for views expressed or for errors and misconceptions.

References

Davis, E.H. and Dilnot, A.W. (1985), ‘The restructuring of National Insurance contributions in the 1985 Budget’, Fiscal Studies, 6, pp. 5160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dicks, G. and Robinson, B. (1985), ‘A Budget for Sterling and a Budget for jobs’, Economic Outlook 1984-1988, London Business School, vol. 9, no. 6.Google Scholar
Ehrenberg, R.G. (1971), Fringe Benefits and Overtime Behavior, Massachusetts: Heath.Google Scholar
Ehrenberg, R.G. and Schumann, P.L. (1982), Longer Hours or More Jobs?, Cornell Studies in Industrial and Labor Relations, no. 22, New York: Cornell University.Google Scholar
European Commission (1994), ‘Growth, competitiveness, employment: the challenges and ways forward into the 21st Century’, White Paper (Office for Official Publications of the European Community: Luxembourg.Google Scholar
Hamermesh, D.S. (1993), Labor Demand, Princeton NJ : Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hansard (1985), Parliamentary Debates (Oral Answers), 77, 982.Google Scholar
Hart, R.A. (1984), The Economics of Non-Wage Labour Costs, London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Hart, R.A. and Kawasaki, S. (1988), ‘Payroll taxes and factor demand’, Research in Labor Economics, 9, pp. 257–85.Google Scholar
Hart, R.A. and Moutos, T. (1994), ‘Tax structure and the choice of compensation system’, European Journal of Political Economy, 10, pp. 765–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawson, N. (1992), The View from No. 11 London : Bantam PressGoogle Scholar
Layard, R. and Nickell, S. (1980), ‘The case for subsidising extra jobs’, Economic Journal, 90, pp. 5173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pissarides, C. (1997), ‘The impact of employment tax cuts on unemployment and wages: the role of unemployment benefits and tax structure’, Centre for Economic Performance, Discussion Paper no. 361.Google Scholar
Whitley, J.D. and Wilson, R.A. (1983), ‘The macroeconomic merits of a marginal employment subsidy’, Economic Journal, 93, pp. 862–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woodbury, S.A. (1983), ‘Substitution between wage and nonwage benefits’, American Economic Review, 73, pp. 166–82.Google Scholar