Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T06:13:25.240Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

HOW POWERFUL ARE TRADE UNIONS? A SKILL-BIASED TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE APPROACH

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 June 2017

Antonio Neto*
Affiliation:
University of Porto, Faculty of Economics, and CEF.UP
Oscar Afonso
Affiliation:
University of Porto, Faculty of Economics, and CEFAGE-UBI
Sandra T. Silva
Affiliation:
University of Porto, Faculty of Economics, and CEF.UP
*
Address correspondence to: Antonio Neto, School of Economics and Management (FEP), University of Porto, Portugal; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

This paper proposes a new theoretical framework aimed at understanding the link between technological change, skill premium, and employment. We build an endogenous growth model of directed technological change with vertical research and development (R&D) in which low-skilled workers might be organized in a trade union. This union can act as a monopoly seller of labor and decide unilaterally the low-skilled wage, or as a managerial union that bargains wage and employment with the employers' federation, i.e., firms. Our results suggest that (i) the impacts of trade unions on technological-bias and on the level of (un)employment crucially depend on their type and preferences; and (ii) trade unions can actually increase low-skilled wages and employment if they have some bargaining power and are employment-oriented. Furthermore, our framework provides some highlights to explain the relationship between wage dispersion and the deunionization process that occurred in the United Kingdom and the United States during the 1980s.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We particularly thank Philippe Aghion for valuable comments and suggestions. We also thank Ana Paula Ribeiro for her contributions on the labor market framework, Natércia Fortuna for her help with the econometric analysis, and Pedro Gil for his pertinent remarks regarding the general framework of the model. This research has been financed by Portuguese Public Funds through FCT (Fundação para a Ciência e a Tecnologia) in the framework of the project PEst-OE/EGE/UI4105/2014. António Neto would also like to acknowledge FCT for the financial support through the doctoral grant SFRH/BD/80734/2011. CEFAGE-UBI has financial support from FCT and FEDER/COMPETE, through grant UID/ECO/04007/2013 (POCI-01-0145-FEDER-007659).

