Introduction
Board monitoring is based on the underlying assumption that directors' human and social capital enables them to curb managerial self-interest and act as vigilant monitors to protect shareholders' interests (Boivie, Graffin, Oliver, & Withers, Reference Boivie, Graffin, Oliver and Withers2016; Eisenhardt, Reference Eisenhardt1989; Fama & Jensen, Reference Fama and Jensen1983). The literature has failed to reach a conclusion on the effectiveness of board monitoring (Goranova, Priem, Ndofor, & Trahms, Reference Goranova, Priem, Ndofor and Trahms2017). What constitutes effective monitoring? Hambrick, Misangyi, and Park (Reference Hambrick, Misangyi and Park2015: 324) posited that ‘the locus of effective monitoring is the individual director’. However, divergent findings on the effectiveness of board monitoring have indicated the importance of understanding the roles and behaviors of individual directors.
Effective monitoring is arduous and risky. The key to understanding the differences in the monitoring efforts of directors lies in their information-processing ability (Boivie, Bednar, Aguilera, & Andrus, Reference Boivie, Bednar, Aguilera and Andrus2016) and career motivation (Hambrick et al., Reference Hambrick, Misangyi and Park2015; Westphal & Zajac, Reference Westphal and Zajac2013). On the one hand, boards rely on firm information to effectively monitor managers; however, they are often at an information disadvantage as managers exploit information asymmetry to increase the monitoring costs for directors (Aboody & Lev, Reference Aboody and Lev2000; Adams & Ferreira, Reference Adams and Ferreira2007; Frankel & Li, Reference Frankel and Li2004). Xiao, Sun, and Weng (Reference Xiao, Sun and Weng2021) found that managers can control information through tactics such as earnings management to reduce directors' dissent on managers' proposals in public. On the other hand, directors are motivated to maintain acquiescence in the boardroom by adhering to prevailing social norms because corporate elites can punish directors for introducing conflict (Boivie, Graffin, & Gentry, Reference Boivie, Graffin and Gentry2016; Harrison, Boivie, Sharp, & Gentry, Reference Harrison, Boivie, Sharp and Gentry2018; Westphal & Khanna, Reference Westphal and Khanna2003). Researchers have found that directors appointed by insiders (Ma & Khanna, Reference Ma and Khanna2016) and those appointed based on CEO–director friendship ties (Westphal, Reference Westphal1999) are negatively associated with board monitoring.
To effectively monitor a firm's management, directors must overcome information barriers and be motivated to acquire a favorable reputation for protecting shareholders' welfare. In this study, we argue that centrality in the interlocking network can supplement directors' existing information set and facilitate reputation spillover, leading to more effective director monitoring. In particular, according to social network theory, a social network can not only influence the flow and quality of information but also ‘dominate motivation’ (Granovetter, Reference Granovetter2005: 34). Moving beyond the atomistic perspective in the literature on director monitoring, in which the individual director is viewed as an independent entity who makes decisions, we contend that the board interlock network is one of the most important social contexts in which directors are embedded (Brass, Reference Brass1984; Kilduff & Brass, Reference Kilduff and Brass2010; Tasselli, Kilduff, & Menges, Reference Tasselli, Kilduff and Menges2015). A director's information-processing ability and reputation concerns are either potentiated or constrained by their position in this network (Brass, Galaskiewicz, Greve, & Tsai, Reference Brass, Galaskiewicz, Greve and Tsai2004), leading to differences in monitoring effectiveness.
A board can be viewed as a black box (Adams, Hermalin, & Weisbach, Reference Adams, Hermalin and Weisbach2010), which makes it difficult for researchers to observe the internal dynamics. To address the problem of endogeneity in board formation and to open the black box of director monitoring, we take advantage of the special regulatory environment in China since 2004 – the China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) requires publicly traded companies to disclose all instances of directors' dissent during board meetings. This research setting provides us with a suitable opportunity to examine the internal process related to the behaviors of directors on a board. From this unique dataset, we find that directors who occupy positions of greater centrality in the board's interlocking network are more likely to dissent. In addition, we examine the underlying mechanisms of information and reputation through two moderators: firm transparency and media mention of director. Furthermore, we find that the effect is contingent on the type of director, which indicates that the characteristics of the nodes in the network play an important role.
This study contributes to the literature on board of directors by highlighting the roles and behaviors of socially situated and constituted directors (Westphal & Zajac, Reference Westphal and Zajac2013). Specifically, we posit that a social network serves as an important social context that alters the information environment and reputation concerns of directors, thus influencing the effectiveness of their monitoring. We show that a social network enhances the efficiency of the directorship market (Jones, Hesterly, & Borgatti, Reference Jones, Hesterly and Borgatti1997; Raub & Weesie, Reference Raub and Weesie1990). Furthermore, our study contributes to the literature on the micro-foundations of corporate governance by proposing hypotheses on and empirically examining the information-processing ability and motivation of directors in the context of their monitoring behaviors (Hambrick et al., Reference Hambrick, Misangyi and Park2015). Finally, this study contributes to the literature on corporate governance in emerging economies (Zhu & Yoshikawa, Reference Zhu and Yoshikawa2015) by showing that in a board of directors, independent directors may not actively perform monitoring functions.
Theoretical Background and Hypotheses
Dissent Voting by Directors on Boards
A board of directors influences corporate decision-making by participating in the ratification and monitoring process (Fama & Jensen, Reference Fama and Jensen1983). Dissent voting by a director on the board plays a vital role in this process. The expression of different opinions by directors is considered a valuable and vital attribute of effective corporate governance (Marchetti, Siciliano, & Ventoruzzo, Reference Marchetti, Siciliano and Ventoruzzo2017). Recent studies have shown that dissent improves firm performance and firm value through improved corporate governance (Choi, Rabarison, & Wang, Reference Choi, Rabarison and Wang2021; Xiao et al., Reference Xiao, Sun and Weng2021). Ye, Zhu, Lu, and Zhang (Reference Ye, Zhu, Lu and Zhang2011) found that most proposals that were not approved by independent directors were associated with subsequent proposal improvements. For example, the rejection of a proposal on related-party transaction was followed by reduced related-party activity in the subsequent year. Using data on Korean listed firms, Kang, Kim, and Oh (Reference Kang, Kim and Oh2022) treated director dissent against proposals as a proxy for cognitive diversity and found that this cognitive diversity helps enhance monitoring effectiveness and increase firm value. Specifically, they found that firms with boards that reject proposals engage in earnings management to a smaller extent, are less likely to restate their financial statements, and are more likely to replace poorly performing CEOs in the years following the proposal rejection. In general, Kang et al. (Reference Kang, Kim and Oh2022) showed that dissent acts as active monitoring that prevents bad behaviors (Tirole, Reference Tirole2001).
Although dissent-driven proposal rejections are less frequent in some countries, such as China than in other countries, such as Korea, studies have shown that dissent voting can make a difference as a type of passive monitoring that provides ‘performance measurement’ of the focal firm's corporate governance practices (Tirole, Reference Tirole2001). Jiang, Wan, and Zhao (Reference Jiang, Wan and Zhao2016) found that in their sample of Chinese firms, 92% of the proposals were eventually passed despite dissent, indicating that director dissent in China is mainly a form of passive monitoring. They also found that dissent in Chinese listed firms results in the dissemination of value-relevant information, leading to an improvement in corporate governance and market transparency through the responses of stakeholders such as shareholders, creditors, and regulators, even though voting ‘no’ on the board may not necessarily prevent a proposal from being passed.
Although studies have shown that dissent voting is effective in monitoring management, improving corporate governance, and increasing firm performance and value, expressing dissent is not easy for directors. Dissent voting is often perceived to be an act that is against the interests of management and controlling shareholders, and that violates the norms of reciprocity (Ma & Khanna, Reference Ma and Khanna2016). In 2001, CSRC made it mandatory for discussion material to be provided before meetings. Therefore, management and the CEO have the opportunity to communicate with directors and seek their support or advice before the official meeting. Dissent occurs when managers refuse to heed the advice of directors and directors decide to defend their views and officially discipline the managers. Dissenting opinions may attract the attention of regulators and investors when announced to the public. Jiang et al. (Reference Jiang, Wan and Zhao2016) showed that dissent almost always triggers investigations by the CSRC. These investigations bring firms' managerial behaviors under increased scrutiny and are likely to result in punishment.
A violation of the interests of management and controlling shareholders can result in relational penalties for the dissenting directors, such as social distancing (Shani & Westphal, Reference Shani and Westphal2015; Westphal & Khanna, Reference Westphal and Khanna2003). Such penalties may be particularly severe given that the ownership is concentrated and the management and controlling shareholders sponsor most proposals (Jiang et al., Reference Jiang, Wan and Zhao2016). Zheng, Li, Huang, and Hu (Reference Zheng, Li, Huang and Hu2016) found that dissenting independent directors are less likely to be re-elected for a second term. Du, Hou, Tang, and Yao (Reference Du, Hou, Tang and Yao2018) reported substantial director turnover and a decrease in the number of board seats after independent directors voted ‘no’.
Network Centrality and Director Dissent
According to agency theory, the effectiveness of director monitoring depends on both the effective acquisition of information and the efficient directorship market that rewards vigilant directors while punishing passive directors (Fama, Reference Fama1980; Fama & Jensen, Reference Fama and Jensen1983). Effective acquisition of information enables directors to take part in corporate decision-making on the board, and an efficient directorship market motivates them to fulfill their fiduciary duty and act in the best interests of both the company and shareholders. We argue that network centrality, which is defined as the extent to which a director is directly or indirectly linked to others in the entire directors’ network (Freeman, Reference Freeman1979), significantly affects the effectiveness of the information and reputation mechanisms, thus influencing the probability of dissent voting.
First, directors with higher network centrality may have greater information advantage. Boards rely on firm information to effectively monitor managers; however, they often experience information disadvantages as managers exploit information asymmetry to increase monitoring costs for directors (Aboody & Lev, Reference Aboody and Lev2000; Adams & Ferreira, Reference Adams and Ferreira2007; Frankel & Li, Reference Frankel and Li2004). As a social network, a board interlock provides an alternative channel for directors, especially well-connected directors, to obtain firm-specific information in order to attenuate the information asymmetry problem. Through modeling, Fracassi (Reference Fracassi2017) found that information on corporate decision-making spills over through the interlocking director network. After interviewing the CEOs of Fortune 100 firms, Beckman and Haunschild (Reference Beckman and Haunschild2002: 97) noted that ‘tacit information that board members bring to the table’ is important in firms' decision-making. They also stated that board interlocks, as ‘inexpensive, trustworthy, credible information sources’, are important sources of first-hand information for board directors (Haunschild & Beckman, Reference Haunschild and Beckman1998: 817). Social networks facilitate information transfer by improving the flow and quality of information, particularly for actors with better connections (Haythornthwaite, Reference Haythornthwaite1996; Jackson, Rogers, & Zenou, Reference Jackson, Rogers and Zenou2017). Therefore, information obtained from an external social network may supplement directors’ existing information set and help them fulfill the monitoring role (Fama & Jensen, Reference Fama and Jensen1983).
Central directors in a board interlock network can access a greater amount of information in the external environment of the firm. Board connections promote information exchange (Larcker, So, & Wang, Reference Larcker, So and Wang2013), which enables directors to gain a deeper understanding of evolving market conditions, helps the prediction of growing trends (Mizruchi, Reference Mizruchi1996; Moore, Reference Moore2001), and narrows the information gap between stakeholders (Schoorman, Bazerman, & Atkin, Reference Schoorman, Bazerman and Atkin1981). Well-positioned outside directors have access to a greater amount of information about suppliers, competitors, and customers (Coles, Daniel, & Naveen, Reference Coles, Daniel and Naveen2012). Although some connections may not directly provide firm-specific information to a director, by obtaining a greater amount of information, directors can verify the quality of information provided to them by management. For example, directors can better assess whether a compensation proposal or a merger and acquisition (M&A) premium decision is reasonable by comparing it with practices in other firms.
When a director's centrality increases, they can obtain a greater amount of support and resources from the board's interlocking network. Thus, they will have greater influence on decision-making in the board and greater power in influencing how the CEO and other board members perceive them and interpret their actions (Sauder, Lynn, & Podolny, Reference Sauder, Lynn and Podolny2012). In exchange for these resources, management may be more willing to share a greater amount of information with central directors and pay greater attention to their opinions (Boivie, Bednar, et al., Reference Boivie, Bednar, Aguilera and Andrus2016).
Second, directors with higher network centrality may be more concerned about reputation. Central directors are more visible to other directors in the network. Therefore, their reputation for effective monitoring may diffuse more broadly and quickly (Brass, Butterfield, & Skaggs, Reference Brass, Butterfield and Skaggs1998). The higher the centrality of a director in a network, the more often the director tends to be noticed in the network (Gould, Reference Gould2002; Podolny, Reference Podolny1993, Reference Podolny2001; Rao, Monin, & Durand, Reference Rao, Monin and Durand2005). This visibility also provides directors with greater credibility and a greater number of cues on the appropriateness of their behavior in the director network (Borgatti, Reference Borgatti2005; Lin, Reference Lin2001). Using game-theoretic models, Raub and Weesie (Reference Raub and Weesie1990) concluded that efficiency is more easily attained in perfectly embedded systems than in systems of atomized interactions because individuals in a perfectly embedded system are more rational and protect their reputations. Moreover, efficiency becomes more restrictive when actors receive information after a greater time lag. When the director is in a position of greater centrality, their reputation spillover is considerably quicker (Brass et al., Reference Brass, Butterfield and Skaggs1998; Yu & Lester, Reference Yu and Lester2008), thus increasing the strength of the reputation mechanism and improving the efficiency of the market.
This visibility may also act as a liability for a central director. Directors who are more central in their networks are more visible and are therefore more likely to face legal or regulatory scrutiny if they do not exhibit agentic qualities (Adut, Reference Adut2005; Fine, Reference Fine1996). For example, Brass et al. (Reference Brass, Butterfield and Skaggs1998: 21) argued that ‘being well known provides additional constraints from surveillance and possible loss of reputation’. Therefore, central directors must strive to portray a responsible, capable, and independent image of themselves in the directorship market in order to build an agentic reputation. Considered together, these two forces equip directors with both the capability and the motivation to perform effective monitoring via dissent (Hambrick et al., Reference Hambrick, Misangyi and Park2015).
Based on the information and reputation mechanisms discussed above, we propose the following hypothesis.
Hypothesis 1 (H1): Directors with greater centrality within the board's interlocking network are more likely to dissent.
To further examine the information and reputation mechanisms of interlocking networks, we developed the moderating effect of firm transparency and the moderating effect of media mention of director. High firm transparency was supposed to attenuate the information advantage brought by network, and intense media attention was supposed to reduce reputation concerns caused by central network position. In addition, we also explored the heterogeneous effects of network centrality on director dissent by developing the moderating effect of director type, which is an important boundary condition of our theoretical arguments.
Moderating Effect of Firm Transparency
Firm transparency is the availability and reliability of firm-specific information disclosed to stakeholders (Bushman, Piotroski, & Smith, Reference Bushman, Piotroski and Smith2004; Qian, Gao, & Tsang, Reference Qian, Gao and Tsang2015). In firms with less transparency, insiders such as managers find it easier to abuse their information advantage in order to increase the directors' costs of obtaining corporate information (Adams & Ferreira, Reference Adams and Ferreira2007; Coles, Daniel, & Naveen, Reference Coles, Daniel and Naveen2008; Duchin, Matsusaka, & Ozbas, Reference Duchin, Matsusaka and Ozbas2010; Linck, Netter, & Yang, Reference Linck, Netter and Yang2008). Duchin et al. (Reference Duchin, Matsusaka and Ozbas2010) reported that the accessibility of required information can influence the monitoring effectiveness of outside directors. A restrictive information environment in firms with less transparency increases information-processing demands on boards, and some information-processing challenges may inhibit directors' monitoring and reduce board effectiveness (Boivie, Bednar, et al., Reference Boivie, Bednar, Aguilera and Andrus2016). The cognitive burden caused by difficulties in information processing may prevent directors from fully using their human capital (Khanna, Jones, & Boivie, Reference Khanna, Jones and Boivie2014). In a recent study, Xiao et al. (Reference Xiao, Sun and Weng2021) found that the level of earnings management – an indicator of financial transparency – was negatively associated with the likelihood of board dissent.
Although emerging markets lack transparency and have an opaque information environment (Liao, Ma, & Yu, Reference Liao, Ma and Yu2022), the transparency of firms in China can differ due to several factors. Studies have shown that auditor quality (Fan & Wong, Reference Fan and Wong2005) and external information gathering by intermediaries such as analysts (Lang, Lins, & Maffett, Reference Lang, Lins and Maffett2012) can influence firm transparency. In particular, when a firm is audited by a large audit firm rather than a small one and covered by a greater number of analysts, it is more likely to disclose a greater amount of reliable information and attenuate information asymmetry between managers and the board. When firm transparency is greater, the cost of obtaining information and the demand for information processing for directors is lower, and directors rely on the board network to a smaller extent to access firm-specific information and verify information provided by the management. Therefore, the information mechanism underlying the influence of a director's centrality on dissent is weakened when firm transparency is greater. Based on this discussion, we propose the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 2 (H2): Firm transparency moderates the positive relationship between network centrality and director dissent in such a way that the relationship is weaker for firms with greater transparency.
Moderating Effect of Media Mention of Director
Media can play an active role in disciplining deviant behaviors in corporate governance in both developed and developing countries (Dyck, Volchkova, & Zingales, Reference Dyck, Volchkova and Zingales2008). Dyck, Morse, and Zingales (Reference Dyck, Morse and Zingales2010) showed that negative media coverage, such as misreporting, may damage the reputation of managers and incur litigation risks. To protect personal reputations, managers are sensitive to how media comment on their decisions (Dyck & Zingales, Reference Dyck and Zingales2002). Furthermore, Liu and McConnell (Reference Liu and McConnell2013) found that media coverage affects managers' decisions to abandon value-reducing acquisition attempts by influencing managers' reputations and future employment opportunities in the managerial labor market. In the context of China, Ji, Quan, Yin, and Yuan (Reference Ji, Quan, Yin and Yuan2021) found that media coverage can mitigate the effect of local gambling attitudes of Chinese listed firms on the stock price crash risk.
Given the role of media in gathering and disseminating information, directors' behaviors in corporate governance are amplified through media coverage. Fos, Li, and Tsoutsoura (Reference Fos, Li and Tsoutsoura2018) found that directors seem to receive a greater amount of media attention when their firm has experienced poor performance and when director elections are approaching. Jiang et al. (Reference Jiang, Wan and Zhao2016) showed that media coverage has a considerable influence on directors' reputations. On the one hand, professional reputation is important for directors because it is one of the major considerations of the board chair when appointing new directors (Kaplan & Reishus, Reference Kaplan and Reishus1990). Research has shown that directors with a reputation for ‘tough’ monitoring get a greater number of opportunities for the future in the directorship market, especially from firms that want to demonstrate their commitment to good corporate governance. Although relationships and loyalty are important factors in directors' retention, reputation continues to be a major concern for boards when appointing new directors (Kaplan & Reishus, Reference Kaplan and Reishus1990). Thus, directors are motivated to be diligent monitors because a good reputation is rewarding. On the other hand, directors whose dereliction of duty is disclosed by the media face higher risks of penalties, litigation, and reputation damage (Brochet & Srinivasan, Reference Brochet and Srinivasan2014; Jiang et al., Reference Jiang, Wan and Zhao2016). Thus, intense media exposure of directors increases their concerns about reputation and prompts them to exercise due diligence.
Under intense media attention, the difference in the reputation concerns of central directors and peripheral directors in the board network is attenuated. Directors who are at peripheral locations in the board interlock network and have a large amount of media coverage can be as visible as directors with greater centrality. Directors' reputations for effective or ineffective monitoring can be quickly amplified through media coverage, and directors' wrongdoings can be detected more easily by regulators. Therefore, the reputation mechanism underlying the influence of a director's centrality on dissent is weakened when the director has a greater number of media mentions. Based on this discussion, we propose the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 3 (H3): Media mention moderates the positive relationship between network centrality and director dissent in such a way that the relationship is weaker for directors with a greater amount of media attention.
Moderating Effect of Director Type
The effects of network centrality on director dissent may be contingent on director type. The board often consists of inside directors and outside directors. Inside director positions are held by key executives in management, such as the CEO and the Chief Financial Officer (CFO), whereas outside director positions are usually held by independent directors. In China, independent directors are mostly former officials or academics (Huang, Lee, Lyu, & Zhu, Reference Huang, Lee, Lyu and Zhu2016). They are usually hired by the board to comply with regulations or provide resources to the firm (Cowen & Marcel, Reference Cowen and Marcel2011; Lester, Hillman, Zardkoohi, & Cannella, Reference Lester, Hillman, Zardkoohi and Cannella2008), and the labor market for directors has specific function expectations for them. In the context of monitoring functions, independent directors are expected to ‘not make trouble for CEOs’ (Hermalin & Weisbach, Reference Hermalin and Weisbach2003: 4). Owing to these expectations, the effects of network centrality on director dissent may vary for independent directors.
First, the information mechanism associated with network centrality is weaker for independent directors. Although independent directors can obtain additional information from the external social network, their abilities to process the information may be limited. According to the information-processing perspective, board monitoring is ‘most effective when available information-processing capacity equals or exceeds information processing demands’ (Khanna et al., Reference Khanna, Jones and Boivie2014: 563). Boivie, Bednar, et al. (Reference Boivie, Bednar, Aguilera and Andrus2016) argued that the degree to which a director's outside job demands are similar or dissimilar to those of the focal firm influences their information-processing capabilities. Carpenter and Westphal (Reference Carpenter and Westphal2001) also reported that similarities between the demands of an outside job and those of the focal firm affect directors' perceptions of the extent to which they can contribute during board meetings. As most independent directors are former officials or academics, the demands of their outside job and those of the director's role are dissimilar; owing to this dissimilarity, they are less likely to have a fair understanding of the firm's business and operation. Therefore, the information advantage that they gain due to a central network position decreases when they monitor the management.
Second, the reputation mechanism associated with network centrality is weaker for independent directors. Li et al. (Reference Li, Krause, Qin, Zhang, Zhu, Lin and Xu2018) argued that independent directors have two concerns when they perform monitoring: reputation concerns as a dutiful fiduciary of shareholders' interests (Fama & Jensen, Reference Fama and Jensen1983; Gilson, Reference Gilson1990) and labor market concerns about future board positions that rely heavily on powerful insiders. For example, Ma and Khanna (Reference Ma and Khanna2016) found that a large proportion of independent directors are appointed by board chairs. In a set of 14,148 firm-year observations, they found that in 55.5% of firms, all independent directors on the board had been appointed by the board chair at that time. Although investors may add value to effective board monitoring through means such as dissent, studies have shown that the labor market does not reward vigilant independent directors with future board positions (Du et al., Reference Du, Hou, Tang and Yao2018; Zheng et al., Reference Zheng, Li, Huang and Hu2016). Labor market concerns can suppress independent directors' concerns about the spillover of their reputation for being vigilant through the board network; consequently, independent directors may adopt a more passive approach to monitoring and may become more insider-oriented.
Considered together, limited information-processing capability and labor market concerns may attenuate the effect of network centrality on dissent by independent directors. Based on this discussion, we propose the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 4 (H4): Director type moderates the positive relationship between network centrality and director dissent in such a way that the relationship is weaker for independent directors.
Methods
Research Context
Since 2004, the CSRC has mandated the disclosure of directors' voting records by Chinese listed A-share companies. According to revised clauses, directors' voting records should include their affirmation, dissent, abstentions, and other opinions on every board proposal (Tang, Du, & Hou, Reference Tang, Du and Hou2013), such as mergers and acquisitions (M&A), compensation of the top management team (TMT), and related transactions. This new policy, aimed at protecting investors' interests by improving the board's decision quality, also provides a suitable opportunity for examining the internal process associated with directors' behavior in the boardroom. Previous studies are mostly based on the Western corporate governance context, in which the board's decision-making process does not have to be revealed. Consequently, a Chinese context, and especially the unique director voting data that is available, offers us a valuable opportunity to advance our knowledge of corporate governance.
The existence of interlocking directorates among listed companies is a ubiquitous phenomenon in both Western countries such as the United States (Mintz & Schwartz, Reference Mintz and Schwartz1981; Useem, Reference Useem1984) and Asian countries such as China (Markóczy, Li Sun, Peng, & Ren, Reference Markóczy, Li Sun, Peng and Ren2013). The interlocking directors' network is a typical two-mode affiliation network (Wasserman, Faust, & Iacobucci, Reference Wasserman, Faust and Iacobucci1994) in which directors are actors, and a board as an event or affiliation, is associated with each actor. Meanwhile, boards are related to each other through directors. Like many previous studies on director network (El-Khatib, Fogel, & Jandik, Reference El-Khatib, Fogel and Jandik2015; Tao, Li, Wu, Zhang, & Zhu, Reference Tao, Li, Wu, Zhang and Zhu2019), we focus on one of the modes – the actors (directors), not the event (board). In the analysis, ‘the occasions on which people interact (the events) are only important in that they link people’ (Wasserman et al., Reference Wasserman, Faust and Iacobucci1994: 307). We identify the links between two directors when they serve on at least one common board. Due to the existence of interlocking directorates, directors on different boards can be connected through a large network. This network of board directors is an important nexus for the social relationships in which the directors are embedded (Fracassi & Tate, Reference Fracassi and Tate2012).
Sample and Data
The firms in our sample were publicly listed on the Shanghai and Shenzhen Stock Exchanges from 2006 to 2013. The votes cast by directors for various proposals were manually collected from annual reports of firms and announcements. We identified 454 firms with 1,785 proposals on which at least one director cast a vote of dissent (voted ‘abstain’ or ‘against’).
Network indicators were calculated based on director affiliation information obtained from the China Stock Market and Accounting Research (CSMAR) database, and data on media mentions were obtained from the Chinese Research Data Services Platform (CNRDS), both of which are leading sources of data on the Chinese stock markets. Other control variables were calculated based on data from CSMAR.
Definitions of Variables
Dependent variable
Dissent vote by director
We generated a dummy variable (Dissent) for each proposal-director observation; the variable was coded as 1 if the director's vote was one of dissent, and as 0 if it was not one of dissent. Consistent with previous studies (Jiang et al., Reference Jiang, Wan and Zhao2016; Kang et al., Reference Kang, Kim and Oh2022; Xiao et al., Reference Xiao, Sun and Weng2021), we classified both ‘abstain’ and ‘against’ as dissent. This classification is reasonable because regulators consider these two negative votes to be similar. According to the requirements of the Company Law of China, only ‘for’ votes are considered effective for board proposals. Both ‘abstain’ and ‘against’ are ineffective by nature and must be disclosed identically. Furthermore, directors who vote either ‘abstain’ or ‘against’ are exempt from the liabilities caused by a company's malpractice (Jiang et al., Reference Jiang, Wan and Zhao2016).
Independent variables
Network centrality
Network centrality is an important indicator in social network analysis. There are four main centrality measures (Wasserman et al., Reference Wasserman, Faust and Iacobucci1994): degree centrality, closeness centrality, betweenness centrality, and eigenvector centrality. (1) Degree centrality is a measure of the number of direct ties between the focal individual and all other individuals within the network. (2) Closeness centrality is the inverse of the sum of the shortest distance between the focal individual and each of the other individuals within the network. It captures the focal individual's efficiency in obtaining information from the network. (3) Betweenness centrality is the frequency with which a focal individual is located on the shortest path between any other pair of individuals within the network. In essence, it captures the power of the focal individual over the information flow in the network because a person in that position can either facilitate or obstruct information flow between the pair of individuals. (4) Eigenvector centrality is a measure of the extent to which the focal individual is tied with other highly connected individuals. It can indicate the importance of the focal individual within the network. The mathematical formulas for these four network centrality measures are available in the Supplementary Appendix.
In our study, we constructed annual networks based on the position information of directors. As the Chinese stock markets grew and the number of listed firms increased, the board network became monotonically larger over time. In the period considered in our study – from 2006 to 2013 – the size of the board network increased from 13,415 (one node represents a unique director) to 22,369 and the number of non-directional links increased from 69,031 to 133,829. To address the issue of comparability between centrality measures across time, we followed the approach used by El-Khatib et al. (Reference El-Khatib, Fogel and Jandik2015) and transformed the original centrality measures to percentile values ranging from 1 (the least central) to 100 (the most central). Thus, the network size becomes insignificant and the centrality values across different years can be directly compared. This transformation maintains the ranking order of the network importance of each individual and enables a clear and simple interpretation of the centrality measures.
We used the software package Pajek, a widely used tool for social network analysis (De Nooy, Mrvar, & Batagelj, Reference De Nooy, Mrvar and Batagelj2011), to calculate the network centrality indicators based on the affiliation information of all of the directors. In addition, as the centrality variables are correlated and even collinear, we conducted a principal component analysis and used the first principal component (also the only principal component whose eigenvector is greater than 1) of the four centrality variables to determine the main effect of all of the centrality factors.
Moderators
Firm transparency
Ma, Zhang, Zhong, and Zhou (Reference Ma, Zhang, Zhong and Zhou2020) showed that large audit firms have a greater amount of expertise to monitor client firms and ensure transparency than small audit firms. Therefore, we used the audit firm indicator ‘Big Four’ to measure firm transparency. We coded firm transparency as 1 if the company was audited by a ‘Big Four’ audit firm (‘Big Four’ firms were identified based on the market share of their audited clients' total assets each year), and as 0 otherwise.
Media attention
Following Jiang et al. (Reference Jiang, Wan and Zhao2016), we used the natural logarithm of the number of articles containing the director's name that were published in major Chinese newspapers, such as China Securities Journal, by distribution volume from year t–3 to year t–1, to measure the media attention on a focal director, where year t is the year in which directors voted on a proposal.
Independent director
We operationalized Independent Director as a dummy variable; a value of 1 indicates that a director is an independent director at the focal firm. Independence is also a control variable in the main effect model.
Control variables
We controlled for several variables at the individual level in our main analysis. Director's gender was coded as 1 if the director was male, and as 0 otherwise. Director's age is the age of the director in the year of the vote on the proposal. Director's education level was assigned a value in the range 1 to 5 (1: primary school; 2: secondary school; 3: bachelor's degree; 4: master's degree; 5: doctorate). Paid Director was coded as 1 if the director received a salary from the focal listed firm, and as 0 if the director received a salary from the shareholder company or received only an allowance from the focal listed firm. We also controlled for the professional background of directors using the following dummy variables: Politician director was coded as 1 if the director was a former official in the government, and as 0 otherwise. Academic director was coded as 1 if the director was a current or former scholar in a university or a research institute, and as 0 otherwise. Finance director was coded as 1 if the director had work experience in the finance field, such as the banking and investment business, and as 0 otherwise. Foreign experience was coded as 1 if the director had studied or worked abroad, and as 0 otherwise. Furthermore, we controlled for the total number of directorships (#Directorship) of the director, which was the number of director positions that the director held in both listed and non-listed firms in the focal year. We also controlled for the director's tenure (measured in months) on the focal board. We controlled for the relationship between the director and chairperson because studies have shown that this relationship significantly influences the director's voting behavior (Coles, Daniel, & Naveen, Reference Coles, Daniel and Naveen2014; Khanna, Kim, & Lu, Reference Khanna, Kim and Lu2015; Ma & Khanna, Reference Ma and Khanna2016). In our study, co-opted tie was coded as 1 for directors who were appointed by a board chair, and as 0 for others. In addition, we controlled for the duration (measured in months) for which the director worked together with the chairperson (Coworktime).
We controlled for several variables at the board and firm level in our robustness check models. At the board level, we controlled for board size, the number of committees (#Committee), the percentage of independent directors (% Independent), tenure dispersion, and CEO duality. The variable board size represents the total number of directors on the board, #Committee is the total number of committees formed by board members, and % Independent is the fraction of independent directors on the board. The variable tenure dispersion represents the standard deviation of the tenures of all of the directors on the same board, scaled by the mean values. CEO duality was coded as 1 if the CEO was also the board chair, and as 0 otherwise.
At the firm level, we controlled for firm size, leverage, state ownership, cross-listing, firm performance, ownership concentration, and indicators of related-party transactions (RPTs). Firm size is the natural logarithm of the total assets, and leverage is the ratio between total liabilities and total assets. State ownership is captured by a dummy variable equal to 1 if the firm was controlled by the state or shareholders associated with the state, and 0 otherwise. For cross-listing, we controlled for BHList, a dummy variable equal to 1 if the firm issued B-shares on Chinese stock exchanges for foreign accounts or H-shares on the Hong Kong Stock Exchange. We used two indicators to measure firm performance: ROA and Tobin's Q. ROA is the return on asset and Tobin's Q is the sum of stock market capitalization and the book value of liabilities is divided by total assets. ROA captures firm financial performance while Tobin's Q captures firm value in the capital market. Ownership concentration was measured using the Herfindahl index of the share ratio of the top 10 shareholders. RPTs are widely recognized as the most common form of potential expropriation by outside shareholders. We used two measures to capture RPTs: the net value of other accounts receivables (AR) and the total value of bank loans guaranteed by the company on behalf of a related party (Guarantee). AR is the difference between other receivables and other payables due to RPTs, scaled by total assets, and Guarantee is the total value of the bank loans guaranteed by the company on behalf of a related party (e.g., subsidiaries and affiliates), scaled by the firm's equity.
Education-related information was missing in approximately 64% of the observations. To ensure the presence of a large number of samples in our analysis, we replaced a missing value with the mean value. To attenuate the influence of extreme values, #Directorship, tenure, coworktime, board size, #Committee, % Independent, tenure dispersion, firm size, leverage, ROA, Tobin's Q, ownership concentration, AR, and guarantee were winsorized at the top and bottom 1%.
Estimation Strategy
In our main analysis, we applied the conditional logit model grouped at the proposal level for model estimation. Following Jiang et al. (Reference Jiang, Wan and Zhao2016), our main regression includes the following proposal fixed effects:
where Dissenti,j,k,t is a dummy variable that is equal to 1 if director i in firm j casts a vote of dissent on proposal k at time t. DirectorChari,t is a vector of variables that describe the network position characteristics of directors. Control is a vector of control variables, which have been described in the subsection Definitions of Variables. Furthermore, α k is the proposal fixed effect, and $\varepsilon _{i.j.k.t}$ is the residual. We did not include firm-level or board-level control variables in our model because in the conditional logit model, the proposal fixed effect automatically subsumes unobserved heterogeneity at the firm, board, proposal, and time-period levels (Jiang et al., Reference Jiang, Wan and Zhao2016). In the data analysis, firm- and board-level variables were excluded from the estimation. This identification helps filter out board formation and proposal inclusion, which are the two most important sources of endogeneity, and relies on the variation in directors' vote outcomes within the same proposal. Using this method, we identified a ‘local average treatment effect’ on the conditional sample of a proposal involving dissent. Based on this model specification, we constructed Panel A.
Although Jiang et al. (Reference Jiang, Wan and Zhao2016) showed that the conditional logit model grouped at the proposal level has fewer endogeneity problems than other models such as the ordinary logit model and provides relatively clean identification for the causes of dissent, we reran the main effect model by applying the conditional logit model grouped at the firm level; the results are presented in the subsection Robustness Checks. This regression includes proposal type fixed effects, firm fixed effects, and year fixed effects, as well as firm-level and board-level control variables. Based on this model specification, we constructed Panel B. The sample size of Panel B was smaller than that of Panel A because some board-level and firm-level control variables were missing for some of the observations.
Summary Statistics
Table 1 shows the distribution of proposal types with at least one vote of dissent from the main sample. Excluding miscellaneous issues, the top four categories, which account for approximately half of the sample, address the following issues: (1) director and officer selection, appointment, and turnover (14.85%), (2) financial reporting (14.34%), (3) investment and M&A (14.01%), and (4) board or shareholder meeting agenda (6.16%). Table 2 shows the descriptive statistics for Panel A.
Notes: Degree(per), Closeness(per), Betweenness(per), and Eigenvector(per) are percentile values of the centrality measures. Principal is the first principal component of Degree(per), Closeness(per), Betweenness(per), and Eigenvector(per) centrality measures.
Table 3 shows the descriptive statistics for Panel B, and Table 4 shows the pairwise correlations matrix for all of the variables. The correlations between director centrality variables and dissent are negative. Considering that central directors have a greater number of options for board positions and firms with good corporate governance may have a smaller extent of dissent, this negative correlation is likely to be driven by the selection problem – central directors are more likely to have a seat on a board at a firm with good corporate governance, therefore, may cast fewer votes of dissent. We need to address this problem in our model specification to avoid spurious relationships.
Note: Correlation coefficients in bold indicate significance at the 0.05 level or better.
Results
Table 5 shows the results of the conditional logit regression on dissent voting by directors. Director centrality is measured by degree in Model 1, closeness in Model 2, betweenness in Model 3, the eigenvector in Model 4, and the principal component in Model 5. We use each of these centrality measurements to test Hypothesis 1. The coefficients in the tables are the original log-odds ratios. Therefore, it is easy to transform them to the ratio of odds ratios by using the exponential function.
Notes: ***p < 0.005, **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05, +p < 0.1. Standard errors in parentheses.
We discuss the results of the hypothesis testing. Controlling for director characteristics, director centrality is statistically significant and positive at the 1% level in Model 1, and statistically significant and positive at the 0.5% level in Model 2 to Model 5. The significantly positive coefficient for the principal component of centralities in Model 5 implies that the four centrality indicators have a substantial joint influence on directors' propensity to dissent. Considering this joint influence of the four indicators, directors occupying central positions within the board interlock network have a stronger tendency to dissent; thus, Hypothesis 1 is supported. We interpret the results by considering Model 5. The odds ratio for principal component of centrality indicators is approximately 1.112 (exp (0.106)), which indicates that a 1-unit increase in director centrality is associated with an 11.2% increase in the odds of dissent versus non-dissent (1.112−1). The probability of drawing an incorrect inference about this positive relationship is less than 0.5%.
Table 6 shows the results of all moderating effects.Footnote 1 In Model 3, the coefficient of the interaction term of director centrality and Big Four audit is statistically significant and negative (coefficient = −0.546, p < 0.01), which indicates that the positive relationship between director centrality and the probability of dissent is weaker for firms audited by the Big Four. To facilitate interpretation and further investigate whether the hypotheses are supported, we plotted the predicted probabilities (Figure 1a) and the marginal effects of centrality on director dissent (Figure 1b). To create Figure 1a, we set all variables other than centrality and Big Four audit in Model 3 of Table 6 to their sample means. In Figure 1a, we can find that for firms without Big Four audit, as centrality increases from 5 to 95% of the range, the predicted probability of dissent would increase from 7.17% to 12.45%, representing a 73.64% increase. However, for firms with Big Four audit, as centrality increases from 5 to 95% of the range, the predicted probability of dissent would decrease rather than increase. Besides, we can find in Figure 1b that the marginal effects of centrality on the probability of dissent are all positive and significant (the confidence interval does not include zero) for firms without Big Four audit. However, the marginal effects of centrality on the probability of dissent are not significantly different from zero (the confidence interval includes zero) for firms with Big Four audit, In general, Hypothesis 2 is supported.
Notes: ***p < 0.005, **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05, +p < 0.1. Standard errors in parentheses. Director centrality variables are standardized. The main effect of Big4 audit is omitted, because it is invariant within a specific proposal.
In Model 4, the coefficient of the interaction term of director centrality and media mention is statistically significant and negative (coefficient = −0.163, p < 0.005), which indicates that the positive relationship between director centrality and the probability of dissent is weaker for directors who have a greater number of media mentions. Similarly, we plotted the predicted probabilities (Figure 2a) and the marginal effects of centrality on director dissent (Figure 2b). To create Figure 2a, we set all variables other than centrality and media mention in Model 4 of Table 6 to their sample means. In Figure 2a, we can find that for directors without media mention, as centrality increases from 5 to 95% of the range, the predicted probability of dissent would increase from 7.20% to 12.13%, representing a 68.47% increase. However, for directors with media mention, as centrality increases from 5 to 95% of the range, the predicted probability of dissent has barely changed. Besides, we can find in Figure 2b that the marginal effects of centrality on the probability of dissent are all positive and significant (the confidence interval does not include zero) for directors without media mention. However, the marginal effects of centrality on the probability of dissent are not significantly different from zero (the confidence interval includes zero) for directors with media mention. In general, Hypothesis 3 is supported.
Model 5 shows the results of the moderating effect of director type. We find that the coefficient of the interaction term of director centrality and independent director is statistically significant and negative (coefficient = −0.230, p < 0.005), which indicates that the positive relationship between director centrality and the probability of dissent is weaker for independent directors. Similarly, we plotted the predicted probabilities (Figure 3a) and the marginal effects of centrality on director dissent (Figure 3b). To create Figure 3a, we set all variables other than centrality and independent director in Model 5 of Table 6 to their sample means. In Figure 3a, we can find that for directors who are not independent directors, as centrality increases from 5 to 95% of the range, the predicted probability of dissent would increase from 8.37% to 20.42%, representing a 143.97% increase. However, for independent directors, as centrality increases from 5 to 95% of the range, the predicted probability of dissent has barely changed. Besides, we can find in Figure 3b that the marginal effects of centrality on the probability of dissent are all positive and significant (the confidence interval does not include zero) for those who are not independent directors. However, the marginal effects of centrality on the probability of dissent are not significantly different from zero (the confidence interval includes zero) for independent directors. In general, Hypothesis 4 is supported.
Robustness Checks
To ensure the robustness of our results, we conducted a battery of additional analyses by (1) applying the conditional logit model with the board- and firm-level control variables; (2) performing propensity score match (PSM) at the director-year level and rerunning the main effects; (3) using alternative proxy variables for moderators; and (4) regressing dissent to network indicators to exclude reverse causality. The results of (1)–(3) are generally consistent with those obtained using the baseline specification model shown in Table 5, and we do not find evidence in support of reverse causality between dissent and director centrality. All of the results are available in the Supplementary Appendix.
Discussion
This study was motivated by the lack of understanding of directors’ monitoring behavior and its antecedents, especially from a social perspective (Westphal & Zajac, Reference Westphal and Zajac2013). Drawing on social network and corporate governance research, we developed a framework of the effects of directors’ positions within the board interlock network on their dissenting behaviors. In line with our argument, we find that directors who occupy central positions in the board's interlocking network are more likely to dissent. Our results also show that this positive relationship is weaker for firms with greater transparency and directors with a greater number of media mentions, supporting the information and reputation mechanisms described in our arguments. Furthermore, we find that the effect of a director's network centrality on dissent is contingent on director type. The effect is weaker for independent directors. Considered together, these findings have several important implications.
Contributions to Theory and Practice
Given that it is exceptionally challenging to effectively monitor a corporate board, it is essential to identify people who could perform this task well (Hambrick et al., Reference Hambrick, Misangyi and Park2015). The first step is to examine why directors may have the capability and motivation for effective monitoring (Cowen & Marcel, Reference Cowen and Marcel2011). To the best of our knowledge, this study is the first to investigate how network positions influence director dissent and to examine the underlying information and reputation mechanisms. Adopting an information-processing perspective, Boivie, Bednar, et al. (Reference Boivie, Bednar, Aguilera and Andrus2016) proposed that boards are essentially groups of individuals obtaining, processing, and sharing information. We extend this stream of research by studying how a social network can supplement the information set of directors and facilitate effective monitoring. In general, we respond to Westphal and Zajac's (Reference Westphal and Zajac2013) call for a behavioral theory of corporate governance by examining the socially situated and socially constituted agency.
We find that for the same centrality of positions, independent directors are likely to project a reputation of being passive directors. This significant finding extends the findings of Li et al. (Reference Li, Krause, Qin, Zhang, Zhu, Lin and Xu2018) who used an experimental design and reported that boardroom transparency drives directors who are inclined toward vigilant monitoring to become more vigilant and directors who are inclined toward passive monitoring to become more passive. Although the findings of Li et al. (Reference Li, Krause, Qin, Zhang, Zhu, Lin and Xu2018) offered insights and showed strong internal validity, the study lacked significant external validity owing to the experimental design. In our study, we improved the external validity of research on director voting through analyses of archival data.
Our findings have two major implications for theory and research on the board interlock network. First, while researchers have typically emphasized the importance of the inter-organizational nature of the board interlock network in determining alliance formation and dissolution (Gulati & Westphal, Reference Gulati and Westphal1999; Yue, Reference Yue2012) and practice diffusion (Galaskiewicz & Burt, Reference Galaskiewicz and Burt1991; Haunschild, Reference Haunschild1994), the results of this study suggest that the interpersonal nature of the board interlock network may also be an important determinant of a firm's behaviors and outcomes, such as board effectiveness.
Second, our study contributes to the emerging literature on the micro-foundations of a social network (Tasselli et al., Reference Tasselli, Kilduff and Menges2015). Social network research has long assumed that motivation and opportunity can be treated ‘as one and the same’ (Burt, Reference Burt1992: 36). However, the opportunity to access and leverage information does not necessarily indicate that actors have the capability to process information and the motivation to realize their potential. We extend current research by demonstrating that network actors may have different levels of information-processing capability and motivation. A more comprehensive analysis of the determinants of network actors’ behaviors should consider both the structures of the relationships and the properties of the nodes, such as roles, interests, motivations, and capabilities (Phelps, Heidl, & Wadhwa, Reference Phelps, Heidl and Wadhwa2012; Shipilov & Li, Reference Shipilov and Li2012; Tasselli et al., Reference Tasselli, Kilduff and Menges2015).
Limitations and Directions for Future Research
Our study has several limitations, which can serve as opportunities for future studies. First, due to the nature of archival data, we were unable to directly measure the underlying mechanisms of information and reputation. Future research could obtain additional insights by using other research designs, such as surveys, experiments, and case studies. These methods could be used to verify our results and provide a more nuanced examination of the decision-making process in director monitoring. Future research could also use more refined measures as moderators. For example, the use of fine-grained measures of information-processing capability and various concerns collected at the individual director level could improve the accuracy of our theoretical predictions.
Second, we focus on theorizing at the individual director level, thus providing several opportunities for future exploration. Individual voice and dissent in general, and board monitoring in particular, could be determined by environmental, firm, board climate, and position characteristics (Boivie, Bednar, et al., Reference Boivie, Bednar, Aguilera and Andrus2016; Hambrick et al., Reference Hambrick, Misangyi and Park2015; Zhou, Shin, Brass, Choi, & Zhang, Reference Zhou, Shin, Brass, Choi and Zhang2009). Therefore, future studies could obtain more insights by incorporating additional factors into the theoretical framework. In a similar vein, as an explorative study, we focused on only one network position and its influence on a specific behavior of directors. Future studies could examine other social network indicators, other social contexts, and other behaviors of directors, such as departure and exit from the firm.
Third, our sample was drawn from directors in publicly listed Chinese firms; therefore, the results should be carefully considered when generalizing the findings to other economies. We believe that the core concept of directors having information barriers and various reputation concerns during their monitoring process and the finding that directors who occupy positions of greater centrality dissent to a greater extent also apply to broader contexts. However, the results related to the moderating effect of director types must be carefully examined because different director characteristics may exist in other institutional and market contexts.
Conclusion
Despite these limitations, to the best of our knowledge, our study is among the first to examine the relationship between directors’ network positions and their dissenting behavior on boards. By investigating the contingent governance effects of directors’ network centrality, our study integrates and contributes to multiple streams of literature on boards of directors, board interlocks, and corporate governance in emerging economies. Thus, our study offers new insights and opens up many new areas of research in an effort to answer the broader question of what constitutes effective monitoring in corporate governance.
Supplementary material
The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/mor.2023.29
Data availability statement
Replication code for this article has been published in Open Science Framework at: https://osf.io/c3a74/
Hong Zhang ([email protected]) is a postdoctoral researcher at the Guanghua School of Management, Peking University, where he also obtained his PhD. His current research interests include non-market strategy, firm innovation, and strategic leadership. He has published his research in journals such as Management and Organization Review and Technological Forecasting and Social Change.
Zimin Liu ([email protected]) is a PhD candidate at the Guanghua School of Management, Peking University. Her current research interests include strategic leadership, creativity and innovation, and micro-foundations of strategy.
Weiguo Zhong ([email protected]) is an Associate Professor of Strategy at the Guanghua School of Management, Peking University. He received his PhD from the City University of Hong Kong. His research interests include firm innovation, non-market strategy, and internationalization strategy of multinational companies from emerging markets. He has published his research in journals such as the Academy of Management Journal, Journal of International Business Studies, Journal of Management, and Management and Organization Review.