Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-tf8b9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T06:48:02.090Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

AFTER THE FREEHOLDER: REPUBLICAN AND LIBERAL THEMES IN THE WORKS OF SAMUEL LAING

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 May 2017

JOCELYN PAUL BETTS*
Affiliation:
Centre for Research in the Arts, Social Sciences, and Humanities, University of Cambridge E-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

Samuel Laing was a key figure in propagating both an academically respectable defense of peasant proprietors and a critique of bureaucratic central government in Victorian Britain, his writings cited and argued with by John Stuart Mill, Herbert Spencer, Walter Bagehot, and John Austin (among others). This article corrects misapprehensions that Laing was a libertarian apologist for unfettered commercialism and complacent patriotism. It situates Laing in his argumentative contexts to show him as a critic of conventional political economy who called for a “natural” society of self-governing freeholders like that he observed in Norway, but who gradually became ambivalently caught between a British commercial and aristocratic order and a Continental model of greater property diffusion and strong central government. Laing's story sheds new light on the complex afterlives of republican and civic themes in nineteenth-century Britain, and their interaction with emergent concerns over the dangers to active citizenship of both wage labor in international markets and centralizing bureaucracies.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

My thanks go to Peter Mandler for comments on an earlier draft of this article, to Ruth Abbott for drawing my attention to Wollstonecraft, and to Thomas Hopkins for engaging discussion of Sismondi (and much besides). Any errors of interpretation are, however, entirely my own. The research for this article was supported by funding from the European Research Council under the European Union's Seventh Framework Program (FP7/2007–2013), ERC grant agreement no 295463.

References

1 Porter, Bernard, “‘Monstrous Vandalism’: Capitalism and Philistinism in the Works of Samuel Laing,” Albion 23/2 (Summer 1991), 253–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 Porter, Bernard, “‘Bureau and Barrack’: Early Victorian Attitudes towards the Continent,” Victorian Studies 27/4 (Summer, 1984), 407–33Google Scholar, at 422.

3 Mandler, Peter, The English National Character (New Haven and London, 2006), 47–9Google Scholar; Parry, Jonathan, The Politics of Patriotism (Cambridge, 2006), 61–4CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

4 Porter, Bernard, “Virtue and Vice in the North: The Scandinavian Writings of Samuel Laing,” Scandinavian Journal of History 23/3–4 (1998), 153–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 It is important to note, however, that these misconceptions have not tarred the presentation in Baigent, Elizabeth, “Laing, Samuel (1780–1868),” Oxford Dictionary of National Biography, online edn (Oxford, 2004)Google Scholar, at www.oxforddnb.com/view/article/15891, accessed 22 March 2017.

6 See Price, Richard, British Society 1680–1880 (Cambridge, 1999), 242–4CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Pocock, J. G. A., The Machiavellian Moment (Princeton, 1975)Google Scholar.

7 On the clash of commerce and civic humanism see Fontana, Bianca, “Whigs and Liberals,” in Bellamy, Richard, ed., Victorian Liberalism (London and New York, 1990), 4257Google Scholar, at 45; Pocock, J. G. A., Virtue, Commerce, and History (Cambridge, 1985), 252–3CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Pocock, “Cambridge Paradigms and Scotch Philosophers,” in Istvan Hont and Michael Ignatieff, eds., Wealth and Virtue (Cambridge, 1983), 235–52, at 242–3. On socialism see Claeys, Gregory, Citizens and Saints (Cambridge, 1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Claeys, “The Origins of the Rights of Labour: Republicanism, Commerce, and the Construction of Modern Social Theory in Britain, 1796–1805”, Journal of Modern History 66/2 (June 1994), 249–90. On Coleridge see Morrow, John, Coleridge's Political Thought (Basingstoke and London, 1990)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; though a perspective slightly less Pocockian is given in Edwards, Pamela, The Statesman's Science (New York, 2004)CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed; and taken up in Craig, David, Robert Southey and Romantic Apostasy (Woodbridge, 2007)Google Scholar.

8 See Biagini, Eugenio, ed., Citizenship and Community (Cambridge, 1996)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Biagini, Liberty, Retrenchment and Reform (Cambridge, 1992), 50–60, 84–93, 184–91; Burrow, John, Whigs and Liberals (Oxford, 1988)Google Scholar, chap. 4; Collini, Stefan, “The Idea of ‘Character’ in Victorian Political Thought,” Transactions of the Royal Historical Society 35 (1985), 2950Google Scholar. The final claim is made in Biagini, Eugenio, “Neo-Roman Liberalism: ‘Republican’ Values and British Liberalism, ca. 1860–1875,” History of European Ideas 29/1 (2003), 5572CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Such continuity has also been uncovered in Bell, Duncan, The Idea of Greater Britain (Princeton, 2007)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, as “civic imperialism.”

9 A shift that has been outlined more clearly by historians of America and France than of Britain. See, e.g., Huston, James L., “The American Revolutionaries, the Political Economy of Aristocracy, and the American Concept of the Distribution of Wealth, 1765–1900,” American Historical Review 98/4 (Oct. 1993), 10791105CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Rosanvallon, Pierre, The Society of Equals, trans. Goldhammer, Arthur (Cambridge, MA and London, 2013), 29CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

10 History of the Speculative Society of Edinburgh (Edinburgh, 1845), 24.

11 Laing, Samuel and Fereday, R. P., The Autobiography of Samuel Laing of Papdale (Kirkwall, 2000), 34–5Google Scholar.

12 Macaskill, John, “The Highland Kelp Proprietors and Their Struggle over the Salt and Barilla Duties, 1817–31,” Journal of Scottish Historical Studies 26/1–2 (July 2006), 6082CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Laing and Fereday, Autobiography, 216–28; Samuel Laing, Address to the Electors of Scotland (Edinburgh, 1833).

13 Porter, “Virtue and Vice in the North,” 155–6.

14 Wollstonecraft, Mary, Letters Written during a Short Residence in Sweden, Norway, and Denmark (London, 1796), 75–6Google Scholar.

15 Laing, Samuel, Journal of a Residence in Norway (London, 1836), 480–81Google Scholar.

16 Ibid., 32–3; Sturlason, Snorre and Laing, Samuel, The Heimskringla, ed. Anderson, Rasmus B. (4 vols., London, 1889), 1Google Scholar: 150–52.

17 Laing, Norway, 210–11.

18 Ibid., 10–11, 39–40, 109–10, 137–9, 164–6, 170–71.

19 Ibid., 115–20; 128–30.

20 Ibid., 133–4; 185–6.

21 Ibid., 125.

22 Laing, Samuel, A Tour in Sweden in 1838 (London, 1839), 32Google Scholar, 64–5.

23 Ibid., 102–3, 284.

24 Ibid., 293.

25 Ibid., 291, 296–7.

26 Cf. Porter, “Virtue and Vice in the North.”

27 See Nelson, Eric, The Greek Tradition in Republican Thought (Cambridge, 2004)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Nelson, The Hebrew Republic (Cambridge, MA and London, 2010)Google Scholar, chap. 2; Pocock, Virtue, Commerce, and History; Pocock, The Machiavellian Moment.

28 See Moore, James, “Natural Rights in the Scottish Enlightenment,” in Goldie, Mark and Wokler, Robert, eds., The Cambridge History of Eighteenth-Century Political Thought (Cambridge, 2006), 291316CrossRefGoogle Scholar, 304–7.

29 Tytler, Alexander Fraser, Memoirs of the Life and Writings of the Honourable Henry Home of Kames, 2 vols. (Edinburgh, 1807), 1Google Scholar: 226.

30 Home, Henry, Kames, Lord, Sketches of the History of Man, 4 vols. (Dublin, 1774–5), 4Google Scholar: 210–17.

31 David Lieberman, “The Legal Needs of a Commercial Society,” in Hont and Ignatieff, Wealth and Virtue, 203–34.

32 Smith, Adam, Lectures on Jurisprudence, ed. Meek, R. L., Raphael, D. D., and Stein, P. G. (Oxford, 1978), 49Google Scholar.

