Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-q99xh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T06:33:18.711Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE DIFFUSION OF ECONOMIC ACTIVITY ACROSS SPACE: A NEW APPROACH

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 January 2021

Carmen Camacho
Affiliation:
PjSE UMR8545, Paris School of Economics and CNRS (France)
Agustín Pérez-Barahona*
Affiliation:
CY Cergy Paris Université, CNRS, THEMA and Ecole Polytechnique (France)
*
Address correspondence to: Agustín Pérez-Barahona, THEMA, CY Cergy Paris Université, 33 Boulevard du Port, 95011 Cergy-Pontoise cedex, France. e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

Dynamic spatial theory has been a fruitful approach to understanding economic phenomena involving time and space. However, several central questions still remain unresolved in this field. The identification of the social optimal allocation of economic activity across time and space is particularly problematic, not been ensured yet in economic growth. Developing a monotone method, we study the optimal solution of the spatial Ramsey model. Under fairly general assumptions, we prove the existence of unique social optimum. Considering a numerical implementation of our algorithm, we study the role played by capital mobility in the neoclassical growth environment. With capital irreversibility and economic openness, space allows for transitional dynamics. Moreover, in this context, capital mobility is beneficial as well in terms of social welfare and inequality. We also consider an application of our method to an extension of the spatial Ramsey model for optimal land-use planning.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2021

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We are thankful to Jacques Drèze, Ingmar Schumacher, Benteng Zou, and Vladimir Veliov for their comments and help. We would also like to express our gratitude to the participants at LEDa seminars (Université Paris-Dauphine), PET 2017 (Paris); EEA-ESEM 2017 (Lisboa), Atelier Methods of Economics Dynamics (Paris School of Economics), CORE@50 (Université catholique de Louvain), and Advances in Dynamic Macroeconomics (Free University of Bozen-Bolzano) for useful discussion. The Associate Editor of this Journal and two anonymous referees provided suggestions that helped to make substantial improvements to the paper. Agustín Pérez-Barahona acknowledges financial support from the Chaire Développement Durable (Ecole Polytechnique—EDF) and the Labex MME-DII.

