Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T06:44:04.805Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

OIL DEPENDENCE, INTERNATIONAL BORROWINGS, AND ECONOMIC INSTABILITY IN A SMALL OPEN ECONOMY

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 August 2016

Ching-chong Lai*
Affiliation:
Institute of Economics, Academia Sinica, National Cheng-Chi University, National Sun Yat-Sen University, and Feng Chia University
Chi-ting Chin
Affiliation:
Ming Chuan University
Kuan-jen Chen
Affiliation:
Fu-Jen Catholic University
*
Address correspondence to: Ching-chong Lai, Institute of Economics, Academia Sinica, Nankang, Taipei 115, Taiwan; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

The existing literature dealing with mutual interactions between the extent of oil dependence and the possibility of belief-driven fluctuations unanimously ignores international loans. This simplified assumption disregards the fact that the relative magnitude of the financial account and the trade account exhibits an increasing trend. Faced with this deficiency in the literature, this paper develops a real business cycle model featuring oil dependence in domestic production and international loans, and examines whether both the presence of international borrowings and the dependence on imported energy will govern the emergence of belief-driven fluctuations.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We are deeply grateful to two anonymous referees for their constructive comments, which substantially improved the paper. We are also indebted to Cheng-wei Chang and Chih-hsing Liao for their helpful suggestions and comments regarding earlier versions of the paper. Any remaining errors or shortcomings are, however, the authors' responsibility. Financial support from the National Science Council of Taiwan, under Grant NSC 101-2410-H-001-008-MY1, is gratefully acknowledged.

