Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-gb8f7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T18:08:37.326Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Human brain evolution in a Malthusian economy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 November 2024

Angus C. Chu*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Macau, Macau, China
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Why did the human brain evolve? This study develops a Malthusian growth model with heterogeneous agents and natural selection to explore the evolution of human brain size. We find that if the cognitive advantage of a larger brain dominates its higher metabolic costs, then the average brain size increases over time, which is consistent with the rising trend in human brain size that started over 2 million years ago. Furthermore, an improvement in hunting-gathering productivity (e.g., the discovery of using stone tools and fire in hunting animals and cooking food) helps to trigger this human brain size evolution. As the average brain size increases, the average level of hunting-gathering productivity also rises over time. Quantitatively, our model is able to replicate the trend in hominin brain evolution over the last 10 million years.

Type
Notes
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

[A]rchaic and early modern humans slowly but steadily acquired new skills, mastered the use of fire, developed increasingly sophisticated blades, handaxes, and flint and limestone tools, and created artworks. A key driver of these cultural and technological advancements, which came to define humankind and set us apart from other species, was the evolution of the human brain. Galor (2022, p. 13-14)

As humans evolved, the volume of the human brain has increased. Over 2 million years ago, a dramatic increase in the growth rate of human brain size occurred, which coincided with the emergence of the earliest members of the human genus Homo.Footnote 1 Homo habilis is one of the earliest known humans and lived in Africa from up to 2.8 million to 1.7 million years ago according to existing fossil evidence, and they had a brain size of about 550 $\textrm{cm}^{3}$ to 690 $\textrm{cm}^{3}$ . Homo ergaster also lived in Africa from roughly 2.0 million to 1.4 million years ago and had a brain size of about 700 $\textrm{cm}^{3}$ to 900 $\textrm{cm}^{3}$ . The well-known Homo erectus lived from roughly 1.9 million to 110,000 years ago in different parts of the world (including Africa, Asia and Europe) and had a brain size of about 600 $\textrm{cm}^{3}$ to 1250 $\textrm{cm}^{3}$ . Homo heidelbergensis lived in Africa and Europe from about 600,000 to 200,000 years ago and had a brain size of about 1100 $\textrm{cm}^{3}$ to 1400 $\textrm{cm}^{3}$ . Homo neanderthalensis, who is commonly known as the Neanderthals, lived in mainly Europe from possibly 430,000 to 40,000 years ago and had a brain size of about 1200 $\textrm{cm}^{3}$ to 1750 $\textrm{cm}^{3}$ . Finally, Homo sapiens emerged in Africa about 300,000 years ago and has an average brain size of about 1400  $\textrm{cm}^{3}$ . Therefore, except for the Neanderthals who had an even larger brain size than modern humans,Footnote 2 human brain size has been increasing from early members of genus Homo to modern humans.Footnote 3

In this study, we develop a hunting-gathering Malthusian growth model with heterogeneous agents to explore the evolution of human brain size driven by natural selection. Our results can be summarized as follows. If the cognitive advantage of a larger brain dominates its higher metabolic costs,Footnote 4 then the average brain size of human population increases over time. This implication is consistent with the rising trend in brain size of archaic human species. We also find that an improvement in hunting-gathering productivity (e.g., the discovery of using stone tools and fire in hunting animals and cooking food) helps to trigger this human brain size evolution. For example, Fonseca-Azevedo and Herculano-Houzel (Reference Fonseca-Azevedo and Herculano-Houzel2012) argue that the shift to a cooked diet may be an important reason for the rapid rising trend in human brain size. Ofek (Reference Ofek2001, p. 73) also wrote that “the hunting-gathering feeding ecology [that led to an improvement in the quality and quantity of diet] facilitated a growing brain.” Furthermore, we find that as the average brain size increases, the average level of hunting-gathering productivity also rises over time. This implication is consistent with Galor’s (Reference Galor2022, p. 16–17) observation that “[t]he evolution of the human brain was the main impetus for the unique advancement of humanity, [ $\ldots$ which] in turn, shaped future evolutionary processes, enabling human beings to adapt more successfully to their shifting environments and to further advance and utilise new technologies.” Finally, we use our Malthusian growth model to perform a quantitative analysis to replicate the trend in hominin brain evolution over the last 10 million years.

This study relates to the literature on evolutionary growth theory based on natural selection in the Malthusian growth model.Footnote 5 A seminal study in this literature by Galor and Moav (Reference Galor and Moav2002) explores how natural selection and the quality–quantity trade-off of children affect the transition of an economy from pre-industrial stagnation to modern economic growth;Footnote 6 see also the interesting studies by Lagerlof (Reference Lagerlof2007) and Dalgaard and Strulik (Reference Dalgaard and Strulik2015) on the selection of human body mass, Galor and Michalopoulos (Reference Galor and Michalopoulos2012) on the selection of entrepreneurial spirit, Galor and Ozak (Reference Galor and Ozak2016) on the selection of future-oriented mindset, and Galor and Klemp (Reference Galor and Klemp2019) on the selection of child quality.Footnote 7 A recent study by Chu (Reference Chu2023) explores natural selection and the extinction of archaic human species in a hunting-gathering Malthusian economy. Another related study by Chu and Xu (Reference Chu and Xu2024) explores the subsequent transitions of human society from hunting-gathering to agriculture and then from agriculture to industrial production also in a Malthusian economy.Footnote 8 This study contributes to this literature by exploring natural selection of human brain size and its evolution in a Malthusian growth model.

This study also relates more broadly to the scientific literature on human brain size evolution; see Heldstab et al. (Reference Heldstab, Isler, Graber, Schuppli and van Schaik2022) for a survey. A recent study by Gonzalez-Forero and Gardner (Reference Gonzalez-Forero and Gardner2018) provides a quantitative analysis on the evolution of human brain and finds that ecological challenges for “finding, caching or processing food” are the main reason for human brain evolution. Robson and Kaplan (Reference Robson and Kaplan2003) provide an economic analysis on the development of human brain as health capital that is accumulated by bodily investment to reduce mortality. We contribute to this literature by also providing an economic analysis based on a microfounded Malthusian growth model, in which fertility decisions of heterogeneous agents give rise to natural selection and the underlying natural selection mechanism for human brain evolution is also ecological in nature that is driven by the advantage of a larger brain in hunting-gathering and food production.

