Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T05:20:43.976Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE INSTABILITY OF OPEN PARETO EFFICIENT ECONOMIES

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 July 2020

Antoine Le Riche*
Affiliation:
Sichuan University
*
Address correspondence to: Antoine Le Riche, School of Economics, Sichuan University, No. 24 South Section 1, Yihuan Road, Chengdu, China, 610065. e-mail: [email protected]. Phone: +86 28 85412504. Fax: +86 28 85470032.

Abstract

This paper analyzes the impact of trade on the stability properties of trading countries and on stationary welfare. We consider a two-country two-good two-factor overlapping generations model where countries differ in terms of their technology. In the autarky equilibrium and the free-trade equilibrium, indeterminacy relies, under dynamic efficiency, on a capital intensive consumption good and intermediate values of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution in consumption. Opening the borders to trade can be a source of a global destabilizing effect. Indeed, considering a free-trade equilibrium in which one country is an exporter of the consumption good and the other country is an exporter of the investment good, indeterminacy can occur with trade even though the two countries are determinate in autarky. Finally, opening to trade increases the stationary welfare of the country that exports the investment good and deteriorates the one of the other country.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

This paper is dedicated to the memory of Carine Nourry. I would like to warmly thank one anonymous referee and the Associate Editor for their precious comments and suggestions. I am grateful to Stefano Bosi, Raouf Boucekkine, Wentao Fu, Zhiming Fu, François Langot, Francesco Magris, Kazuo Nishimura, Carine Nourry, Antoine Parent, Thomas Seegmuller, Ahmed Tritah, Alain Venditti, and Lei Zhang for useful comments and suggestions. This paper benefited from presentation at the “Doctoral Workshop on Dynamics Macroeconomics,” Strasbourg, France, June 2014, at the general seminar of GAINS, Le Mans, France, November 2014, at the “Association for the Development of Research in Economics and Statistics” conference, Paris, France, February 2015, at “Public Economic Theory” conference, Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, July 2016, at the seminar of Sichuan University, Chengdu, China, October 2018 and the “International Conference on Applied Finance, Macroeconomic Performance and Economic Growth,” Hangzhou, China, October 2018. This research is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China project numbers 71742004 and 71673194. Any errors are my own.

