Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gvvz8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T06:33:52.422Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

HETEROGENEITY IN WAGE SETTING BEHAVIOR IN A NEW-KEYNESIAN MODEL

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 July 2019

Sylvester C. W. Eijffinger
Affiliation:
Tilburg University, CentER, European Banking Center, CEPR
Anderson Grajales-Olarte*
Affiliation:
Tilburg University, CentER, European Banking Center, Banco de la República (Central Bank of Colombia)
Burak R. Uras
Affiliation:
Tilburg University, CentER, European Banking Center
*
Address correspondence to: Anderson Grajales-Olarte, Banco de la República Carrera 7 # 14-78, Bogotá, Colombia; e-mails: [email protected]; [email protected]. Phone: +57 300 4 24 73 78.

Abstract

In this paper we estimate a New-Keynesian dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (NK DSGE) model with heterogeneity in price and wage setting behavior. In a recent study, Coibion and Gorodnichenko develop a DSGE model, in which firms follow four different types of price setting schemes: sticky prices, sticky information, rule-of-thumb, or flexible prices. We enrich Coibion and Gorodnichenko framework by incorporating heterogeneity in nominal wage setting behavior among households. We solve this DSGE model and estimate it using Bayesian techniques for the US economy from 1955 to 2008. The estimation results show the relevance of heterogeneity in wage setting among households. More importantly, we identify qualitative and quantitative business cycle features allowed by the heterogeneity in wage rigidity, such as the persistence in price and wage inflation, which a standard NK model with only Calvo-type wage rigidity fails to achieve. We also show that modeling wage-rigidity heterogeneity—as opposed to standard Calvo wages—amplifies the macroeconomic output fluctuations resulting from a technology shock while it mitigates the output fluctuations following a monetary tightening.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© 2019 Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We wish to thank William Barnett, Harry Huizinga, Louis Raes, Damjan Pfajfar, Ata Bertay, an associate editor, and an anonymous referee for their valuable comments and suggestions. We also thank the participants of the Tilburg EconomicsWorkshop and the European Banking Center Conference. The views expressed in this document are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Central Bank of Colombia or those of its Board of Directors. All remaining errors are ours.