References

REFERENCES

Agénor, Pierre-Richard and Montiel, Peter J. (1999) Development Macroeconomics, 2nd ed. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Aguiar-Conraria, Luís and Wen, Yi (2007) Understanding the large negative impact of oil shocks. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39, 925944.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aguiar-Conraria, Luís and Wen, Yi (2008) A note on oil dependence and economic instability. Macroeconomic Dynamics 12, 717723.Google Scholar
Aguiar-Conraria, Luís and Wen, Yi (2012) OPEC's oil exporting strategy and macroeconomic (in)stability. Energy Economics 34, 132136.Google Scholar
Barro, Robert J. and Sala-i-Martin, Xavier (2004) Economic Growth, 2nd ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Basu, Susanto and Fernald, John G. (1997) Returns to scale in U.S. production: Estimates and implications. Journal of Political Economy 105, 249283.Google Scholar
Benhabib, Jess and Farmer, Roger (1994) Indeterminacy and increasing returns. Journal of Economic Theory 63, 1941.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benhabib, Jess and Farmer, Roger (1996) Indeterminacy and sector-specific externalities. Journal of Monetary Economics 37, 421443.Google Scholar
Benhabib, Jess and Wen, Yi (2004) Indeterminacy, aggregate demand, and the real business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 51, 503530.Google Scholar
Bhandari, Jagdeep S. (1981) The simple macroeconomics of an oil-dependent economy. European Economic Review 16, 333354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhandari, Jagdeep S. and Turnovsky, Stephen J. (1984) Materials price increases and aggregate adjustment in an open economy. European Economic Review 25, 151182.Google Scholar
Blanchard, Olivier J. and Riggi, Marianna (2009) Why Are the 2000s So Different from the 1970s? A Structural Interpretation of Changes in the Macroeconomic Effects of Oil Prices. NBER working paper 15467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouza, Serpil and Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2012) The distributional consequences of foreign transfers: Do they reduce or exacerbate inequality? Oxford Economic Papers 64, 702735.Google Scholar
Buiter, Willem H. (1984) Saddlepoint problems in continuous time rational expectations models: A general method and some macroeconomic examples. Econometrica 52, 665680.Google Scholar
Burmeister, Edwin (1980) On some conceptual issues in rational expectations modeling. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 12, 800816.Google Scholar
Burnside, Craig (1996) Production function regressions, returns to scale, and externalities. Journal of Monetary Economics 37, 177201.Google Scholar
Chang, Wen-Ya and Tsai, Hsueh-Fang (2006) Devaluation, capital formation, and the current account. Open Economies Review 17, 341357.Google Scholar
Chin, Chi-Ting, Guo, Jang-Ting, and Lai, Ching-Chong (2012) A note on indeterminacy and investment adjustment costs in an endogenously growing small open economy. Macroeconomic Dynamics 16, 438450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chung, Keunsuk and Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2010) Foreign debt supply in an imperfect international capital market: Theory and evidence. Journal of International Money and Finance 29, 201223.Google Scholar
Cohen, Daniel and Sachs, Jeffrey (1986) Growth and external debt under risk of debt repudiation. European Economic Review 30, 529560.Google Scholar
Correia, Isabel, Neves, Joao C., and Rebelo, Sergio (1995) Business cycles in a small open economy. European Economic Review 39, 10891113.Google Scholar
Djajić, Slobodan (1983) Current-account effects of a temporary change in government expenditure. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 91, 8396.Google Scholar
Edwards, Sebastian (1984) LDC foreign borrowing and default risk: An empirical investigation, 1976–1980. American Economic Review 74, 726734.Google Scholar
Eicher, Theo S., Turnovsky, Stephen J., and Walz, Uwe (2000) Optimal policy for financial market liberalizations: Decentralization and capital flow reversals. German Economic Review 1, 1942.Google Scholar
Findlay, Ronald and Rodriguez, Carlos A. (1977) Intermediate imports and macroeconomic policy under flexible exchange rates. Canadian Journal of Economics 10, 208217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Walter H. (1995) An optimizing analysis of the effects of world interest disturbances on the open economy term structure of interest rates. Journal of International Money and Finance 14, 105126.Google Scholar
Galí, Jordi (2008) Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Garcia-Cicco, Javier, Pancrazi, Roberto, and Uribe, Martin (2010) Real business cycles in emerging countries. American Economic Review 100, 25102531.Google Scholar
Greenwood, Jeremy, Hercowitz, Zvi, and Huffman, Gregory W. (1988) Investment, capacity utilization, and the real business cycle. American Economic Review 78, 402417.Google Scholar
Harrison, Sharon G. (2001) Indeterminacy in a model with sector-specific externalities. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 25, 747764.Google Scholar
Imbens, Guido W., Rubin, Donald B., and Sacerdote, Bruce (2001) Estimating the effect of unearned income on labor supply, earnings, savings and consumption: Evidence from a survey of lottery players. American Economic Review 91, 778794.Google Scholar
Jaimovich, Nir (2008) Income effects and indeterminacy in a calibrated one-sector growth model. Journal of Economic Theory 143, 610623.Google Scholar
Khan, Hashmat and Tsoukalas, John (2011) Investment shocks and the comovement problem. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 35, 115130.Google Scholar
Khan, Hashmat and Tsoukalas, John (2012) The quantitative importance of news shocks in estimated DSGE models. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 44, 15351561.Google Scholar
Kilian, Lutz and Lewis, Logan T. (2011) Does the Fed respond to oil price shocks? Economic Journal 121, 10471072.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kimball, Miles S. and Shapiro, Matthew D. (2010) Labor Supply: Are the Income and Substitution Effects Both Large or Both Small? NBER working paper 14208.Google Scholar
King, Robert G., Plosser, Charles I., and Rebelo, Sergio (1988) Production, growth and business cycle: I. The basic neoclassical model. Journal of Monetary Economics 21, 195232.Google Scholar
Kormilitsina, Anna (2011) Oil price shocks and the optimality of monetary policy. Review of Economic Dynamics 14, 199223.Google Scholar
Lai, Ching-chong and Chin, Chi-ting (2010) (In)determinacy, increasing returns, and the optimality of the Friedman rule in an endogenously growing open economy. Economic Theory 44, 69100.Google Scholar
Laitner, John and Stolyarov, Dmitriy (2004) Aggregate returns to scale and embodied technical change: theory and measurement using stock market data. Journal of Monetary Economics 51, 191233.Google Scholar
Lane, Philip R. and Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria (2007) The external wealth of nations Mark II: Revised and extended estimates of foreign assets and liabilities, 1970–2004. Journal of international Economics 73, 223250.Google Scholar
Letendre, Marc-André (2004) Capital utilization and habit formation in a small open economy model. Canadian Journal of Economics 37, 721741.Google Scholar
Mendoza, Enrique G., Quadrini, Vincenzo, and Rios-Rull, Jose-Victor (2009) Financial integration, financial development, and global imbalances. Journal of Political Economy 117, 371416.Google Scholar
Meng, Qinglai and Velasco, Andrés (2003) Indeterminacy in a small open economy with endogenous labor supply. Economic Theory 22, 661669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meng, Qinglai and Velasco, Andrés (2004) Market imperfections and the instability of open economies. Journal of International Economics 64, 503519.Google Scholar
Modigliani, Franco (1986) Life cycle, individual thrift, and the wealth of nations. American Economic Review 76, 297313.Google Scholar
Natal, Jean (2012) Monetary policy response to oil price shocks. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 44, 53101.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, William D. (2007) Who's afraid of a big bad oil shock? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2007.2, 219238.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, Maurice (1980) Intermediate imports, the terms of trade and the dynamics of the current account. Journal of International Economics 10, 461480.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, Maurice (1983) Intertemporal price speculation and the optimal current-account deficit. Journal of International Money and Finance 2, 135145.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, Maurice (1989) Fiscal deficits and relative prices in a growing world economy. Journal of Monetary Economics 23, 461484.Google Scholar
Perli, Roberto (1998) Indeterminacy, home production, and the business cycle: A calibrated analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics 41, 105125.Google Scholar
Romer, Paul M. (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy 94, 10021037.Google Scholar
Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie and Uribe, Martin (2003) Closing small open economy models. Journal of International Economics 61, 163185.Google Scholar
Schubert, Stefan F. (2014) Dynamic effects of oil price shocks and their impact on the current account. Macroeconomic Dynamics 18, 316337.Google Scholar
Schubert, Stefan F. and Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2011) The impact of oil prices on an oil-importing developing economy. Journal of Development Economics 94, 1829.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, Partha (1991) Imported input price and the current account in an optimizing model without capital mobility. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 15, 91101.Google Scholar
Turnovsky, Stephen J. (1997) Equilibrium growth in a small economy facing an imperfect world capital market. Review of Development Economics 1, 122.Google Scholar
Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2000) Methods of Macroeconomic Dynamics, 2nd ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2002) Knife-edge conditions and the macrodynamics of small open economies. Macroeconomic Dynamics 6, 307335.Google Scholar
Weder, Mark (2001) Indeterminacy in the small open economy Ramsey growth model. Journal of Economic Theory 98, 339356.Google Scholar
Wen, Yi (1998) Capacity utilization under increasing returns to scale. Journal of Economic Theory 81, 736.Google Scholar