33 Book Three has been widely discussed and the account here does not add to the combined analyses of Haakonssen, Knud, The Science of a Legislator (Cambridge, 1981)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, chap. 7; Hont, Istvan, Politics in Commercial Society, ed. Kapossy, Béla and Sonenscher, Michael (Cambridge, MA and London, 2015)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hont, Jealousy of Trade (Cambridge, MA and London, 2010)Google Scholar, chap. 5; Hont, “Adam Smith's History of Law and Government as Political Theory,” in Richard Bourke and Raymond Geuss, eds., Political Judgement (Cambridge, 2009), 131–71; Winch, Donald, Adam Smith's politics (Cambridge, 1978)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, chap. 4.

34 Smith, Adam, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, ed. Cannan, Edwin, 2 vols. (Chicago, 1976), 1Google Scholar: 408.

35 Ibid., Book Three, chap. 2.

36 Ibid., Book Three, chap. 1, quotes at 402.

37 Ibid., 441–2.

38 Ibid., 445.

39 Ibid., Book Three, chap. 3.

40 Ibid., 432–9, quote at 439.

41 Smith, Adam, The Theory of Moral Sentiments, ed. Raphael, D. D. and Macfie, A. L. (Oxford, 1976)Google Scholar, Part Four, chap. 1, section ten. See citation in Hont, Politics in Commercial Society, 92–4.

42 Winch, Donald, Riches and Poverty (Cambridge, 1996), 151–2Google Scholar; Howe, Anthony, “The ‘Manchester school’ and the Landlords: The Failure of Land Reform in Early Victorian Britain,” in Cragoe, Matthew and Readman, Paul, eds., The Land Question in Britain (Basingstoke, 2010), 7491Google Scholar.

43 Montesquieu, The Spirit of the Laws, eds. and trans. Cohler, Anne M., Miller, Basia Carolyn, and Stone, Harold Samuel (Cambridge, 1989)Google Scholar, Book Five, chaps. 5–9. See also de Dijn, Annalien, French Political Thought from Montesquieu to Tocqueville (Cambridge, 2008)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

44 Bourke, Richard, Empire and Revolution (Princeton, 2015), 1920Google Scholar; Winch, Riches and Poverty, 180–82. For Stewart's use of the relevant theme in Montesquieu see Dugald Stewart, The Collected Works of Dugald Stewart, ed. William Hamilton, 11 vols. (1854–60), 9; 359–61.

45 Ibid., 203, 449–50.

46 Collini, Stefan, Winch, Donald, and Burrow, John, That Noble Science of Politics (Cambridge, 1983), 2736CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Fontana, Biancamaria, Rethinking the Politics of Commercial Society (Cambridge, 1985)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, esp. 155–7.

47 Winch, Riches and Poverty, 265–9, 356–64.

48 Malthus, T. R., Principles of Political Economy (Boston, MA, 1821Google Scholar; first published in England in 1820), 194–8, 335–9.

49 McCulloch, John Ramsay, “Disposal of Property by Will,” Edinburgh Review 40/80 (July 1824), 350–75Google Scholar, 363–9.

50 See Hilton, Boyd, The Age of Atonement (Oxford, 1986)Google Scholar.

51 Chalmers, Thomas, On Political Economy in Connexion with the Moral State and Moral Prospects of Society, 2nd edn. (Glasgow, 1832)Google Scholar. For Chalmers's tortuous exposition of this Physiocrat-indebted point regarding taxation see chap. 9. For the general aims see 300, and chap. 16.

52 Ibid., chap. 11, quote at 344.

53 Ibid., 352–71, quote at 364.

54 Ibid., 372–7.

55 Laing, Notes of a Traveller, 2nd edn. (London, 1842), 162–3Google Scholar, 287.

56 Ibid., 376, 392.

57 See Laing, Samuel, Notes on the Rise, Progress, and Prospects of the Schism from the Church of Rome (London, 1845), 116–20Google Scholar; Sturlason and Laing, Heimskringla, 1: 89–99.