References

REFERENCES

Aloi, M. and Lloyd-Braga, T. (2010) National labor markets, international factor mobility and macroeconomic instability. Economic Theory 43(3), 431456.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aloi, M., Dixon Huw, D. and Lloyd-Braga, T. (2000) “Endogenous fluctuations in an open economy with increasing returns to scale. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 24(1), 97125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Autor, D., Dorn, D. and Hanson, G. (2013) The China syndrome: Local labor market effects of import competition in the United States. American Economic Review 103(6), 21212168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baxter, M. (1992) Fiscal policy, specialization, and trade in the two-sector model: The return of Ricardo? Journal of Political Economy 10(4), 713744.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bianconi, M. (1995) On dynamic real trade models. Economics Letters 47(1), 4752.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benhabib, J. and Nishimura, K. (1985) Competitive equilibrium cycles. Journal of Economic Theory 35(2), 284306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benhabib, J. and Nishimura, K. (1998) Indeterminacy and sunspots with constant returns. Journal of Economic Theory 81(1), 5896.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bond, E. W., Iwasa, K. and Nishimura, K. (2013) Poverty traps and inferior goods in a dynamic Heckscher-Ohlin model. Macroeconomic Dynamics 17(6), 12271251.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cecchi, D. and Garcia-Peñalosa, C. (2010) Labour market institutions and the personal distribution of income in the OECD. Economica 77(307), 413450.Google Scholar
Chen, Y. and Zhang, Y. (2011) A note on Tariff policy, increasing returns, and endogenous fluctuations and equilibrium indeterminacy: A global analysis. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15(2), 279291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cremers, E. T. (2005) Intergenerational welfare and trade. Macroeconomic Dynamics 9(5), 585611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
di Giovanni, J. and Levchenko, A. (2009) Trade openness and volatility. Review of Economics and Statistics 9(3), 558585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, P. A. (1965) National debt in a neoclassical growth model. American Economic Review 55(5), 11261150.Google Scholar
Drugeon, J.-P. (2004) On consumptions, inputs and outputs subsitutabilities and the evanescence of optimal cycles. Journal of Difference Equations and Applications 10(5), 473487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drugeon, J.-P., Nourry, C. and Venditti, A. (2010) On efficiency and local uniqueness in two-sector OLG economies. Mathematical Social Sciences 59(1), 120144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eaton, J. and Kortum, S. (2002) Technology, geography and trade. Econometrica 70(5), 17411779.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fadinger, H. and Fleiss, P. (2011) Trade and sectoral productivity. The Economic Journal 121(555), 120144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grandmont, J.-M., Pintus, P. and de Vilder, R. (1998) Capital-labor substitution and competitive nonlinear endogenous business cycles. Journal of Economic Theory 80(1), 1459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hu, Y. and Mino, K. (2013) Trade structure and belief-driven fluctuations in a global economy. Journal of International Economics 90(2), 414424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iwasa, K. and Nishimura, K. (2014) Dynamic two-country Heckscher-Ohlin model with externality. International Journal of Economic Theory 10(1), 5374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kemp, M. C. and Wong, K.-Y. (1995) Gains from trade with overlapping generations. Economic Theory 6(2), 283303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kose, A., Prasad, E. and Terrones, M. (2003) Financial integration and macroeconomic volatility. IMF Staff Papers 50, 119141.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. (2009) The increasing returns revolution in trade and geography. American Economic Review 99(3), 561571.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Le Riche, A. (2017) Macroeconomic volatility and trade in OLG economies. International Journal of Economic Theory 13(4), 401425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Le Riche, A., Lloyd-Braga, T. and Modesto, L. (2019) Intra-industry trade, involuntary unemployment and indeterminacy. Submitted.Google Scholar
Matsuyama, K. (2013) Endogenous ranking and equilibrium lorenz curve across (ex-ante) identical countries. Econometrica 81(5), 20092031.Google Scholar
Naito, T. and Zhao, L. (2009) Aging, transitional dynamic, and gains from trade. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 33(8), 15311542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nishimura, K. and Shimomura, K. (2002) Trade and indeterminacy in a dynamic general equilibrium model. Journal of Economic Theory 105(1), 244260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nishimura, K, Venditti, A. and Yano, M. (2006) Endogenous fluctuations in two-country models. The Japanese Economic Review 57(4), 516532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nishimura, K, Venditti, A. and Yano, M. (2009) Optimal growth an competitive equilibrium business cycles under decreasing returns in two-country models. Review of International Economics 17(2), 371391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nishimura, K, Venditti, A. and Yano, M. (2014) Destabilization effect of international trade in a perfect foresight dynamic general equilibrium model. Economic Theory 55(2), 357392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nishimura, K. and Yano, M. (1993) Interlinkage in the endogenous real business cycles of international economies. Economic Theory 3(1), 151168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nourry, C. and Venditti, A. (2011) Local indeterminacy under dynamic efficiency in a two-sector overlapping generations economy. Journal of Mathematical Economics 47(2), 164169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nourry, C. and Venditti, A. (2012) Endogenous business cycles in overlapping-generations economies with multiple consumption goods. Macroeconomic Dynamics 16(1), 86102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Obstfeld, M. (1994) Risk-taking, global diversification and growth. American Economic Review 84(5), 13101329.Google Scholar
Parello, C. P. (2019) Equilibrium indeterminacy in one-sector small open economies: the role of international labor migration. Macroeconomic Dynamics 23(4), 15281562.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reichlin, P. (1986) Equilibrium cycles in overlapping generations economy with production. Journal of Economic Theory 40(1), 89102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. (1971) Factor price equalization in a dynamic economy. Journal of Political Economy 78(3), 456485.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sim, N., and Ho, K.-W. (2007) Autarky indeterminacy and trade determinacy. International Journal of Economic Theory 3(4), 151168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Takahashi, H., Mashiyama, K. and Sakagami, R. (2012) Does the capital intensity matter? Evidence from the postwar Japanese economy and other OECD countries. Macroeconomic Dynamics 16(1), 103116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vissing-Jorgensen, A. and Attanasio, O. (2003) Stock-market participation, intertemporal substitution and risk aversion. American Economic Review 93(2), 383391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Y. and Chen, Y. (2011) Tariff and equilibrium indeterminacy: A global analysis. Macroeconomic Dynamics 16(3), 394410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar