Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gbm5v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T06:34:47.002Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE TWO REVOLUTIONS, LANDED ELITES, AND EDUCATION DURING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 January 2019

Duarte N. Leite
Affiliation:
Max Planck Institute for Social Law and Social Policy
Óscar Afonso*
Affiliation:
University of Porto
Sandra T. Silva
Affiliation:
University of Porto
*
Address correspondence to: Oscar Afonso, Universidade do Porto, Faculdade de Economia, CEFUP, CEFAGE and OBEGEF, Rua Dr Roberto Frias, 4200-464, Porto, Portugal; e-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

Understanding the causes of the Industrial Revolution, namely the process of transition from a Malthusian equilibrium to modern economic growth, has been the subject of passionate debate. This paper contributes to insights into the process of industrialization and the demographic transition that followed. We present a model that proposes a mechanism behind the claim that landed elites had strong incentives to block education reforms. By applying the theory of interest groups to landownership, landowners could delay education. However, they could not prevent its introduction indefinitely since gains for the landed elites derived from education would at some moment surpass the costs associated with them. We also sustain that improvements in agricultural productivity prior to the Industrial Revolution may have induced a positive impact on the landowners’ decision to educate the population, which led to an earlier introduction of education reforms. The conclusions fit the patterns of the late boom of industrialization and demographic transition and help explain why some countries (e.g., Britain and The Netherlands) had accelerated education reforms and a faster process of industrialization than most continental countries. A theoretical model is presented, and numerical simulations are exhibited to illustrate our claims.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© 2019 Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We particularly thank Oded Galor and Pedro Mazeda Gil, an editor as well as two anonymous referees for all the very helpful suggestions in previous versions of this paper. We also greatly benefited from the comments of the seminar and conference participants at Brown University, University of Porto, and PEJ conference. Andrea Villeneuve delivered excellent research assistance. The usual disclaimer applies. This study was funded by FCT, Portugal, and FEDER/COMPETE 2020, through grant UID/ECO/04007/2013 (respectively, POCI-01-0145-FEDER-006890 and POCI-01-0145-FEDER-007659).

References

Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2006) Economic backwardness in political perspective. The American Political Science Review 100(1), 115131.10.1017/S0003055406062046CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2012) Why Nations Fail, the Origins of Power and Prosperity. New York: Crown.10.1355/ae29-2jCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Afonso, O. and Magalhães, M. (2018) How powerful are network effects? A skill-biased technological change approach. Macroeconomic Dynamics 138. doi:10.1017/S1365100518000524.Google Scholar
Allen, R. C. (1988) The growth of labor productivity in early modern English agriculture. Explorations in Economic History 25(2), 117146.10.1016/0014-4983(88)90013-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, R. C. (1999) Tracking the agricultural revolution in England. The Economic History Review 52(2), 209235.10.1111/1468-0289.00123CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, R. C. (2009) The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511816680CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashraf, Q. and Galor, O. (2011a) Cultural Diversity, Geographical Isolation, and the Origin of the Wealth of Nations. National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Papers: No. 17640.10.3386/w17640CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashraf, Q. and Galor, O. (2011b) Dynamics and stagnation in the Malthusian epoch. American Economic Review 101(5), 20032041.10.1257/aer.101.5.2003CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ashraf, Q. and Galor, O. (2013) The ‘Out of Africa’ hypothesis, human genetic diversity, and comparative economic development. American Economic Review 103(1), 146.10.1257/aer.103.1.1CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Banerjee, A. and Iyer, L. (2005) History, institutions, and economic performance: The legacy of colonial land tenure systems in India. American Economic Review 95(4), 11901213.10.1257/0002828054825574CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, S., Cinnirella, F. and Woessmann, L. (2010) The trade-off between fertility and education: Evidence from before the demographic transition. Journal of Economic Growth 15(3), 177204.10.1007/s10887-010-9054-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, S., Cinnirella, F. and Woessmann, L. (2012) The effect of investment in children’s education on fertility in 1816 Prussia. Cliometrica 6(1), 2944.10.1007/s11698-011-0061-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bourguignon, F. and Verdier, T. (2000) Oligarchy, democracy, inequality and growth. Journal of Development Economics 62, 285313.10.1016/S0304-3878(00)00086-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadberry, S., Campbell, B. M. S. and van Leeuwen, B. (2013) When did Britain industrialise? The sectoral distribution of the labour force and labour productivity in Britain, 1381–1851. Explorations in Economic History 50(1), 1627.10.1016/j.eeh.2012.08.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, R. (1991) Society and Economy in Modern Britain 1700–1850. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Cervellati, M. and Sunde, U. (2005) Human capital formation, life expectancy, and the process of development. American Economic Review 95(5), 16531672.10.1257/000282805775014380CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Clark, G. (1993) Agriculture and the industrial revolution, 1700-1850. In: Mokyr, J (ed.), The British Industrial Revolution: An Economic Perspective, pp. 227266. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Clark, G. (2002) Land rental values and the agrarian economy: England and Wales, 1500–1914. European Review of Economic History 6(3), 281308.10.1017/S136149160200014XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cubberley, E. P. (1920) The History of Education: Educational Practice and Progress Considered as a Phase of the Development and Spread of Western Civilization. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The Riverside Press.Google Scholar
Diamond, J. (1997) Guns, Germs and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies. New York: W. W. Norton & Co.Google Scholar
Ekelund, R. B. and Tollison, R. D. (1997) Politicized Economies: Monarchy, Monopoly and Mercantilism. Texas: Texas A&M University Press.Google Scholar
Elgin, C. (2012) A theory of economic development with endogenous fertility. Macroeconomic Dynamics 16, 686705.10.1017/S1365100510000842CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engerman, S. L. and Sokoloff, K. L. (2000) Institutions, factor endowments, and paths of development in the new world. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(3), 217232.Google Scholar
Flora, P., Kraus, F. and Pfenning, W. (1983) State, Economy, and Society in Western Europe 1815-1975: The Growth of Industrial Societies and Capitalist Economies. London: Palgrave Macmillan.10.1007/978-1-349-06936-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. (2005) The demographic transition and the emergence of sustained economic growth. Journal of the European Economic Association 3(2–3), 494504.10.1162/jeea.2005.3.2-3.494CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. (2011) Unified Growth Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Galor, O. and Moav, O. (2002) Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4), 11331191.10.1162/003355302320935007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. and Moav, O. (2006) Das human-kapital: A theory of the demise of the class structure. Review of Economic Studies 73(1), 8511710.1111/j.1467-937X.2006.00370.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O., Moav, O. and Vollrath, D. (2009) Inequality in landownership, the emergence of human-capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence. The Review of Economic Studies 76(1), 143179.10.1111/j.1467-937X.2008.00506.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Galor, O. and Özak, Ö. (2016) The agricultural origins of time preference. American Economic Review 106(10), 30643103.10.1257/aer.20150020CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Galor, O. and Weil, D. N. (2000) Population, technology, and growth: From Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. American Economic Review 90(4), 806828.10.1257/aer.90.4.806CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goni, M. (2016) Landed Elites and Education Provision in England and Wales. Evidence from School Boards, 1870-99. Working Paper University of Vienna, Mimeo.Google Scholar
Green, A. (1990) Education and State Formation: The Rise of Education Systems in England, France and the USA. Hampshire, UK: Macmillan Palgrave.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (1989) Reputation and coalitions in medieval trade: Evidence on the Maghribi traders. Journal of Economic History 49, 857882.10.1017/S0022050700009475CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, H. I. and Kim, M. (2003) Education policy: Egalitarian or elitist? Economics and Politics 15, 225246.10.1111/1468-0343.00123CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, B. E. (2001) The new econometrics of structural change: Dating breaks in U.S. labour productivity. Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(4), 117128.10.1257/jep.15.4.117CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, G. D. and Prescott, E. C. (2002) Malthus and solow. American Economic Review 92(4), 12051217.10.1257/00028280260344731CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. I. and Romer, P. M. (2010) The new Kaldor facts: Ideas, institutions, population, and human capital. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2(1), 224245.Google Scholar
Lagerlöf, N. P. (2006) The Galor–Weil model revisited: A quantitative exercise. Review of Economic Dynamics 9(1), 116142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landes, D. (1998) The Wealth and Poverty of Nations. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Lee, R. (2003) The demographic transition: Three centuries of fundamental change. Journal of Economic Perspectives 17(4), 167190.10.1257/089533003772034943CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Litina, A. (2016) Natural land productivity, cooperation and comparative development. Journal of Economic Growth 21, 351408.10.1007/s10887-016-9134-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lizzeri, A. and Persico, N. (2004) Why did the elites extend the suffrage? Democracy and the scope of government, with an application to Britain’s “age of reform”. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(2), 707765.10.1162/0033553041382175CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maddison, A. (2003) The World Economy: Historical Statistics. Paris: Development Centre Studies, OECD.10.1787/9789264104143-enCrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, D. N. (1972) The enclosure of open fields: Preface to a study of its impact on the efficiency of English agriculture in the eighteenth century. The Journal of Economic History 32(1), 1535.10.1017/S0022050700075379CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miyagiwa, K. and Papageorgiou, C. (2007) Endogenous aggregate elasticity of substitution. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 31, 28992919.10.1016/j.jedc.2006.06.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, J. (1990) The Lever of Riches, Technological Creativity and Economic Progress. New York and London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. (2009) The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain 1700–1850. Cornwall: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Murphy, T. E. (2010) Old Habits Die Hard (Sometimes): Can Département Heterogeneity Tell Us Something about the French Fertility Decline? Working Paper Series. Milan, Innocenzo Gasparini Institute for Economic Research.Google Scholar
Neto, A., Afonso, O. and Silva, S. (2018) How powerful are trade unions? A skill-biased technological change approach. Macroeconomic Dynamics 145. doi:10.1017/S1365100516001346.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge Press University.10.1017/CBO9780511808678CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. and Thomas, R. P. (1973) The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511819438CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M. (1982) The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Overton, M. (1996) Agricultural Revolution in England: The Transformation of the Agrarian Economy 1500–1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511607967CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porta, R. L., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1999) The quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 15(1), 222279.10.1093/jleo/15.1.222CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A. and Trebbi, F. (2004) Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth 9(2), 131165.10.1023/B:JOEG.0000031425.72248.85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stephens, W. (1998) Education in Britain, 1750 - 1914: Social History in Perspective. New York: St. Martin’s Press.10.1007/978-1-349-27231-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, R. and Dimsdale, N. (2017) A millenium of UK Data. http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/research/Pages/onebank/threecenturies.aspx.Google Scholar
Thompson, F. M. L. (1968) The second agricultural revolution, 1815-1880. The Economic History Review 21(1), 6277.Google Scholar
Voigtländer, N. and Voth, H. J. (2006) Why England? Demographic factors, structural change and physical capital accumulation during the Industrial Revolution. Journal of Economic Growth 11(4), 319361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Leite et al. supplementary material

Appendix

Download Leite et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 1.4 MB