The rest of this study is organized as follows. Section 2 sets up the Malthusian model. Section 3 presents our results on human brain evolution. Section 4 explores some extensions to the baseline model. The final section concludes.

2. A Malthusian model with human brain evolution

The Malthusian growth model is based on the seminal work of Malthus (Reference Malthus1798), who observed that population growth is limited by the availability of natural resources. In this section, we consider a canonical Malthusian growth model; see for example, Ashraf and Galor (Reference Ashraf and Galor2011). There is a group of humans, who may be Homo sapiens or any other archaic humans, such as Homo erectus or Neanderthals. The group engages in hunting-gathering within a fixed area of land $Z$ . The novel element is heterogeneity in brain size, which in turn affects consumption and hunting-gathering productivity.

2.1 Endogenous fertility and population dynamics

Within the human population, there is a large number of families indexed by $ i\in \{1,\ldots, m\}$ . Each family $i$ has an adult population $N_{i,t}$ at time $t$ . Therefore, the total adult population size at time $t$ is

(1) \begin{equation} N_{t}=\sum _{i=1}^{m}N_{i,t}\text{.} \end{equation}

Each family $i$ is endowed with an exogenous brain size denoted as $b_{i}\in \lbrack b^{\min },b^{\max }]$ , where $b_{i}$ is heterogeneous across families and follows a general distribution within the lower bound $b^{\min }$ and upper bound $b^{\max }$ on brain size.

Given the metabolic costs of the brain, a family with a larger brain size faces a higher subsistence requirement on per capita consumption denoted as $ \kappa _{i}=\kappa (b_{i})$ , which is assumed to be an increasing function in brain size $b_{i}$ . We consider overlapping generations of agents, and each agent lives for two periods. Each adult agent of family $i$ has the following utility function $u_{i,t}$ at time $t$ :

(2) \begin{equation} u_{i,t}=(1-\gamma )\ln (c_{i,t}-\kappa _{i})+\gamma \ln n_{i,t+1}\text{,} \end{equation}

where $\gamma \in (0,1)$ is the degree of preference on fertility relative to consumption $c_{i,t}$ . $n_{i,t+1}$ is the agent’s number of children, who then become adults at time $t+1$ . Raising children is costly, and the level of consumption net of the fertility cost is

(3) \begin{equation} c_{i,t}=y_{i,t}-\rho n_{i,t+1}\text{,} \end{equation}

where the parameter $\rho \gt 0$ determines the cost of fertility and $y_{i,t}$ is the per capita output of food production in family $i$ .

The utility-maximizing level of consumption is

(4) \begin{equation} c_{i,t}=(1-\gamma )y_{i,t}+\gamma \kappa _{i}\text{,} \end{equation}

and the utility-maximizing level of fertility is

(5) \begin{equation} n_{i,t+1}=\frac{\gamma }{\rho }(y_{i,t}-\kappa _{i})\text{,} \end{equation}

where fertility cost $\rho$ is identical across families for simplicity. Equations ([4]) and ([5]) show that a family with a larger brain size $b_{i}$ allocates a larger amount of food output to consumption (due to the higher subsistence requirement $\kappa (b_{i})$ ) at the expense of fertility. Therefore, if a larger brain size does not carry a cognitive advantage, then families with larger brains would have an evolutionary disadvantage.

Each adult agent in family $i$ has $n_{i,t+1}$ children, and the number of adult agents in family $i$ at time $t$ is $N_{i,t}$ . Therefore, the law of motion for the adult population size in family $i$ is

(6) \begin{equation} N_{i,t+1}=n_{i,t+1}N_{i,t}=\frac{\gamma }{\rho }(y_{i,t}-\kappa _{i})N_{i,t} \text{,} \end{equation}

which is decreasing in the subsistence requirement $\kappa _{i}$ . The growth rate of $N_{i,t}$ at time $t$ is

(7) \begin{equation} \frac{\Delta N_{i,t}}{N_{i,t}}\equiv \frac{N_{i,t+1}-N_{i,t}}{N_{i,t}}=\frac{ \gamma }{\rho }(y_{i,t}-\kappa _{i})-1\text{,} \end{equation}

and the growth rate of total adult population $N_{t}$ at time $t$ is

(8) \begin{equation} \frac{\Delta N_{t}}{N_{t}}=\sum _{i=1}^{m}s_{i,t}\frac{\Delta N_{i,t}}{N_{i,t} }=\frac{\gamma }{\rho }\sum _{i=1}^{m}s_{i,t}(y_{i,t}-\kappa _{i})-1\text{,} \end{equation}

where $s_{i,t}\equiv N_{i,t}/N_{t}$ and $\Delta N_{t}/N_{t}$ will be simply referred to as the population growth rate.

2.2 Hunting-gathering

To capture the cognitive advantage of a larger human brain, we assume that the level of hunting-gathering productivity denoted as $\theta _{i}=\theta (b_{i})$ in each family $i$ is also increasing in its brain size $b_{i}$ . The food production function of family $i$ is

(9) \begin{equation} Y_{i,t}=\theta _{i}(lN_{i,t})^{\alpha }(Z_{i,t})^{1-\alpha }\text{,} \end{equation}

where $lN_{i,t}$ and $Z_{i,t}$ are, respectively, the amount of labor and land devoted to hunting-gathering by family $i$ . Individual labor supply $l\gt 0$ is exogenous, and the parameter $\alpha \in (0,1)$ measures labor intensity of the hunting-gathering process.

For simplicity, the amount of land occupied by family $i$ for hunting-gathering is assumed to be proportional to its population share $ s_{i,t}$ :Footnote 9

(10) \begin{equation} Z_{i,t}=s_{i,t}Z=\frac{N_{i,t}}{N_{t}}Z\text{.} \end{equation}

Substituting ([10]) into ([9]) yields the level of food output per capita in family $i$ as

(11) \begin{equation} y_{i,t}\equiv \frac{Y_{i,t}}{N_{i,t}}=\frac{\theta _{i}(lN_{i,t})^{\alpha }(Z_{i,t})^{1-\alpha }}{N_{i,t}}=\theta _{i}l^{\alpha }\left ( \frac{Z}{N_{t}} \right ) ^{1-\alpha }\text{,} \end{equation}

which is increasing in the family’s brain size $b_{i}$ via its hunting-gathering productivity $\theta (b_{i})$ .

3. Natural selection and brain size evolution

Substituting ([11]) into ([7]) yields the population growth rate of family $i$ asFootnote 10

(12) \begin{equation} g_{i,t}\equiv \frac{\Delta N_{i,t}}{N_{i,t}}=\frac{\gamma }{\rho }\left [ \theta _{i}l^{\alpha }\left ( \frac{Z}{N_{t}}\right ) ^{1-\alpha }-\kappa _{i} \right ] -1\text{,} \end{equation}

which is increasing in hunting-gathering productivity $\theta _{i}$ but decreasing in the subsistence requirement $\kappa _{i}$ . Recall that both $ \theta _{i}=\theta (b_{i})$ and $\kappa _{i}=\kappa (b_{i})$ are increasing functions of brain size $b_{i}$ . Therefore, a larger brain size $b_{i}$ has a positive effect on fertility via a higher level of hunting-gathering productivity $\theta _{i}$ and also a negative effect on fertility via a higher subsistence requirement $\kappa _{i}$ . If we were to assume $\kappa _{i}=\kappa$ to be homogeneous across families, then families with the largest brain size $b^{\max }$ would dominate the population by having the highest hunting-gathering productivity $\theta (b^{\max })$ and the highest population growth rate. Conversely, if we were to assume $\theta _{i}=\theta$ to be homogeneous across families, then families with the smallest brain size $b^{\min }$ would dominate the population by having the lowest subsistence requirement $\kappa (b^{\min })$ and the highest population growth rate. In general, families that have the highest population growth rate would dominate the population in the long run. For the rest of this analysis, we assume that the productivity benefit $\theta (b_{i})$ is weakly concave in $b_{i}$ whereas the metabolic cost $\kappa (b_{i})$ is weakly convex in $b_{i}$ . We first examine the condition under which the average human brain size evolves toward $b^{\max }$ .

3.1 Expanding brain size in human evolution

If the positive effect of brain size $b_{i}$ on fertility always dominates its negative effect (i.e.,

(13) \begin{equation} \frac{\partial g_{i,t}}{\partial b_{i}}\gt 0\Leftrightarrow l^{\alpha }\left ( \frac{Z}{N_{t}}\right ) ^{1-\alpha }\frac{\partial \theta _{i}}{\partial b_{i} }\gt \frac{\partial \kappa _{i}}{\partial b_{i}} \end{equation}

for all $b_{i}\in \lbrack b^{\min },b^{\max }]$ and $N_{t}\in \lbrack N_{0},N^{\ast }]$ where $N^{\ast }$ is the steady-state level of total population),Footnote 11 then the population growth rate of family $ i$ is increasing in its brain size $b_{i}$ . In this case, the growth rate of the population share of family $i$ is also rising in its brain size:Footnote 12

\begin{equation*} \Delta s_{i,t}\approx \frac {\Delta N_{i,t}}{N_{t}}=s_{i,t}g_{i,t}\Rightarrow \frac {\partial \Delta s_{i,t}/s_{i,t}}{\partial b_{i}}\approx \frac {\partial g_{i,t}}{\partial b_{i}}\text {.} \end{equation*}

As a result, families with the largest brain size would have an evolutionary advantage and eventually dominate the population. In the long run, $ s_{i,t}(b_{i}=b^{\max })\rightarrow 1$ because given ([13]), its population growth rate $g_{i,t}(b_{i}=b^{\max })$ in ([12]) is the highest among all families such that $s_{j,t}(b_{j}\lt b^{\max })\rightarrow 0$ . In this case, total population $N_{t}$ converges to the steady-state population level of the families with the largest brain size $b^{\max }$ :

(14) \begin{equation} \lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }N_{t}\rightarrow N^{\ast }=\left [ \frac{\gamma \theta (b^{\max })l^{\alpha }}{\rho +\gamma \kappa (b^{\max })}\right ] ^{1/(1-\alpha )}Z\text{,} \end{equation}

which is derived from ([12]) by setting $b_{i}=b^{\max }$ .

As their population share $s_{i,t}(b_{i}=b^{\max })$ rises over time due to their higher population growth rate, the average brain size $b_{t}\equiv \sum _{i=1}^{m}s_{i,t}b_{i}$ of human population also increases over time, which is consistent with the rising trend in human brain size that started over 2 million years ago. Eventually, the average brain size converges to the upper bound (i.e., $b_{t}\rightarrow b^{\max }$ as $s_{i,t}(b_{i}=b^{ \max })\rightarrow 1$ ). As the average brain size increases over time, the average level of hunting-gathering productivity $\theta _{t}\equiv \sum _{i=1}^{m}s_{i,t}\theta _{i}$ also rises over time and converges to $ \theta (b^{\max })$ .Footnote 13

When does this expanding brain size in human evolution occur? To explore this question, we substitute $N^{\ast }$ from ([4]) into $N_{t}$ in ([13]) to derive

(15) \begin{equation} \frac{\rho +\gamma \kappa (b^{\max })}{\gamma \theta (b^{\max })}\theta ^{\prime }(b^{\max })\gt \kappa ^{\prime }(b^{\max })\text{.} \end{equation}

Recall from ([13]) that the positive effect of $b_{i}$ is decreasing in $N_{t}$ . So, if the inequality in ([13]) holds for $N^{\ast }$ , it would also hold for $N_{t}\in \lbrack N_{0},N^{\ast }]$ . In the following section, we consider a parametric example to demonstrate when ([15]) holds.

3.1.1 A parametric example

Suppose $\theta (b_{i})$ and $\kappa (b_{i})$ take the following functional form: $\theta (b_{i})=1+\overline{\theta }b_{i}$ and $\kappa (b_{i})= \overline{\kappa }b_{i}$ , where $\overline{\theta }\gt 0$ and $\overline{\kappa }\gt 0$ are productivity and cost parameters, respectively. To be more precise, as the productivity parameter $\overline{\theta }$ increases, hunting-gathering productivity $\theta (b_{i})$ rises, and this positive marginal effect of $\overline{\theta }$ on hunting-gathering productivity $ \theta (b_{i})$ is increasing in brain size $b_{i}$ .Footnote 14 Similarly, as brain size $b_{i}$ increases, hunting-gathering productivity $\theta (b_{i})$ also rises, and this positive marginal effect of $b_{i}$ on hunting-gathering productivity $ \theta (b_{i})$ is also increasing in the parameter $\overline{\theta }$ , which therefore captures the marginal effect of brain size on hunting-gathering productivity. In other words, an increase in the parameter $\overline{\theta }$ represents an improvement in hunting-gathering productivity that is complementary to brain size (i.e., a family $i$ with a larger brain size $b_{i}$ is better able to benefit from the increase in $ \overline{\theta }$ ). For example, the discovery of stone tools (an exogenous increase in $\overline{\theta }$ in our model) is only useful for a hominin species that is intelligent enough to make use of the tools.

Given $\theta (b_{i})=1+\overline{\theta }b_{i}$ and $\kappa (b_{i})= \overline{\kappa }b_{i}$ , ([15]) simplifies to

(16) \begin{equation} \overline{\theta }\gt \frac{\gamma }{\rho }\overline{\kappa }\text{.} \end{equation}

In this case, in order for human population to evolve toward a larger average brain size, the productivity parameter $\overline{\theta }$ needs to be sufficiently large relative to the product of the cost parameter $ \overline{\kappa }$ and the ratio $\gamma /\rho$ .Footnote 15 The comparison between hunting-gathering productivity and metabolic cost is intuitive, whereas the ratio $\gamma /\rho$ also plays a role because fertility and population size are increasing in fertility preference $\gamma$ and decreasing in fertility cost $\rho$ . As ([13]) shows, a larger population reduces the marginal benefit of brain size on hunting-gathering productivity due to the decreasing returns to scale in food production. An implication of ([16]) is that a high level of hunting-gathering productivity $\overline{\theta }$ that is complementary to brain size (e.g., the discovery of using fire in hunting animals and cooking food or the development of “increasingly sophisticated blades, handaxes, and flint and limestone tools”) helps to trigger the emergence of an expanding brain size in human evolution;Footnote 16 see for example, Gowlett (Reference Gowlett2016) who provides evidence that the discovery of fire “has fuelled the increase in brain size through the Pleistocene.”

3.1.2 Summary of results

Proposition1 summarizes all our results in this section.

Proposition 1. The population growth rate of family $i$ is increasing in its hunting-gathering productivity $\theta _{i}$ but decreasing in its subsistence requirement $\kappa _{i}$ . If the positive effect of a larger brain size $b_{i}$ on hunting-gathering productivity $\theta _{i}$ always dominates its negative effect (via a higher subsistence requirement $\kappa _{i}$ ) on fertility, then families with the largest brain size $b^{\max }$ have an evolutionary advantage, and the average brain size in human population increases over time. As the average brain size $b_{t}$ increases, the average level of hunting-gathering productivity $\theta _{t}$ also rises over time. Suppose $\theta (b_{i})=1+\overline{\theta }b_{i}$ and $\kappa (b_{i})=\overline{\kappa }b_{i}$ . Then, an improvement in hunting-gathering productivity $\overline{\theta }$ that is complementary to brain size helps to trigger the emergence of an expanding brain size in human evolution.

3.2 Optimal brain size in human evolution

We now explore the more interesting case in which the average brain size $ b_{t}$ evolves toward an interior steady state $b^{\ast }\in (b^{\min },b^{\max })$ . If there exists a certain level of population threshold $ \widetilde{N}$ under which

(17) \begin{equation} l^{\alpha }\left ( \frac{Z}{\widetilde{N}}\right ) ^{1-\alpha }\frac{\partial \theta (b^{\ast })}{\partial b_{i}}=\frac{\partial \kappa (b^{\ast })}{ \partial b_{i}}\text{,} \end{equation}

then there exists an interior optimal brain size $b^{\ast }\in (b^{\min },b^{\max })$ from an evolutionary viewpoint. To determine this optimal brain size, we also need the steady-state population level:

(18) \begin{equation} N_{i}^{\ast }(b_{i}=b^{\ast })=\left [ \frac{\gamma \theta (b^{\ast })l^{\alpha }}{\rho +\gamma \kappa (b^{\ast })}\right ] ^{1/(1-\alpha )}Z= \widetilde{N}\text{,} \end{equation}

where $\widetilde{N}$ and $b^{\ast }$ are determined jointly by ([17]) and ([18]). In other words, families with the optimal brain size $b^{\ast }$ have the highest steady-state population growth rate and dominate the population in the long run (i.e., $s_{i,t}(b_{i}=b^{\ast })\rightarrow 1$ because its steady-state population growth rate $g_{i}^{\ast }(b_{i}=b^{\ast })=0$ is the highest among all families such that $g_{j}^{\ast }(b_{j}\neq b^{\ast })\lt 0$ ).Footnote 17

Combining ([17]) and ([18]) yields the following condition that determines $ b^{\ast }$ :

(19) \begin{equation} \frac{\theta ^{\prime }(b^{\ast })}{\kappa ^{\prime }(b^{\ast })}=\frac{ \gamma \theta (b^{\ast })}{\rho +\gamma \kappa (b^{\ast })}\text{.} \end{equation}

The left-hand side of ([19]) is weakly decreasing in $b^{\ast }$ because $ \theta ^{\prime \prime }\leq 0$ and $\kappa ^{\prime \prime }\geq 0$ . As for the right-hand side of ([19]) defined as $\Phi (b^{\ast })\equiv \gamma \theta (b^{\ast })/[\rho +\gamma \kappa (b^{\ast })]$ , it can be shown that ([19]) implies $\Phi ^{\prime }(b^{\ast })=0$ . Therefore, we need to assume that at least one of $\theta ^{\prime \prime }\leq 0$ and $\kappa ^{\prime \prime }\geq 0$ is a strict inequality to ensure the existence of a solution $ b^{\ast }$ . If $b^{\ast }$ falls within the range of brain size $b_{i}\in \lbrack b^{\min },b^{\max }]$ , then families with the optimal brain size $ b^{\ast }$ will dominate the population in the long run and have a steady-state level of population that is equal to the threshold $\widetilde{N}$ in ([18]). In this case, given an initial value $b_{0}$ , the average brain size $b_{t}\equiv \sum _{i=1}^{m}s_{i,t}b_{i}$ rises toward $b^{\ast }$ as $ s_{i,t}(b_{i}=b^{\ast })\rightarrow 1$ .Footnote 18

3.2.1 Another parametric example

Suppose $\theta (b_{i})$ and $\kappa (b_{i})$ now take the following functional form: $\theta (b_{i})=1+\overline{\theta }b_{i}$ and $\kappa (b_{i})=\overline{\kappa }b_{i}^{2}$ , where $\overline{\theta }\gt 0$ and $ \overline{\kappa }\gt 0$ are parameters. In this case, the optimal brain size $ b^{\ast }$ from ([19]) is determined by the following quadratic equation:

(20) \begin{equation} (b^{\ast })^{2}+\frac{2b^{\ast }}{\overline{\theta }}=\frac{\rho }{\gamma \overline{\kappa }}\text{,} \end{equation}

in which the solution $b^{\ast }\gt 0$ is increasing in hunting-gathering productivity $\overline{\theta }$ that is complementary to brain size. If $ \overline{\theta }$ becomes sufficiently large, it is possible for $b^{\ast }$ to even exceed the upper bound $b^{\max }$ , in which case the average brain size $b_{t}$ converges to $b^{\max }$ as in Section 3.1. Solving ([20]) yields

(21) \begin{equation} b^{\ast }=-\frac{1}{\overline{\theta }}+\sqrt{\frac{1}{\overline{\theta }^{2} }+\frac{\rho }{\gamma \overline{\kappa }}}\in (b^{\min },b^{\max })\text{,} \end{equation}

which depends positively on the parameter $\overline{\theta }$ and the composite parameter $\rho /(\gamma \overline{\kappa })$ . Proposition2 summarizes our result in this section.

Proposition 2. Suppose $\theta (b_{i})=1+\overline{\theta }b_{i}$ and $\kappa (b_{i})= \overline{\kappa }b_{i}^{2}$ . Then, $b^{\ast }$ in ([ 21 ]) is the evolutionarily optimal human brain size, which is increasing in hunting-gathering productivity $\overline{\theta }$ that is complementary to brain size.

3.2.2 Quantitative analysis

In this section, we compute the value of the optimal brain size $b^{\ast }$ in ([21]) and explore its quantitative implications. The introduction features a discussion on the range of brain size of different human species. Table 1 presents a summary based on the midpoint of the range of brain size of each of these species. It also uses the brain size of the first human species, Homo habilis, as the benchmark and presents the relative brain size of the subsequent human species.

Table 1. Human brain size

Suppose the brain size of each human species was optimal (given the level of hunting-gathering productivity $\overline{\theta }$ ) at its time. Then, we compute the change in $\overline{\theta }$ required for the optimal brain size to increase from $b^{\ast }=1$ for Homo habilis to $ b^{\ast }=2.26$ for Homo sapiens. In addition, this simulation also involves the fertility cost parameter $\rho$ , the fertility preference parameter $\gamma$ and the subsistence consumption parameter $ \overline{\kappa }$ . Specifically, the simulation requires an assigned value of the composite parameter $\rho /(\gamma \overline{\kappa })$ . Given that we do not know its value, we consider a range to examine how the value of this composite parameter affects our calculation. Table 2 presents the results. As $\rho /(\gamma \overline{\kappa })\rightarrow 5$ , the percent increase in $\overline{\theta }$ (required for $b^{\ast }$ to increase from 1 to 2.26) approaches infinity. Therefore, we start with a value of 6 for $ \rho /(\gamma \overline{\kappa })$ as a lower bound. Then, we examine how large the percent increase in $\overline{\theta }$ would be under a range of values of $\rho /(\gamma \overline{\kappa })$ for illustration. It turns out that as $\rho /(\gamma \overline{\kappa })$ increases, the percent increase in $\overline{\theta }$ remains over 100%. Thus, we conclude that the dramatic increase in human brain size over the last 2.5 million years was driven by a rapid improvement in hunting-gathering productivity $\overline{ \theta }$ that is complementary to brain size.

Table 2. Changes in productivity $\overline{\theta }$

We now consider hominin brain evolution over the last 10 million years. According to DeSilva et al. (Reference DeSilva, Traniello, Claxton and Fannin2021), the cranial capacity in fossil apes (Miocene hominids) from 10 million years ago is about 250 $cm^{3}$ , which is about 40% of the brain size of Homo habilis. If we consider a value of 10 for $\rho /(\gamma \overline{\kappa })$ as a benchmark, then the implied value of $\overline{\theta }$ for $b^{\ast }=0.40$ is 0.08. Suppose $\overline{\theta }$ increases linearly from 0.08 to 0.22 between 10 million years ago and 2.5 million years ago and from 0.22 to 0.92 between 2.5 millions years ago and the dawn of the Agricultural Revolution about 10,000 years ago. Then, we simulate the path of the optimal brain size $b^{\ast }$ in ([21]) as $\overline{\theta }$ gradually increases from 10 million years ago to recent times in Figure 1, which closely replicates the trend of hominin brain size in DeSilva et al. (Reference DeSilva, Traniello, Claxton and Fannin2021).Footnote 19 Specifically, the growth trend of hominin brain size was steadily slow from 10 million years ago to 2.5 million years ago and then accelerated about 2.5 million years ago before decelerating until recent times. This pattern is robust to other values of $\rho /(\gamma \overline{\kappa })$ with the recent deceleration becoming less rapid at larger values of $\rho /(\gamma \overline{\kappa })$ .Footnote 20

Figure 1. Simulated trend of hominin brain size.

4. Extensions

In this section, we consider a number of extensions to our baseline model.Footnote 21 Section 4.1 considers the presence of a scale effect in hunting-gathering productivity. Section 4.2 considers the evolution of human body mass.

4.1 Scale effect

In this section, we introduce a scale effect on hunting-gathering productivity to our baseline model.Footnote 22 For simplicity, we assume that subsistence requirement $\kappa _{i}=\kappa$ is homogeneous across families. In this case, our baseline model predicts that families with the largest brain size $b^{\max }$ would dominate the population by having the highest hunting-gathering productivity $\theta (b^{\max })$ and the highest population growth rate. Suppose we now modify the hunting-gathering productivity function as $\theta (s_{i,t}b_{i})$ to be increasing in $s_{i,t}b_{i}$ , where $s_{i,t}\equiv N_{i,t}/N_{t}$ is the population share of family $i$ and captures a scale effect of relative population size on hunting-gathering productivity. For example, a larger family group may be able to occupy a more fertile area of land for hunting-gathering purposes. In this case, the population growth rate of family $i$ in ([12]) becomes

(22) \begin{equation} g_{i,t}=\frac{\gamma }{\rho }\left [ \theta (s_{i,t}b_{i})l^{\alpha }\left ( \frac{Z}{N_{t}}\right ) ^{1-\alpha }-\kappa \right ] -1\text{,} \end{equation}

which shows that the relative population size $s_{i,t}$ now plays a role. The family that dominates in the long run may no longer be the one with the largest brain size $b^{\max }$ . Instead, the initial population share $ s_{i,0}$ also matters. Specifically, the family with the largest $ s_{i,0}b_{i}$ dominates the population in the long run as its population share $s_{i,t}$ rises over time and eventually converges to unity (i.e., $ s_{i,t}\rightarrow 1$ ). In other words, a human species with a relatively large brain size (e.g., the Neanderthals) may not survive in the long run because its initial population size is relatively small.

4.2 Body mass

Our model assumes that a larger brain size carries a benefit to productivity but requires higher subsistence consumption. Considering the evolution of human body mass, Lagerlof (Reference Lagerlof2007) and Dalgaard and Strulik (Reference Dalgaard and Strulik2015) also assume that a higher body mass has a positive effect on productivity but requires higher subsistence consumption. Therefore, one natural question is how the evolution of human body mass differs from the evolution of human brain size.

Empirically, Lagerlof (Reference Lagerlof2007) documents that the average human body mass increased from 61.8 kg roughly 1.8 million years ago to 76.0 kg about 36-75 thousand years ago.Footnote 23 This 23% increase in human body mass is significant but not as much as the increase in human brain size, which more than doubled in the last 2 million years. Therefore, the increase in human brain size is not a mere reflection of a higher human body mass. Rather, human brain size has increased relative to human body mass.Footnote 24

Theoretically, if we modify the hunting-gathering productivity function as $ \theta _{i}=\theta (B_{i})$ and the subsistence requirement function as $ \kappa _{i}=\kappa (B_{i})$ , which are both increasing in the body mass $ B_{i}$ of family $i\in \{1,\ldots, m\}$ . Then, this alternative model could generate the same implication that the average human body mass rises over time. However, given that the increase in human brain size is quantitatively more prominent in the data than the increase in human body mass, it is arguably more important to apply an evolutionary growth model (like the one in this study) to the evolution of human brain size than that of human body mass.Footnote 25

5. Conclusion

In this study, we have developed a hunting-gathering Malthusian growth model with heterogeneity in human brain size, which gives rise to natural selection and brain size evolution. We find that if the cognitive advantage of a larger brain dominates its higher metabolic costs, then the average human brain size increases over time, which is consistent with the rising trend in brain size of archaic human species. Furthermore, we have used our evolutionary growth-theoretic framework to show how an improvement in hunting-gathering productivity (e.g., the discovery and use of fire) could give rise to an expanding brain size in human evolution. Quantitatively, our Malthusian model is able to replicate the trend in hominin brain evolution over the last 10 million years. In the modern time, as the human society evolves away from the Malthusian equilibrium, there will emerge additional factors that determine human brain size. For example, medical technological progress (such as the invention of cesarean section) can overcome the limitation in the size of human birth canal in allowing for further growth in human infant brain size. Therefore, introducing medical technological progress to the Malthusian growth model could be an interesting extension for future research.

Finally, we conclude with the following discussion. Our growth-theoretic analysis assumes that the range of human brain size is exogenous. It is the population share that changes endogenously over time, which in turn gives rise to an endogenous evolution of the average brain size. One can endogenize the range of brain size, for example, by assuming that the average brain size has a spillover effect on its range, such that each family’s brain size in the next generation grows by the same proportion as growth in the average brain size across families in the current generation. We leave this extension to future research.

A. Appendix A

In our baseline model, we consider a simple land-division rule in ([10]). In this appendix, we consider a more general land-division rule given byFootnote 26

(23) \begin{equation} Z_{i,t}=\frac{(N_{i,t})^{\phi }}{\sum _{j=1}^{m}(N_{j,t})^{\phi }}Z\text{,} \end{equation}

which nests ([10]) as a special case with $\phi \rightarrow 1$ . Here, we consider another parameter space given by $\phi \in \lbrack 0,1)$ . This parameter $\phi$ captures the elasticity of the relative land ratio $ Z_{i,t}/Z_{j,t}$ with respect to the relative family size $N_{i,t}/N_{j,t}$ . In this case, all families with different brain sizes survive in the long run. To see this result, we use ([23]) to modify ([12]) as

(24) \begin{equation} \frac{\Delta N_{i,t}}{N_{i,t}}=\frac{\gamma }{\rho }\left [ \theta _{i}l^{\alpha }\left ( \frac{Z_{i,t}}{N_{i,t}}\right ) ^{1-\alpha }-\kappa _{i} \right ] -1=\frac{\gamma }{\rho }\left [ \theta _{i}l^{\alpha }\left ( \frac{ (N_{i,t})^{\phi }}{\sum _{j=1}^{m}(N_{j,t})^{\phi }}\frac{Z}{N_{i,t}}\right ) ^{1-\alpha }-\kappa _{i}\right ] -1\text{.} \end{equation}

If $\phi =0$ , then the steady-state population size of any family $i\in \{1,\ldots, m\}$ is

(25) \begin{equation} N_{i}=\left ( \frac{\gamma \theta _{i}l^{\alpha }}{\rho +\gamma \kappa _{i}} \right ) ^{1/(1-\alpha )}\frac{Z}{m}\text{,} \end{equation}

which is increasing in hunting-gathering productivity $\theta _{i}=\theta (b_{i})$ and decreasing in the subsistence requirement $\kappa _{i}=\kappa (b_{i})$ . Therefore, a larger brain size $b_{i}$ has a positive effect on the steady-state population size of family $i$ via a higher level of hunting-gathering productivity $\theta _{i}$ and also a negative effect via a higher subsistence requirement $\kappa _{i}$ .

If $\phi =(0,1)$ , then the steady-state population size of family $i\in \{1,\ldots, m\}$ is given by

(26) \begin{equation} N_{i}=\left ( \frac{\gamma \theta _{i}l^{\alpha }}{\rho +\gamma \kappa _{i}} \right ) ^{1/(1-\alpha )}\frac{Z}{\sum _{j=1}^{m}(N_{j}/N_{i})^{\phi }}\text{,} \end{equation}

where the relative family size is given by

(27) \begin{equation} \frac{N_{i}}{N_{j}}=\left [ \frac{\theta _{i}/(\rho +\gamma \kappa _{i})}{ \theta _{j}/(\rho +\gamma \kappa _{j})}\right ] ^{1/[(1-\alpha )(1-\phi )]} \text{.} \end{equation}

Therefore, $N_{i}$ continues to be increasing in hunting-gathering productivity $\theta _{i}$ and decreasing in the subsistence requirement $ \kappa _{i}$ . As before, a larger brain size $b_{i}$ has a positive effect on the steady-state population size of family $i$ via a higher level of hunting-gathering productivity $\theta _{i}$ and a negative effect via a higher subsistence requirement $\kappa _{i}$ . Interestingly, larger brain sizes $b_{j}$ of other families $j$ now have a negative effect on the steady-state population size of family $i$ via their higher level of hunting-gathering productivity $\theta _{j}$ and a positive effect via their higher subsistence requirement $\kappa _{j}$ .

More importantly, for $\phi \in \lbrack 0,1)$ , the steady-state population size of all families $i\in \{1,\ldots, m\}$ remains strictly positive. In this case, even human species with the smallest brain size $b^{\min }$ continue to survive in the long run. This counterfactual outcome deserves attention as it allows for the possibility of trade in different food products between different human species. For example, there is evidence that Neanderthals hunted large mammals whereas early sapiens hunted smaller preys.Footnote 27

Footnotes

The author would like to thank the Associate Editor, two anonymous referees, Yuichi Furukawa, Xilin Wang and Rongxin Xu for their helpful comments and gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Asia-Pacific Academy of Economics and Management at the University of Macau. The usual disclaimer applies.

1 See DeSilva et al. (Reference DeSilva, Traniello, Claxton and Fannin2021) for data on a rising trend in human brain size starting over 2 million years ago. They also find that there may have been a brain size reduction since 3000 years ago; however, a subsequent study by Villmoare and Grabowski (Reference Villmoare and Grabowski2022) questions the validity of this recent reduction in human brain size.

2 Existing evidence suggests that both Homo neanderthalensis and Homo sapiens evolved from Homo heidelbergensis, rather than Homo neanderthalensis evolving into Homo sapiens.

3 Another exception is Homo floresiensis, who lived in the island of Flores, Indonesia from possibly 190,000 to 50,000 years ago and had a small brain size of about 420 $\textrm{cm}^{3}$ , which was likely due to island dwarfism.

4 See van Valen (Reference van Valen1974) and Lynn (Reference Lynn1990) for estimates of the cognitive advantage of a larger human brain size. See Gonzalez-Forero and Gardner (Reference Gonzalez-Forero and Gardner2018) for estimates of the metabolic costs of the human brain.

5 See Hansson and Stuart (Reference Hansson and Stuart1990) and Rogers (Reference Rogers1994) for early economic models of natural selection of agents with different time preferences but not in a Malthusian environment. See also Robson (Reference Robson2001) for a survey of this related branch of the literature.

6 See Collins et al. (Reference Collins, Baer and Weber2014) for an interesting quantitative analysis of the Galor–Moav model.

7 See Ashraf and Galor (Reference Ashraf and Galor2018) for a comprehensive survey of this literature.

8 Chu, Peretto and Furukawa (Reference Chu, Peretto and Furukawa2024) explore the endogenous transition of human society from multiple states to a unified empire in an agricultural Malthusian economy.

9 Appendix A considers a more general land-division rule.

10 It is useful to note that $g_{i,t}$ simply depends on $N_{t}$ (instead of $ N_{i,t}$ ) due to $Z_{i,t}=s_{i,t}Z$ in ((10)).

11 Here, we assume that the initial level of population is below the steady-state equilibrium level.

12 The approximation $N_{t+1}\approx N_{t}$ implicitly assumes that the brain size of an individual family has a negligible effect on the total population growth rate $g_{t}$ . In general, $\Delta s_{i,t}/s_{i,t}=(g_{i,t}-g_{t})/(1+g_{t})$ .

13 See for example, Galor (Reference Galor2022, p. 16-17).

14 A related interpretation can also be applied to the cost parameter $ \overline{\kappa }$ .

15 If the inequality in ([16]) is reversed, then brain size would eventually converge to $b^{\min }$ instead. However, if initial population $N_{0}$ is sufficiently small, then the positive effect of $b_{i}$ may still dominate but only initially.

16 See Fonseca-Azevedo and Herculano-Houzel (Reference Fonseca-Azevedo and Herculano-Houzel2012), Galor (Reference Galor2022, p. 17) and Ofek (Reference Ofek2001, p. 73).

17 Here, we assume that at least one of the families $i\in \{1,\ldots, m\}$ has this brain size $b^{\ast }$ .

18 Here, we assume that the average brain size at time 0 is below $b^{\ast }$ .

19 See Figure 1 of DeSilva et al. (Reference DeSilva, Traniello, Claxton and Fannin2021).

20 In other words, at larger values of $\rho /(\gamma \overline{\kappa })$ , the trend of human brain size from 2.5 million years ago becomes more linear and less consistent with DeSilva et al. (Reference DeSilva, Traniello, Claxton and Fannin2021).

21 In Appendix A, we also consider a more general land-division rule.

22 We would like to thank a referee for suggesting this extension.

23 Since then, the average human body mass has fallen back to 58.2 kg in recent times.

24 Grabowski (Reference Grabowski2016) argues that the increase in human body mass may be the result of a larger brain size.

25 We would like to thank a referee for this suggestion.

26 Chu (Reference Chu2023) also adopts this conflict success function to explore the Neanderthal extinction.

27 See for example Fa et al. (Reference Fa, Stewart, Lloveras and Vargas2013).

References

Ashraf, Q. and Galor, O.. (2011). Dynamics and stagnation in the malthusian epoch. American Economic Review 101, 20032041.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ashraf, Q. and Galor, O.. (2018). The macrogenoeconomics of comparative development. Journal of Economic Literature 56, 11191155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chu, A. (2023). Natural selection and neanderthal extinction in a malthusian economy. Journal of Population Economics 36, 16411656.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chu, A., Peretto, P. and Furukawa, Y.. (2024). Evolution from political fragmentation to a unified empire in a malthusian economy. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 222, 284293.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chu, A. and Xu, R.. (2024). From neolithic revolution to industrialization. Macroeconomic Dynamics 28, 699717.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collins, J., Baer, B. and Weber, E. J.. (2014). Economic growth and evolution: parental preference for quality and quantity of offspring. Macroeconomic Dynamics 18, 17731796.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dalgaard, C.-J. and Strulik, H.. (2015). The physiological foundations of the wealth of nations. Journal of Economic Growth 20, 3773.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeSilva, J. M., Traniello, J. F. A., Claxton, A. G. and Fannin, L. D.. (2021). When and why did human brains decrease in size? A new change-point analysis and insights from brain evolution in ants. Frontiers in Ecology and Evolution 9, 742639.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fa, J., Stewart, J., Lloveras, L. and Vargas, J.. (2013). Rabbits and hominin survival in iberia. Journal of Human Evolution 64, 233241.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fonseca-Azevedo, K. and Herculano-Houzel, S.. (2012). Metabolic constraint imposes tradeoff between body size and number of brain neurons in human evolution. Proceedings of The National Academy of Sciences of The United States of America 109, 1857118576.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Galor, O. (2022). The Journey of Humanity: The Origins of Wealth and Inequality, Dutton.Google Scholar
Galor, O. and Klemp, M.. (2019). Human genealogy reveals a selective advantage to moderate fecundity. Nature Ecology & Evolution 3, 853857.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Galor, O. and Moav, O.. (2002). Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 11331191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. and Ozak, O.. (2016). The agricultural origins of time preference. American Economic Review 106, 30643103.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Galor, O. and Michalopoulos, S.. (2012). Evolution and the growth process: natural selection of entrepreneurial traits. Journal of Economic Theory 147, 759780.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gonzalez-Forero, M. and Gardner, A.. (2018). Inference of ecological and social drivers of human brain-size evolution. Nature 557, 554557.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gowlett, J. A. J. (2016). The discovery of fire by humans: a long and convoluted process. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 371, 20150164.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Grabowski, M. (2016). Bigger brains led to bigger bodies?: the correlated evolution of human brain and body size. Current Anthropology 57, 174196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansson, I. and Stuart, C.. (1990). Malthusian selection of preferences. American Economic Review 80, 529544 Google Scholar
Heldstab, S. A., Isler, K., Graber, S. M., Schuppli, C. and van Schaik, C. P.. (2022). The economics of brain size evolution in vertebrates. Current Biology 32, R697R708.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lagerlof, N.-P. (2007). Long-run trends in human body mass. Macroeconomic Dynamics 11, 367387 Google Scholar
Lynn, R. (1990). The evolution of brain size and intelligence in man. Human Evolution 5, 241244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malthus, T. R. (1798). An Essay on the Principle of Population, Oxford World’s Classics.Google Scholar
Ofek, H. (2001). Second Nature: Economic Origins of Human Evolution, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robson, A. (2001). The biological basis of economic behavior. Journal of Economic Literature 39, 1133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robson, A. and Kaplan, H.. (2003). The evolution of human life expectancy and intelligence in hunter-gatherer economies. American Economic Review 93, 150169.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rogers, A. (1994). Evolution of time preference by natural selection. American Economic Review 84, 460481 Google Scholar
van Valen, L. (1974). Brain size and intelligence in man. American Journal of Biological Anthropology 40, 417423.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Villmoare, B. and Grabowski, M.. (2022). Did the transition to complex societies in the holocene drive a reduction in brain size? A reassessment of the DeSilva, et al., 2021 hypothesis. Frontiers in Ecology and Evolution 10, 963568.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Human brain size

Figure 1

Table 2. Changes in productivity $\overline{\theta }$

Figure 2

Figure 1. Simulated trend of hominin brain size.