58 Laing, Norway, 186; Laing, Sweden, 425–6; Laing, Notes of a traveller, 56.

59 Laing, Sweden, 276.

60 Ibid., 430.

61 Laing, Journal of a Residence in Norway, 36–7, 299.

62 Laing, Notes of a Traveller, 60.

63 See Drake, Michael, “Malthus on Norway,” Population Studies 20/2 (Nov. 1966), 175–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

64 Malthus, T. R., An Essay on the Principle of Population, 6th edn., 2 vols. (London, 1826), 1Google Scholar: 263–7.

65 Chalmers, On Political Economy, 422.

66 Laing, Norway, 481

67 Ibid., 148–9.

68 Ibid., 481.

69 Laing, Notes of a Traveller, 37–9.

70 Laing, Norway, 18–22, quote at 22.

71 Ibid., 19–20, 481–2.

72 Ibid., iii–iv.

73 Ibid., 479–80.

74 Ibid., 227.

75 See Mackintosh, James, A Discourse on the Study of the Law of Nature and Nations, 2nd edn (London, 1799), 47–9Google Scholar.

76 The opening salvo came in Björnstjerna's On the Moral State and Political Union of Sweden and Norway (London, 1840). Laing's response was published in the Monthly Chronicle and thereafter attached to the second edition of Notes of a Traveller.

77 Laing, Notes of a Traveller, viii–ix.

78 Laing, Norway, iii–iv.

79 Ibid., 2.

80 Ibid., 38.

81 Ibid., 121–3; Arthur Young, The Example of France, a Warning to Britain (1793).

82 Laing, Norway, 227, 203–4.

83 de Tocqueville, Alexis, Democracy in America, ed. and trans. Mansfield, Harvey C. and Winthrop, Debra (Chicago, 2000), 4653CrossRefGoogle Scholar, quote at 47.

84 Kenny, Courtney Stanhope, The History of the Law of Primogeniture in England (London, 1878), 60Google Scholar; Paine, Thomas, Rights of Man (Mineola, NY, 1999), 42Google Scholar.

85 Romani, Roberto, “The Republican Foundations of Sismondi's Nouveaux principes d’économie politique,” History of European Ideas 31/1 (2005), 1733CrossRefGoogle Scholar. A far more detailed account of Sismondi's development and thought that corrects aspects of Romani's slightly simplistic dichotomy of “political economy” and “republicanism” can be found in Thomas Hopkins, “Say and Sismondi on the Political Economy of Post-revolutionary Europe c.1800–1842” (Ph.D. thesis, University of Cambridge, 2010), 81–204.

86 de Sismondi, J.-C.-L. Simonde, New Principles of Political Economy, trans. Hyse, Richard (New Brunswick and London, 1991), 518–21Google Scholar.

87 Ibid., 586.

88 Ibid., 143–7, 186–7, 123.

89 Ibid., 53, 305–6, 311–12, 569–71; for Sismondi's preference for a form of aristocracy see [de Sismondi, J.-C.-L. Simonde], Political Economy, and the Philosophy of Government; a Series of Essays Selected from the Works of M. de Sismondi (London, 1847), 302–13Google Scholar, 368–402.

90 Laing, Notes of a Traveller, 35–56.

91 Ibid., 79–82.

92 Ibid., 62–3.

93 Ibid., 78.

94 Ibid., 87–91.

95 Ibid., 216.

96 Ibid., 26–7.

97 The theme has been well treated in Joanna Innes, “Central Government ‘Interference’: Changing Conceptions, Practices, and Concerns, c.1700–1850,” in Harris, Jose, ed., Civil Society in British History (Oxford, 2003), 3960CrossRefGoogle Scholar. On the importance of ideas of local and central government see Hoppen, K. Theodore, The Mid-Victorian Generation (Oxford, 1998), 104–5Google Scholar; for a detailed account of localism as politics see Weinstein, Benjamin, Liberalism and Local Government in Early Victorian London (Woodbridge and Rochester, NY, 2011)Google Scholar.

98 Laing, Sweden, 363.

99 Laing, Notes of a Traveller, 78.

100 Ibid., 71–6.

101 Ibid., 147–8.

102 Laing, Sweden, 76.

103 Laing, Norway, 299.

104 Laing, Notes of a Traveller, 361.

105 Ibid., 362.

106 Ibid., and quotes at 374.

107 Smith, Wealth of Nations, 2: 264–5.

108 Laing, Notes of a Traveller, 9.

109 Ibid., 373–6, quote at 376.

110 Ibid., 228–308, 42–6, quote at 308.

111 Sismondi, New Principles, 199–205.

112 See too Laing, Samuel, Observations on the Social and Political State of the European People in 1848 and 1849 (London, 1850), 36Google Scholar.

113 Ibid., 100.

114 Ibid., 102–3.

115 Ibid., 93–4.

116 Ibid., 98

117 Ibid., 104.

118 Ibid., 151, 122–4.

119 Laing, Samuel, Observations on the Social and Political State of Denmark (London, 1852), 8087Google Scholar.

120 Laing, Observations on the European People, 528.

121 Ibid., 110.

122 Ibid., 111.

123 Laing, Denmark, 41, 299–313, 383–9.

124 Ibid., 301–5; Laing, Observations on the European People, 152–72; Laing, Sweden, 78–91; Sismondi, New Principles, 324.

125 A compilation of French condemnations of primogeniture and entail published for British readers in 1844 made use of Hippolyte Passy, Gustave de Beaumont, Sismondi, Eugène Buret, Guizot, Constant, Charles Dupin, and Say. The Aristocracy of Britain and the Laws of Entail and Primogeniture Judged by Recent French Writers (Cupar, 1844).

126 See Cragoe and Readman, The Land Question, passim; Thompson, F. M. L., “Changing Perceptions of Land Tenures in Britain, 1750–1914,” in Winch, Donald and O'Brien, Patrick K., eds., The Political Economy of British Historical Experience 1688–1914 (Oxford, 2002), 119–38Google Scholar, 128–32. For Thorold Rogers's awareness of Laing's pioneering status see Thorold Rogers, James E., The Industrial and Commercial History of England, ed. Rogers, Arthur G. L. (New York and London, 1892), 265Google Scholar. On Gladstone see Stubbs, Charles William, The Land and the Labourers (London, 1884), iiGoogle Scholar.

127 Martin, David, John Stuart Mill and the Land Question (Leeds, 1981), 1920Google Scholar; Mill, John Stuart, The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, ed. Robson, John M., 33 vols. (Toronto and London, 1963–91), 2Google Scholar: 283–5; Cobden, Richard, The Letters of Richard Cobden, ed. Howe, Anthony and Morgan, Simon, 4 vols. (Oxford, 2007–15), 4Google Scholar: 351; Thomas Thornton, William, A Plea for Peasant Proprietors (London, 1848), viviiGoogle Scholar.

128 Duncan, Jonathan, “Tenure of Land in Ireland,” Dublin Review 24/48 (1848), 349–80Google Scholar; Smith, William Henry, “Political Economy, by J. S. Mill,” Blackwood's 64/396 (1848) 407–28Google Scholar; anon., “A Plea for Peasant Proprietors,” Athenaeum 1091 (23 Sept. 1848), 949–50Google Scholar. See also Peter Gray, “The Peculiarities of Irish Land Tenure, 1800–1914,” in Winch and O'Brien, British Historical Experience, 139–62, 145–9.

129 Michell, Thomas, “Yeomen Farmers in Norway,” Quarterly Review 162/324 (1886), 384413Google Scholar.

130 Mill, Collected Works, 2: 294.

131 Ibid., 3: 767–8.

132 Carey, H. C., Principles of Social Science, 3 vols. (Philadelphia, 1858–9), 3Google Scholar: 342–6.

133 Jevons, William Stanley, “The Future of Political Economy,” Fortnightly Review 20/119 (Nov. 1876), 617–31Google Scholar, 621.

134 Mill, Collected Works, 13: 622.

135 Austin, John, “Centralization,” Edinburgh Review 85/171 (Jan. 1847), 221–58Google Scholar, 237.

136 Ibid., 242–3.

137 Greg, William R., Essays on Political and Social Science, 2 vols. (London, 1853), 1Google Scholar: 113–206, quote at 196.

138 Kay, Joseph, The Social Condition and Education of the People in England and Europe, 2 vols. (London, 1850)Google Scholar.

139 Greg, Essays on Political and Social Science, 1: 158–61.

140 Bagehot, Walter, The English Constitution, ed. Taylor, Miles (Oxford, 2001), 140–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

141 Spencer, Herbert, “Over-Legislation,” Westminster Review 60/117 (July 1853), 5184Google Scholar, at 82.

142 Parry, The Politics of Patriotism, 61–4.