Article contents
The Seventeenth-Century Crisis in South Asia
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 28 November 2008
Extract
In several of the world's regions a ‘general crisis’ seems to have occurred in the first half of the seventeenth century. At that time in each region, political instability and war, population decline and urban stagnation, economic crises marked by falling prices and depleted stocks of precious metals, and dramatic climatic shifts converged. These symptoms have been detected in western Europe, in the Ottoman lands, and even in China and Japan. Their causes have been attributed in part to the effects of the price revolution, partly to climate change, and in part to rising populations which begin to outstrip agricultural production. The latter tendency in particular seems to have caused a fiscal crisis for the absolutist agrarian states characteristic of Eurasia in this period. Other analyses stress the effects of a tightening linkage in the emerging capitalist world economy in which precious metal flows served to mark newly imposed interdependencies.
- Type
- Articles
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1990
References
This is a revised version of a paper presented at the Association for Asian Studies Annual General Meeting in Washington, D.C., in March 1989.
1 For the most recent comparative discussion see Goldstone, Jack, ‘East and West in the Seventeenth Century: Political Crises in Stuart England, Ottoman Turkey, and Ming China’, Comparative Studies in Society and History 30 (1988), 103–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar Also Atwell, William, ‘Some Observations on the Seventeenth Century Crisis in China and Japan’, Journal of Asian Studies 45 (1986), 223–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
2 Goldstone, 105: ‘Put simply, large agrarian states of this period were not equipped to deal with the impact of a steady growth of population that was in excess of the productivity of the land’.
3 For a detailed description of the effects of Imperial decline and public order on commercial life see Gupta, Ashin Das, Indian Merchants and the Decline of Surat, c. 1700–1750 (Wiesbaden: Franz Steiner Verlag, 1978). Caravans and even the routine commercial post carried by runners suffered a drastic decline in speed and reliability (pp. 56–7).Google Scholar
4 Moosvi, Shireen, The Economy of the Mughal Empire, c. 1595 (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1987), 198–9.Google Scholar
5 Ibid., 201.
6 Begley, W. E. and Desai, Z. A. (eds), The Shah Jahan Nama of 'Inayat Khan (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1989) 282.Google Scholar Under the escheat system the emperor appropriated a large portion of each estate and then passed on some portion to the deceased's heirs. Ali, M. Athar, The Mughal Nobility under Aurangzeb (Aligarh: Asia publishing House, 1966) 63–5.Google Scholar
7 Ali, Athar, Mughal Nobility, 64.Google Scholar
8 Richards, , ‘Mughal State Finance’, 293.Google Scholar
9 Richards, J. F., ‘Mughal State Finance and the Premodern World Economy’ in Comparative Studies in Society and History (1981), 296.Google Scholar
10 Richards, J. F., Precious Metals in the Later Medieval and Early Modern Worlds (Durham: Carolina Academic Press, 1983), 26.Google Scholar
11 Habib, Irfan, ‘A System of Trimetallism in the Age of the “Price Revolution”: Effects of the Silver Influx on the Mughal Monetary System’ in Richards, John F. (ed.), The Imperial Monetary System of Mughal India (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1987).Google Scholar
12 Deyell, John, ‘The Development of Akbar's Currency System and Monetary Integration of the conquered Kingdom’s in Richards, , Monetary Integration, 44–5.Google Scholar
13 Richards, , Imperial Monetary System, 2–3.Google Scholar
14 Raychaudhuri, Taypan and Habib, Irfan (eds), The Cambridge Economic History of India Volume I: c. 1200–1750 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982), 375–6.Google Scholar
15 Ibid., 167.
16 Ibid., 170.
17 Ibid., 169.
18 Grover, B. R., ‘An Integrated Pattern of Commercial Life in the Rural Society of North India During the 17th–18th Centuries’ Proceedings, Indian Historical Records Commission, 37th Session, 1966, 121–53.Google Scholar
19 Ibid. Surat was estimated to have a population of 100,000 in 1663 and 200,000 in 1700.
20 Raychaudhuri and Habib, 171 Table 3, ‘Estimate of population of towns in Mughal India’. Estimates for Agra in 1609 are 500,000; in 1629–43, 660,000; and in 1666, 800,000.Google Scholar
21 Blake, Stephen P., ‘Cityscape of an Imperial Capital: Shahjahanabad in 1739’ in Frykenberg, R. E., Delhi Through the Ages (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1986).Google Scholar
22 Raychaudhuri and Habib, 217.Google Scholar
23 Ibid., 225.
24 Ibid., 217.
25 Chandra, Satish, ‘The Structure of Village Society in Northern India’ in Chandra, Satish, Medieval India (Delhi: Manohar, 1982), 33.Google Scholar
26 Satish Chandra, ‘Role of the Local Community, the Zamindars and the State in Providing Capital Inputs for the Improvement and Expansion of Cultivation’ in ibid., 171–2.
27 Rachaudhuri and Habib, 176–7; 246.Google Scholar
28 Tapan Rachaudhuri, ‘Inland Trade’ in ibid., 325–59.
29 Arasaratnam, Sinnappah, Merchants, Companies and Commerce on the Coromandel Coast 1650–1750 (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1986), 111.Google Scholar
30 Richards, , ‘Mughal State Finance’, 303.Google Scholar
31 Prakash, Om, The Dutch East India Company and the Economy of Bengal, 1630–1720 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1985), 70–1.Google Scholar
32 Ibid., 82.
33 Ibid., 256.
34 Arasaratnam, , Merchants, Companies, and Commerce, 3–4.Google Scholar
35 Chandra, , Medieval India, 46–75 for two essays on the jagirdari crisis.Google Scholar
36 Habib, Irfan, The Agrarian System of Mughal India (London: Asia Publishing House, 1963), 320.Google Scholar
37 Ali, Athar, Mughal Nobility, 92–4.Google Scholar
38 Richards, J. F., Mughal Administration in Golconda (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1975), 157–62.Google Scholar
39 For details of these years in Hyderabad province see ibid., 215–35.
- 12
- Cited by