References

Acemoglu, D. (2009) Introduction to Modern Economic Growth. NJ, USA: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ahmed, N. (1977) Optimal control of a class of strongly nonlinear parabolic systems. Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications 61, 188207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attanasio, O. and Browning, M. (1995) Consumption over the life cycle and over the business cycle. American Economic Review 85(5), 11181137.Google Scholar
Attanasio, O. and Weber, G. (1993) Consumption, the interest rate and aggregation. Review of Economic Studies 60(3), 631649.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. J. and Kurz, M. (1970) Public Investment, the Rate of Return, and Optimal Fiscal Policy. Baltimore, MA, USA: The Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Baldwin, R. and Krugman, P. (2004) Agglomeration, integration and tax harmonisation. European Economic Review 48(1), 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, R. and Martin, P. (2004) Agglomeration and regional growth. In: Henderson, V. and Thisse, J. (eds.), Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, vol. 4. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Barbu, V. and Precupanu, T. (2012) Convexity and Optimization in Banach Spaces. New York City, USA: Springer Science & Business Media.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R., G. Mankiw and X. Sala-i-Martin (1995) Capital mobility in neoclassical models of growth. American Economic Review 85(1), 103–115.Google Scholar
Barro, R. and X. Sala-i-Martin (2004) Economic Growth, 2nd ed. Cambridge, MA, USA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Bebernes, J. and Schmitt, K. (1979) On the existence of maximal and minimal solutions for parabolic partial differential equations. Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society 73(2), 211218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bental, B. (1985) Is capital mobility always desirable? A welfare analysis of portfolio autarky in a growing economy. International Economic Review 26(1), 203212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchet, A., Mossay, P. and Santambrogio, P. (2016) Existence and uniqueness of equilibrium for a spatial model of social interactions. International Economic Review 57, 3159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucekkine, R., Camacho, C. and Zou, B. (2009) Bridging the gap between growth theory and the new economic geography: The spatial Ramsey model. Macroeconomic Dynamics 13, 2045.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucekkine, R., Camacho, C. and Fabbri, G. (2013a) Spatial dynamics and convergence: The spatial AK model. Journal of Economic Theory 148, 27192736.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucekkine, R., Camacho, C. and Fabbri, G. (2013b) On the optimal control of some parabolic partial differential equations arising in economics. Serdica Mathematical Journal 39, 10011024.Google Scholar
Boucekkine, R., Fabbri, G., Salvatore, F. and Gozzi, F. (2018) Growth and agglomeration in the heterogeneous space: A generalized AK approach. Journal of Economic Geography 39, 10011024.Google Scholar
Bourguignon, F. (2015) The Globalization of Inequality. Princeton, NJ, USA: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Breinlich, H. (2006) The spatial income structure in the European Union – What role for economic geography?. Journal of Economic Geography 6, 593617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brito, P. (2004) The Dynamics of Growth and Distribution in a Spatially Heterogenous World. WP 13/2004, ISEG Working Papers.Google Scholar
Brock, W. and Xepapadeas, A. (2008) Diffusion-induced instability and pattern formation in infinite horizon recursive optimal control. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32, 27452787.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brock, W. and Xepapadeas, A. (2010) Pattern formation, spatial externalities and regulation in coupled economic-ecological systems, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 59, 149164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brock, W. and Xepapadeas, A. (2017) Climate change policy under polar amplification. European Economic Review 99, 93112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camacho, C. and Pérez-Barahona, A. (2015) Land use dynamics and the environment. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 52, 96118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camacho, C., Zou, B. and Briani, M. (2008) On the dynamics of capital accumulation across space. European Journal of Operational Research 186(2), 451465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandra, J., Lakshmikantham, V. and Leela, S. (1978) A monotone method for infinite systems of nonlinear boundary value problems. Archive for Rational Mechanics and Analysis 68(2), 179190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chetty, R. (2006) A new method of estimating risk aversion. American Economic Review 96(5), 18211834.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costello, C. and Polasky, S. (2008) Optimal harvesting of stochastic spatial resources. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 56, 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Damijan, J. and Kostevc, C. (2011) Trade liberalisation and economic geography in CEE countries: The role of FDI in the adjustment pattern of regional wages. Post-Communist Economies 23, 163189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Desmet, K. and Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2009) Spatial growth and industry age. Journal of Economic Theory 144(6), 24772502.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Desmet, K. and Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2010) On spatial dynamics. Journal of Regional Science 50(1), 4363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Desmet, K. and Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2014) Spatial development. American Economic Review 104(4), 12111243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Desmet, K. and Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2015) On the spatial economic impact of global warming. Journal of Urban Economics 88, 1637.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ekeland, I. (1974) On the variational principle. Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications 47, 324353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fabbri, G. (2016) Geographical structure and convergence: A note on geometry in spatial growth models. Journal of Economic Theory 162, 114136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fattorini, H. (1990) Some remarks on Pontryagin’s maximum principle for infinite dimensional control problems. In: Perspectives in Control Theory. Progress in Systems and Control Theory, vol. 2, pp. 12–25. Boston, MA, US: Birkhäuser.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forslid, R., Haaland, J. I. and Midelfart-Knarvik, K. (2002) A U-shaped Europe? A simulation study of industrial location. Journal of International Economics 57, 273297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, A. (1959) Convergence of solutions of parabolic equations to a steady state. Journal of Mathematics and Mechanics 8, 5776.Google Scholar
Fujita, M. and Mori, T. (2005) Frontiers of the new economic geography. Papers in Regional Science 84(3), 301521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. (1996) Convergence? Inferences from theoretical models. The Economic Journal 106, 10561069.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gori, L., Antoci, A., Fiaschi, D. and Sodini, M. (2019) Introduction to Macroeconomic Dynamics special issue on new tools for global analysis of economic dynamics. Macroeconomic Dynamics. doi: 10.1017/S1365100519000439.Google Scholar
Hadamard, J. (1923) Lectureson the Cauchy Problem in Linear Partial Differential Equations. New Haven, CT, USA: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
IBRD (2016) Taking on Inequality. Washington DC, USA: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank, World Bank Publications, The World Bank Group.Google Scholar
Kehoe, T., Levine, D. and Romer, P. (1990) Determinacy of equilibria in dynamic models with finitely many consumers. Journal of Economic Theory 50(1), 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kose, A., Prasad, E., Rogoff, K. and Wei, S. (2010) Financial globalization and economic policies. In: Rodrik, D. and Rosenzweig, M. (eds.), Handbook of Development Economics, vol. 5, Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.Google Scholar
La Torre, D., Liuzzi, D. and Marsiglio, S. (2015) Pollution diffusion and abatement activities across space and over time. Mathematical Social Sciences 78, 4863.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
La Torre, D., Liuzzi, D. and Marsiglio, S. (2019a) The optimal population size under pollution and migration externalities: A spatial control approach. Mathematical Modelling of Natural Phenomena, 14, 104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
La Torre, D., Liuzzi, D. and Marsiglio, S. (2019b) Transboundary Pollution Externalities: Think Globally, Act Locally?. arXiv:1910.04469.Google Scholar
Lions, J. (1966a) Optimisation pour certaines classes d’équations d’évolution non linéaires. Annali di Matematica Pura ed Applicata 72(1), 275–294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lions, J. (1966b) Sur quelques problèmes d’optimisation dans les equations d’evolution linéaires de type parabolique. In: Caianiello, E. (ed.), Applications of functional Analysis to Optimization. New York, USA: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Lions, J. (1972) Some Aspects of the Optimal Control of Distributed Parameter Systems. Regional Conference Series in Applied Mathematics. Philadelphia, PA, USA: SIAM.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milanovic, B. (2011) A short history of global inequality: The past two centuries. Explorations in Economic History 48, 494506.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mossay, P. and Picard, P. (2011) On spatial equilibria in a social interaction model. Journal of Economic Theory 146, 24552477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pao, C. (1992), Nonlinear Parabolic and Elliptic Equations. New York, USA: Plenum Press.Google Scholar
Patel, S. (1964) The economic distance between nations: Its origin, measurement and outlook. The Economic Journal 74(293), 119131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quah, D. (1996a) Convergence empirics across economies with (some) capital mobility. Journal of Economic Growth 1, 95124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quah, D. (1996b) Twin peaks: Growth and convergence in models of distribution dynamics. The Economic Journal 106, 10451055.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radi, D., Lamantia, F. and Bischi, G. (2019) Offshoring, reshoring, unemployment, and wage dynamics in a two-country evolutionary model. Macroeconomic Dynamics. doi: 10.1017/S1365100519000385.Google Scholar
Raymond, J. and Zidani, H. (1999) Pontryagin’s principle for time-optimal problems. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 101(2), 375402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D. and van Ypersele, T. (2001) Capital mobility, distributive conflict and international tax coordination. Journal of International Economics 54, 5773.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Santambrogio, F., Xepapadeas, A. and Yannacopoulos, A. (forthcoming) Rational expectations equilibria in a Ramsey model of optimal growth with non-local spatial externalities. Journal de Mathématiques Pures et Appliquées.Google Scholar
Sattinger, D. (1972) Monotone methods in nonlinear elliptic and parabolic boundary value problems. Indiana University Mathematics Journal 21(11), 9791000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thisse, J. (2010) Towards a unified theory of economic geography and urban economics. Journal of Regional Science 50(1), 281296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar