Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dsjbd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T09:15:30.589Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE WEALTH DISTRIBUTION AND THE DEMAND FOR STATUS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 May 2009

Yulei Luo
Affiliation:
University of Hong Kong
Eric R. Young*
Affiliation:
University of Virginia
*
Address correspondence to: Dr. Eric R. Young, Department of Economics, University of Virginia, Charlottesville, VA 22904, USA; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

Standard economic theories of asset markets assume that assets are valued entirely for the consumption streams they can finance. This paper examines the introduction of the demand for status (as a function of wealth) into a model of uninsurable idiosyncratic risk—the “spirit of capitalism” (“soc”) assumption. We find that soc preferences lead to less inequality in wealth; placing wealth into the utility function leads to a shrinking wealth distribution. The drop in wealth concentration is smaller if the utility function implies status is a luxury good, but no parametrization leads to higher wealth Gini coefficients than the benchmark case. We then consider the consequences of revenue-neutral tax reforms with and without soc preferences, finding that they make little difference for this policy experiment.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Aiyagari, S. Rao (1994) Uninsured idiosyncratic risk and aggregate saving. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, 659684.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aiyagari, S. Rao (1995) Optimal capital income taxation with incomplete markets, borrowing constraints, and constant discounting. Journal of Political Economy 103, 11581175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aiyagari, S. Rao and Alvarez, Fernando (2001) Efficient Dynamic Monitoring of Unemployment Insurance Claims. Mimeo, University of Chicago.Google Scholar
Aiyagari, S. Rao and McGrattan, Ellen R. (1998) The optimum quantity of debt. Journal of Monetary Economics 42, 447469.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bakshi, Gurdip S. and Chen, Zhiwu (1996) The spirit of capitalism and stock-market prices. American Economic Review 86, 133157.Google Scholar
Boileau, Martin and Brown, Rebecca W. (2007) The spirit of capitalism, asset returns, and the business cycle. Macroeconomic Dynamics 11, 214230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boskin, Michael J. and Sheshiski, Eytan (1978) Optimal redistributive taxation when individual welfare depends on relative income. Quarterly Journal of Economics 92, 589601.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Budría Rodríguez, Santiago, Díaz-Giménez, Javier, Quadrini, Vicenzo, and Ríos-Rull, José-Víctor (2002) Updated facts on the U.S. distributions of earnings, income, and wealth. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 26, 235.Google Scholar
Carroll, Christopher D. (2002) Portfolios of the rich. In Guiso, Luigi, Haliassos, Michael, and Jappelli, Tullio (eds.), Household Portfolios: Theory and Evidence. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Carroll, Christopher D. (2004) Theoretical Foundations of Buffer Stock Savings. NBER Working Paper 10867.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castañeda, Ana, Díaz-Giménez, Javier, and Ríos-Rull, José-Víctor (2003) Accounting for wealth and income inequality. Journal of Political Economy 111, 818857.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chue, Timothy K. (2004) The Spirit of Capitalism and International Risk Sharing. Econometric Society 2004 Far Eastern Meetings Working Paper 589.Google Scholar
Conesa, Juan Carlos, Kitao, Sagiri, and Krueger, Dirk (2007) Taxing Capital? Not a Bad Idea After All! Mimeo, Goethe University.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conesa, Juan Carlos and Krueger, Dirk (2006) On the optimal progressivity of the income tax code. Journal of Monetary Economics 53, 14251450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corneo, Giacomo (2002) The efficient side of progressive income taxation. European Economic Review 46, 13591368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dávila, Julio, Hong, Jay H., Krusell, Per, and Ríos-Rull, José-Víctor (2006) Constrained-Efficient Allocations in the Growth Model with Idiosyncratic Shocks. Mimeo, University of Pennsylvania.Google Scholar
Díaz-Giménez, Javier and Pijoan-Mas, Josep (2006) Flat Tax Reforms in the U.S.: A Boon for the Income Poor. CEPR Discussion Paper 5812.Google Scholar
De Nardi, Mariacristina, (2004) Wealth inequality and intergenerational links. Review of Economic Studies 71, 743768.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Domeij, David and Heathcote, Jonathan (2004) On the distributional effects of reducing capital taxes. International Economic Review 45, 523554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duesenberry, James S. (1949) Income, Saving, and the Theory of Consumer Behavior. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Eicher, Theo, Prunera, Maria Carmen Riera, and Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2003) Tax policy and inequality: Empirical and theoretical implications. In Eicher, Theo and Turnovsky, Stephen J. (eds.), Growth and Inequality: Issues and Policy Implications. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Floden, Martin and Lindé, Jesper (2001) Idiosyncratic risk in the United States and Sweden: Is there a role for government insurance? Review of Economic Dynamics 4, 406437.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Francis, Johanna L. (2005a) Life Cycle Saving and the Capitalist Spirit. Mimeo, Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore, MD.Google Scholar
Francis, Johanna L. (2005b) Entrepreneurs and the Capitalist Spirit. Mimeo, Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore, MD.Google Scholar
Gong, Liutang and Zou, Heng-fu (2002) Direct preferences for wealth, the risk premium puzzle, growth, and policy effectiveness. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 26, 247270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gouveia, Miguel and Strauss, Robert P. (1994) Effective federal individual tax functions: An exploratory empirical analysis. National Tax Journal 47, 317339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hadar, Josef and Russell, William R. (1969) Rules for ordering uncertain prospects. American Economic Review 49, 2534.Google Scholar
Kenc, Turalay and Dibooğlu, Sel (2007) The spirit of capitalism, asset pricing and growth in a small open economy. Journal of International Money and Finance 26 (8), 13781402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kongsamut, Piyabha, Rebelo, Sergio, and Xie, Danyang (2001) Beyond balanced growth. Review of Economic Studies 68, 869882.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Dirk and Lustig, Hanno (2007) When Is Market Incompleteness Irrelevant for the Price of Aggregate Risk? Mimeo, University of Pennsylvania and UCLA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krusell, Per, Quadrini, Vincenzo, and Ríos-Rull, José-Víctor (1996) Are consumption taxes really better than income taxes? Journal of Monetary Economics 37, 475503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krusell, Per and Smith, Anthony A. Jr., (1997) Income and wealth heterogeneity, portfolio choice, and equilibrium asset returns. Macroeconomic Dynamics 1, 387422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krusell, Per and Smith, Anthony A. Jr. (1998) Income and wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy. Journal of Political Economy 106, 867896.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krusell, Per and Smith, Anthony A. Jr. (2002) Revisiting the Welfare Effects of Eliminating Business Cycles. Mimeo, Princeton University and Yale University.Google Scholar
Krusell, Per and Stavlöt, Ulrika (2005) On the Origins of Diversity of Culture Consumption. Mimeo, Princeton University.Google Scholar
Lettau, Martin (1997) Comment on “The Spirit of Capitalism and Stock Market Prices” by G. S. Bakshi and Chen, Z. (AER, 1996). Tilburg University, Center for Economic Research Discussion Paper 49.Google Scholar
Pjioan-Mas, Josep (2006) Precautionary savings or working longer hours? Review of Economic Dynamics 9, 326352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reiter, Michael (2004) Do the Rich Save Too Much? How to Explain the Top Tail of the Wealth Distribution. Mimeo, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.Google Scholar
Robson, Arthur J. (1992) Status, the distribution of wealth, private and social attitude to risk. Econometrica 60, 837857.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothschild, Michael and Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1970) Increasing risk I: A Definition. Journal of Economic Theory 2, 225243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, William T. (2001) How does the spirit of capitalism affect stock market prices? Review of Financial Studies: 14 12151232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tauchen, George (1986) Finite state Markov-chain approximations to univariate and vector autoregressions. Economics Letters 20 (2), 177181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ventura, Gustavo (1999) Flat tax reform: A quantitative exploration. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 23, 14251458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, Eric R. (2004) Unemployment insurance and capital accumulation. Journal of Monetary Economics 51, 16831710.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young., Eric R. (2005) Approximate Aggregation. Mimeo, University of Virginia.Google Scholar
Zou, Heng-fu (1994) The spirit of capitalism and long-run growth. European Journal of Political Economy 10, 279293.CrossRefGoogle Scholar