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, D. (1998) Why do new technologies complement skills? Directed technical change and wage inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113 (4), 10551090.10.1162/003355398555838Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2002) Technical change, inequality, and the labor market. Journal of Economic Literature 40 (1), 772.10.1257/jel.40.1.7Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2003) Patterns of skill premia. Review of Economic Studies 70 (2), 199230.10.1111/1467-937X.00242Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2015) Localised and biased technologies: Atkinson and Stiglitz's new view, induced innovations, and directed technological change. Economic Journal 125 (583), 443463.10.1111/ecoj.12227Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Aghion, P., and Violante, G. L. (2001) Deunionization, technical change and inequality. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 55 (1), 229264.10.1016/S0167-2231(01)00058-6Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Zilibotti, F. (2001) Productivity differences. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (2), 563606.10.1162/00335530151144104Google Scholar
Afonso, O. (2006) Skill-biased technological knowledge without scale effects. Applied Economics 38 (1), 1321.10.1080/00036840500367625Google Scholar
Aghion, P. (2002) Schumpeterian growth theory and the dynamics of income inequality. Econometrica 70 (3), 855882.10.1111/1468-0262.00312Google Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60 (2), 323351.10.2307/2951599Google Scholar
Attanasio, O. P. and Weber, G. (1993) Consumption growth, the interest rate and aggregation. The Review of Economic Studies 60 (3), 631649.10.2307/2298128Google Scholar
Barro, R. and Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004) Economic Growth, 2nd ed. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Becker, G. and Murphy, K. (1992) The division of labour, coordination costs, and knowledge. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (4), 11371160.10.2307/2118383Google Scholar
Bertinelli, L., Cardi, O., and Sen, P. (2013) Deregulation shock in product market and unemployment. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37 (4), 711734.10.1016/j.jedc.2012.11.004Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. (2004) The economic future of Europe. Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 (4), 326.10.1257/0895330042632735Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. (2007) Adjustment within the euro. The difficult case of Portugal. Portuguese Economic Journal 6 (1), 121.10.1007/s10258-006-0015-4Google Scholar
Booth, A. L. (1995) The Economics of the Trade Union. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Booth, A. L. (2014) Wage determination and imperfect competition. Labour Economics 30, 5358.10.1016/j.labeco.2014.06.010Google Scholar
Bryson, A. (2007) The effect of trade unions on wages. Reflects et perspectives de la vie économique 46 (2–3), 3345.10.3917/rpve.462.0033Google Scholar
Chang, J.-J. and Hung, H.-W. (2016) Trade unions, unemployment, economic growth, and income inequality. Macroeconomic Dynamics 20 (1), 404428.10.1017/S1365100514000443Google Scholar
Chang, J.-J., Shaw, M.-F., and Lai, C.-C. (2007) A “managerial” trade union and economic growth. European Economic Review 51 (2), 365384.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2005.12.003Google Scholar
Checchi, D., Visser, J., and Werfhorst, H. G. v. d. (2007) Inequality and Union Membership: The Impact of Relative Earnings Position and Inequality Attitudes. Discussion paper series IZA no. 2691.Google Scholar
Chu, A. C., Cozzi, G., and Furukawa, Y. (2016) Unions, innovation and cross-country wage inequality. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 64, 104118.10.1016/j.jedc.2015.12.004Google Scholar
Chusseau, N., Dumont, M., and Hellier, J. (2008) Explaining rising inequality: Skill-biased technical change and north–south trade. Journal of Economic Surveys 22 (3), 409457.10.1111/j.1467-6419.2007.00537.xGoogle Scholar
Clark, A. (1990) Efficient bargains and the Mcdonald–Solow conjecture. Journal of Labor Economics 8 (4), 502528.10.1086/298232Google Scholar
Connolly, M. (2003) The dual nature of trade: Measuring its impact on imitation and growth. Journal of Development Economics 72 (1), 3155.10.1016/S0304-3878(03)00067-1Google Scholar
Dinopoulos, E. and Thompson, P. (1999) Scale effects in Schumpeterian models of economic growth. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 9 (2), 157185.10.1007/s001910050079Google Scholar
Dobbelaere, S. (2004) Estimation of price-cost margins and union bargaining power for Belgian manufacturing. International Journal of Industrial Organization 22 (10), 13811398.10.1016/j.ijindorg.2004.10.003Google Scholar
Dobbelaere, S., Kiyota, K., and Mairesse, J. (2015) Product and labor market imperfections and scale economies: Micro-evidence on France, Japan and the Netherlands. Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2), 290322.10.1016/j.jce.2014.08.006Google Scholar
Dobbelaere, S. and Mairesse, J. (2013) Panel data estimates of the production function and product and labor market imperfections. Journal of Applied Econometrics 28 (1), 146.10.1002/jae.1256Google Scholar
Donado, A. and Wälde, K. (2012) How trade unions increase welfare. Economic Journal 122 (563), 9901009.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2012.02513.xGoogle Scholar
Dowrick, S. (1990) Wage pressure, bargaining and price-cost margins in UK manufacturing. The Journal of Industrial Economics 38 (3), 239267.10.2307/2098497Google Scholar
Dunlop, J. (1944) Wage Determination Under Trade Unions. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Etro, F. (2008) Growth leaders. Journal of Macroeconomics 30 (3), 11481172.10.1016/j.jmacro.2007.04.003Google Scholar
Fadinger, H. and Mayr, K. (2014) Skill-biased technological change, unemployment, and brain drain. Journal of the European Economic Association 12 (2), 397431.10.1111/jeea.12049Google Scholar
Faia, E. and Rossi, L. (2013) Union power, collective bargaining, and optimal monetary policy. Economic Inquiry 51 (1), 408427.10.1111/j.1465-7295.2012.00461.xGoogle Scholar
Feng, L. (2014) Taste shocks, endogenous labor supply, and equity home bias. Macroeconomic Dynamics 18 (7), 14661487.10.1017/S1365100512001046Google Scholar
Freeman, R. B. and Medoff, J. L. (1984) What Do Unions Do? New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Galor, O. and Moav, O. (2000) Ability-biased technological transition, wage inequality, and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (2), 469497.10.1162/003355300554827Google Scholar
Gartner, H., Schank, T., and Schnabel, C. (2013) Wage cyclicality under different regimes of industrial relations. Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society 52 (2), 516540.Google Scholar
Gil, P., Afonso, O., and Vasconcelos, P. B. (2016) A note on skill-structure shocks, the share of the high-tech sector, and economic growth dynamics. Macroeconomic Dynamics 20 (7), 19061923.10.1017/S1365100515000152Google Scholar
Gil, P. M., Brito, P., and Afonso, O. (2013) Growth and firm dynamics with horizontal and vertical R&D. Macroeconomic Dynamics 17, 14381466.10.1017/S1365100512000181Google Scholar
Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1991) Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hornstein, A., Krusell, P., and Violante, G. (2005) The effects of technical change on labor market inequalities. In Aghion, P. and Durlauf, S. N. (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1, (suppl. part b), chap. 20, pp. 12751370. Amsterdam: Elsevier B.V.Google Scholar
Johnson, G. E. (1990) Work rules, featherbedding, and Pareto-optimal union-management bargaining. Journal of Labor Economics 8 (1), S237S259.10.1086/298251Google Scholar
Karabarbounis, L. and Neiman, B. (2014) The global decline of the labor share. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (1), 61103.10.1093/qje/qjt032Google Scholar
Kaufman, B. (2002) Models of union wage determination: What have we learned since Dunlop and Ross? Industrial Relations 41 (1), 110158.Google Scholar
Kortum, S. (1997) Research, patenting, and technological change. Econometrica 65 (6), 13891419.10.2307/2171741Google Scholar
Kreickemeier, U. and Nelson, D. (2006) Fair wages, unemployment and technological change in a global economy. Journal of International Economics 70 (2), 451469.10.1016/j.jinteco.2005.11.003Google Scholar
Krusell, P. and Rudanko, L. (2016) Unions in a frictional labor market. Journal of Monetary Economics 80, 3550.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2016.04.006Google Scholar
Kurokawa, Y. (2014) A survey of trade and wage inequality: Anomalies, resolutions and new trends. Journal of Economic Surveys 28 (1), 169193.10.1111/joes.12007Google Scholar
Kwan, Y. K. and Lai, E. L.-C. (2003) Intellectual property rights protection and endogenous economic growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 27 (5), 853873.10.1016/S0165-1889(02)00018-0Google Scholar
Lawson, N. (2011) Is collective bargaining Pareto efficient? A survey of the literature. Journal of Labor Research 32 (3), 282304.10.1007/s12122-011-9112-yGoogle Scholar
Layard, R. and Nickell, S. (1990) Is unemployment lower if unions bargain over employment? Quarterly Journal of Economics 105 (3), 773787.10.2307/2937898Google Scholar
Lingens, J. (2003) The impact of a unionised labour market in a Schumpeterian growth model. Labour Economics 10 (1), 91104.10.1016/S0927-5371(02)00135-5Google Scholar
Lingens, J. (2007) Unions, wage setting, and economic growth. Economic Modelling 24 (1), 167188.10.1016/j.econmod.2006.06.009Google Scholar
McDonald, I. M. and Solow, R. M. (1981) Wage bargaining and employment. American Economic Review 71 (5), 896908.Google Scholar
Millard, S. P. and Mortensen, D. T. (1997) The Unemployment and Welfare Effects of Labour Market Policy: A Comparison of the USA and the UK. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mortensen, D. and Pissarides, C. (1994) Job creation and job destruction in the theory of unemployment. Review of Economic Studies 61 (3), 397415.10.2307/2297896Google Scholar
Nelson, R. R. and Phelps, E. S. (1966) Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. American Economic Review 56 (1/2), 6975.Google Scholar
Oesch, D. (2010) What explains high unemployment among low-skilled workers? Evidence from 21 OECD countries. European Journal of Industrial Relations 16 (1), 3955.10.1177/0959680109355307Google Scholar
Pencavel, J. H. (1984) The tradeoff between wages and employment in trade union objectives. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 99 (2), 215231.10.2307/1885523Google Scholar
Reis, A. B. and Sequeira, T. N. (2007) Human capital and overinvestment in R&D. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 109 (3), 573591.10.1111/j.1467-9442.2007.00508.xGoogle Scholar
Ross, A. (1948) Trade Union Wage Policy. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Scheuer, S. (2011) Union membership variation in Europe: A ten-country comparative analysis. European Journal of Industrial Relations 17 (1), 5773.10.1177/0959680110392739Google Scholar
Schultz, T. (1975) The value of the ability to deal with disequilibria. Journal of Economic Literature 13 (3), 827846.Google Scholar
Şener, F. (2008) R&D policies, endogenous growth and scale effects. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32 (12), 38953916.10.1016/j.jedc.2008.03.009Google Scholar
Thompson, P. and Waldo, D. (1994) Growth and trustified capitalism. Journal of Monetary Economics 34 (3), 445462.10.1016/0304-3932(94)90028-0Google Scholar
Violante, G. L. (2008) Skill-biased technical change. In Durlauf, S. N. and Blume, L. E. (eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Retrieved 7 April 2017 from http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_S000493Google Scholar
Wälde, K. (2000) Egalitarian and elitist education systems as the basis for international differences in wage inequality. European Journal of Political Economy 16 (3), 445468.10.1016/S0176-2680(99)00055-5Google Scholar