References

Adjemian, S., Bastani, H., Juillard, M., Karamé, F., Mihoubi, F., Perendia, G., Pfeifer, J., Ratto, M. and Villemot, S. (2011) Dynare: Reference Manual, Version 4. CEPREMAP, Dynare Working Paper, 1.Google Scholar
Altig, D., Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M. and Linde, J. (2002) Technology shocks and aggregate fluctuations. Unpublished Draft Paper.Google Scholar
Alvarez, L., Dhyne, E., Hoeberichts, M., Kwapil, C., Le Bihan, H., Lünnemann, P., Martins, F., Sabbatini, R., Stahl, H., Vermeulen, P. and Jouko, V. (2006) Sticky prices in the Euro Area: A summary of new micro-evidence. Journal of the European Economic Association 4(May), 575584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amato, J. D. and Laubach, T. (2003) Estimation and control of an optimization-based model with sticky prices and wages. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 27(7), 11811215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
An, S. and Schorfheide, F.. (2007) Bayesian analysis of DSGE models. Econometric Reviews 26(2–4), 113172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andersen, T. M. (1998) Persistency in sticky price models. European Economic Review 42(3–5), 593603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andrés, J., López-Salido, D. and Nelson, E. (2005) Sticky-Price Models and the Natural Rate Hypothesis. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Working Paper.10.20955/wp.2005.018CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angeloni, I., Aucremanne, L., Ehrmann, M., Galí, J., Levin, A. and Smets, F. (2006) New evidence on inflation persistence and price stickiness in the euro area: Implications for macro modeling. Journal of the European Economic Association 4, 562574.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, K. (2001) Optimal monetary policy responses to relative-price changes. Journal of Monetary Economics 48, 5580.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barattieri, A., Basu, S. and Gottschalk, P. (2014) Some evidence on the importance of sticky wages. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 6(1), 70101.Google Scholar
Belgibayeva, A. and Horvath, M. (2017) Real rigidities and optimal stabilization at the zero lower bound in New Keynesian economies. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 130.Google Scholar
Bihan, H. L., Montornès, J. and Heckel, T. (2012) Sticky wages: Evidence from quarterly microeconomic data. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4(3), 132.Google Scholar
Bils, M. and Klenow, P. J. (2004) Some evidence on the importance of sticky prices. Journal of Political Economy 112(5), 947985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvo, G. (1983) Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12(1978), 383398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campolmi, A. (2014) Which inflation to target? A small open economy with sticky wages. Macroeconomic Dynamics 18(1), 145174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Canova, F. (2007) Methods for Applied Macroeconomic Research. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caplin, A. and Leahy, J. (1991) State-dependent pricing and the dynamics of money and output. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(3), 683708.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlsson, M. and Skans, O. N. (2012) Evaluating microfoundations for aggregate price rigidities: Evidence from matched firm-level data on product prices and unit labor cost. American Economic Review 102(4), 15711595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlstrom, C. and Fuerst, T. S. (2010) Nominal rigidities, residential investment, and adjustment costs. Macroeconomic Dynamics 14(1), 136148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carvalho, C. (2006) Heterogeneity in price stickiness and the real effects of monetary shocks. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 6(3), 158.Google Scholar
Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C. (1999) Monetary policy shocks: What have we learned and to what end? In: Taylor, J. B. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, pp. 65148. Amsterdam: Elsevier, North Holland.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C. (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 113(1), 145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christoffel, K. and Linzert, T. (2010) The role of real wage rigidity and labor market frictions for inflation persistence. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42(7), 14351446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coibion, O. and Gorodnichenko, Y. (2011) Strategic interaction among heterogeneous price-setters in an estimated DSGE model. Review of Economics and Statistics 93(August), 920940.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Graeve, F. (2008) The external finance premium and the macroeconomy: US post-WWII evidence. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32(11), 34153440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeJong, D. N. and Dave, C. (2011) Structural Macroeconometrics, 2nd ed. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
DeJong, D. N., Ingram, B. F. and Whiteman, C. H. (2000) A Bayesian approach to dynamic macroeconomics. Journal of Econometrics 98(2), 203223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhyne, E., Alvarez, L., Bihan, H. L., Veronese, G., Dias, D., Hoffmann, J., Jonker, N., Lünnemann, P., Rumler, F. and Jouko, V. (2006) Price changes in the euro area and the United States: Some facts from individual consumer price data. Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(2), 171192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixon, H. and Bihan, H. L. (2012) Generalized Taylor and generalized Calvo price and wage setting: Micro-evidence with macro implications. The Economic Journal 122, 532554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Druant, M., Fabiani, S., Kezdi, G., Lamo, A., Martins, F. and Sabbatini, R. (2009). How Are Firms’ Wages and Prices Linked: Survey Evidence in Europe. European Central Bank, Working Paper Series, 1084.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Druant, M., Fabiani, S., Kezdi, G., Lamo, A., Martins, F. and Sabbatini, R. (2012). Firms’ price and wage adjustment in Europe: Survey evidence on nominal stickiness. Labour Economics 19(5), 772782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edge, R., Laubach, T. and Williams, J. (2003) The Responses of Wages and Prices to Technology Shocks. FRB of San Francisco, Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erceg, C., Henderson, D. W. and Levin, A. (2000) Optimal monetary policy with staggered wage and price contracts. Journal of Monetary Economics 46(2), 281313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernández-Villaverde, J. (2010) The econometrics of DSGE models. SERIEs 1(1–2), 349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galí, J. (2008) Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Galí, J. (2013) Notes for a new guide to Keynes (I): Wages, aggregate demand, and employment. Journal of the European Economic Association 11(October), 9731003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galí, J. and Monacelli, T. (2014) Understanding the Gains from Wage Flexibility: The Exchange Rate Connection. CEPR, Discussion Paper Series.Google Scholar
Galí, J., Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2012) Unemployment in an Estimated New Keynesian Model. In: McCallum, B. (ed.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, pp. 329360. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Gelman, A., Carlin, J., Stern, H., Dunson, D., Vehtari, A. and Rubin, D. (2013) Bayesian Data Analysis, 3rd ed. Boca Raton, Florida: Chapman & Hall. Taylor & Francis Group.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geweke, J. (1999) Using simulation methods for Bayesian econometric models: Inference, development, and communication. Econometric Reviews 18(1), 173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, P. K. and Hellerstein, R. (2009) How Rigid Are Producer Prices? Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Staff Reports, November 2.Google Scholar
Hamilton, J. D. (2017) Why you should never use the Hodrick-Prescott filter. The Review of Economis and Statistics, 144.Google Scholar
Hirose, Y. and Inoue, A. (2016) The zero lower bound and parameter bias in an estimated DSGE model. Journal of Applied Econometrics 31(4), 630651.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoeberichts, M. and Stokman, A. (2006) Price Setting Behaviour in the Netherlands: Results of a Survey. European Central Bank, Working Paper Series, 607.Google Scholar
Huang, K. and Liu, Z. (1999) Staggered Contracts and Business Cycle Persistence. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Discussion Paper, 127.Google Scholar
Iskrev, N. (2010) Local identification in DSGE models. Journal of Monetary Economics 57(2), 189202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karagedikli, Ö., Matheson, T., Smith, C. and Vahey, S. P. (2010) RBCs and DSGEs: The computational approach to business cycle theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Surveys 24(1), 113136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, K. and Pagan, A. R. (1999) The econometric analysis of calibrated macroeconomic models. In: Hashem, P. and Wickens, M. (eds.), Handbook of Applied Econometrics Volume 1: Macroeconomics, 1st ed, pp. 309338. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing Ltd.Google Scholar
Klenow, P. J. and Kryvtsov, O. (2008) State-dependent or time-dependent pricing: Does it matter for recent US inflation? The Quarterly Journal of Economics CXXIII(August), 863904.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koop, G. (2003) Bayesian Econometrics. Chichester, England: Wiley-Interscience.Google Scholar
Lünnemann, P. and Wintr, L. (2009) Wages Are Flexible, Aren’t They? Evidence from Monthly Micro Wage Data. European Central Bank, Working Paper Series, 1074.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N. G and Reis, R. (2002). Sticky information versus sticky prices: A proposal to replace the New Keynesian Phillips curve. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4), 12951328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McFadden, D. (1989) A method of simulated moments for estimation of discrete response models without numerical integration. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 57(5), 9951026.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Middleditch, P. (2010) A New Keynesian Model with Heterogeneous Price Setting. ECB Working Paper Series, 148.Google Scholar
Midrigan, V. (2011) Menu costs, multi-product firms, and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 79(July), 11391180.Google Scholar
Nakamura, E. and Steinsson, J. (2008) Five facts about prices: A reevaluation of menu cost models. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123(4), 14151464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olivei, G. and Tenreyro, S. (2007) The timing of monetary policy shocks. The American Economic Review 97(3), 636663.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pfajfar, D. and de Ridder, M. (2017) Policy Shocks and Wage Rigidities: Empirical Evidence from Regional Effects of National Shocks. Cambridge-INET Working Paper Series.Google Scholar
Rabanal, P. (2007) Does inflation increase after a monetary policy tightening? Answers based on an estimated DSGE model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 31(3), 906937.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabanal, P. and Rubio-Ramírez, J. F. (2001) Nominal versus real wage rigidities: A Bayesian approach. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Working Paper, November.Google Scholar
Rabanal, P. and Rubio-Ramírez, J. F. (2003) Inflation persistence: How much can we explain? Economic Review 88(2), 4355.Google Scholar
Rabanal, P. and Rubio-Ramírez, J. F. (2005) Comparing New Keynesian models of the business cycle: A Bayesian approach. Journal of Monetary Economics 52(6), 11511166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotemberg, J. J. (1982) Monopolistic price adjustment and aggregate output. The Review of Economic Studies 49(4), 517531.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotemberg, J. J. and Woodford, M. (1997) An optimization-based econometric framework for the evaluation of monetary policy. In: Bernanke, B. and Julio, R. (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 12, pp. 297361. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Sargent, T. J. (1989) Two models of measurements and the investment accelerator. Journal of Political Economy 97(2), 251287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheedy, K. D. (2010) Intrinsic inflation persistence. Journal of Monetary Economics 57(8), 10491061.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sigurdsson, J. and Sigurdardottir, R. (2012) Evidence of nominal wage rigidity and wage setting from Icelandic microdata. Central Bank of Iceland, Working Paper 9676 (August 2012), 141.Google Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2003) An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro area. Journal of the European Economic Association 1(5), 11231175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2007) Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. American Economic Review 97(3), 586606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stahlschmidt, S. (2007) On the heterogeneity of price stickiness and its consequences for European monetary policy. Humboldt-Universitat zu Berlin, Unpublished Manuscript, 504055.Google Scholar
Taylor, J. B. (1999) Staggered price and wage setting in macroeconomics. Handbook of Macroeconomics 1, 10091050.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vermeulen, P., Dias, D., Dossche, M., Gautier, E., Hernando, I., Sabbatini, R. and Stahl, H. (2012) Price setting in the Euro area: Some stylized facts from individual producer price data. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 44(8), 16311650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Verona, F. and Wolters, M. (2014) Sticky information models in Dynare. Computational Economics 43(3), 357370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woodford, M. (2003) Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Eijffinger et al. supplementary material

Appendix

Download Eijffinger et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 102.4 KB