Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2plfb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T19:29:05.795Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

JOB TURNOVER, TREND GROWTH, AND THE LONG-RUN PHILLIPS CURVE

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 April 2016

Dennis J. Snower
Affiliation:
Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Christian-Alberts University, CEPR and IZA
Mewael F. Tesfaselassie*
Affiliation:
Kiel Institute for the World Economy
*
Address correspondence to: Mewael F. Tesfaselassie, Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Kiellinie 66, 24105 Kiel, Germany; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

The paper reexamines the long-run Phillips curve in a New Keynesian model with job turnover and trend productivity growth. We show that an increase in money growth has substantial positive effects on steady state output, consumption, and employment in the presence of (i) observed job turnover rates and, if consumption smoothing is sufficiently strong, (ii) observed productive growth rates. Furthermore, we show that the optimal inflation rate is slightly under 2% for reasonable calibrations of job turnover and trend growth.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Financial support from the German Science Foundation within the project “Trend Productivity Growth and Labor Market Frictions in a New Keynesian Business Cycle Model” is gratefully acknowledged.

References

REFERENCES

Aghion, P. (2002) Schumpeterian growth theory and the dynamics of income inequality. Econometrica 70, 855882.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1998) Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Amano, R., Moran, K., Murchison, M., and Rennison, A. (2009) Trend inflation, wage and price rigidities, and productivity growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 56, 353364.Google Scholar
Ascari, G. (1998) Superneutrality of money in staggered wage-setting models. Macroeconomic Dynamics 2, 383400.Google Scholar
Ascari, G. (2004) Staggered prices and trend inflation: Some nuisances. Review of Economic Dynamics 7, 642667.Google Scholar
Ascari, G. and Rossi, L. (2012) Trend inflation and firms price-setting: Rotemberg versus Calvo. Economic Journal 122, 11151141.Google Scholar
Ascari, G. and Sbordonne, A. (2014) The macroeconomics of trend inflation. Journal of Economic Literature 53, 679739.Google Scholar
Bakhshi, H., Burriel-Llombart, P., Kahn, H., and Rudolf, B. (2003) Endogenous Price Stickiness, Trend Inflation, and the New Keynesian Phillips Curve. Working paper 191, Bank of England.Google Scholar
Basu, S. and Kimball, M. (2002) Long-Run Labor Supply and the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution for Consumption. Unpublished manuscript, Boston College and University of Michigan.Google Scholar
Bilbiie, F. (2011) Non-separable preferences and Frisch labor supply: One solution to a fiscal policy puzzle. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 43, 221251.Google Scholar
Bilbiie, F., Gironi, F., and Melitz, M. (2007) Monetary policy and business cycles with endogenous entry and product variety. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 22, 299353.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. and Diamond, P. (1990) The cyclical behavior of the gross flows of U.S. workers. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 85143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchard, O. and Gali, J. (2010) Labour markets and monetary policy: A New Keynesian model with unemployment. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2, 130.Google Scholar
Chugh, S. (2006) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy with sticky wages and sticky prices. Review of Economic Dynamics 9, 683714.Google Scholar
Davis, S. and Haltiwanger, J. (1990) Gross job creation and destruction: Microeconomic evidence and macroeconomic implications. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 5, 123168.Google Scholar
Erceg, C., Henderson, D., and Levin, A. (2000) Optimal monetary policy with staggered wage and price contracts. Journal of Monetary Economics 46, 281313.Google Scholar
Graham, L. and Snower, D. (2004) The Real Effects of Money Growth in Dynamic General Equilibrium. Working paper 412, European Central Bank.Google Scholar
Graham, L. and Snower, D. (2008) Hyperbolic discounting and the Phillips curve. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40, 427448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1991) Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Guerron-Quintana, P. (2008) Refinements on macroeconomic modeling: The role of non-separability and heterogeneous labour supply. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32, 36133630.Google Scholar
Hall, R. (2003) Modern theory of unemployment fluctuations: Empirics and policy applications. American Economic Review 93, 145150.Google Scholar
Huang, K. and Liu, Z. (2002) Staggered price setting, staggered wage setting and business cycle persistence. Journal of Monetary Economics 49, 405433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ireland, P. (2011) A New Keynesian perspective on the Great Recession. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 43, 3154.Google Scholar
Kambourov, G. and Manovskii, I. (2008) Rising occupational and industry mobility in the United States: 1968–1997. International Economic Review 49, 4179.Google Scholar
Keen, B. and Wang, Y. (2007) What is a realistic value for price adjustment costs in New Keynesian models? Applied Economics Letters 14, 789793.Google Scholar
Kiley, L. (2003) Why is inflation low when productivity growth is high? Economic Inquiry 41, 392406.Google Scholar
King, R., Plosser, C., and Rebelo, S. (1988a) Production growth and business cycles: I. The basic neoclassical model. Journal of Monetary Economics 21, 195232.Google Scholar
King, R., Plosser, C., and Rebelo, S. (1988b) Production growth and business cycles: II. New directions. Journal of Monetary Economics 21, 309341.Google Scholar
King, R. and Wolman, A. (1996) Inflation targeting in a St. Louis model of the 21st century. Federal Reserve of St. Louis Review 78, 83107.Google Scholar
Kliesen, K. (2010) Is the Fed's Definition of Price Stability Evolving? Economic synopsis 33, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.Google Scholar
Lombardo, G. and Vestin, D. (2008) Welfare implications of Calvo vs. Rotemberg-pricing assumptions. Economics Letters 100, 275279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mankiw, G. (2001) The inexorable and mysterious tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. Economic Journal 111, 4561.Google Scholar
Monacelli, T. and Perotti, R. (2009) Fiscal Policy, Wealth Effects, and Markups. NBER working paper 14584.Google Scholar
Mortensen, D. (2005) Growth, unemployment, and labour market policy. Journal of the European Economic Association 3, 236258.Google Scholar
Pissarides, C. (2000) Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, 2nd ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Rotemberg, J. (1982) Monopolistic price adjustment and aggregate output. Review of Economic Studies 49, 517531.Google Scholar
Sbordone, A. (2002) Prices and unit labor costs: A new test of price stickiness. Journal of Monetary Economics 49, 265292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitt-Grohe, S. and Uribe, M. (2006) Comparing Two Variants of Calvo-Type Wage Stickiness. Working paper 12740, NBER.Google Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2007) Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. American Economic Review 97, 586606.Google Scholar
Tesfaselassie, M.F. (2013) Trend productivity growth and the government spending multiplier. Journal of Macroeconomics 37, 197207.Google Scholar
Wolman, A. (2001) A primer on optimal monetary policy with staggered price-setting. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 87 (4), 2752.Google Scholar
Yun, T. (1996) Nominal price rigidity, money supply endogeneity, and business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 37, 345370.Google Scholar