Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dsjbd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T20:14:44.806Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

DIAGNOSING LABOR MARKET SEARCH MODELS: A MULTIPLE-SHOCK APPROACH

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 August 2012

Kenneth Beauchemin
Affiliation:
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Murat Tasci*
Affiliation:
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
*
Address correspondence to: Murat Tasci, Research Department, P.O. Box 6387, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Cleveland, OH 44101-1387, USA; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

We construct a multiple-shock, discrete-time version of the Mortensen–Pissarides labor market search model to investigate the basic model's well-known tendency to underpredict the volatility of key labor market variables. In addition to the standard labor productivity shock, we introduce shocks to matching efficiency and job separation. We estimate the multiple-shock model and then simulate its properties. Although it generates significantly more volatility while preserving the Beveridge curve relationship, the multiple-shock model generates counterfactual implications for the cyclicality of job separations. Using a business cycle accounting approach, next we show that the model requires significantly procyclical and volatile matching efficiency and counterfactually procyclical job separations to render the observed data without error. We conjecture that the basic Mortensen–Pissarides model lacks mechanisms to generate sufficiently strong labor market reallocation over the business cycle, and suggest nontrivial labor force participation and job-to-job transitions as promising avenues of research.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Andolfatto, David (1996) Business cycles and labor market search. American Economic Review 86 (1), 112132.Google Scholar
Barnichon, Regis (2010) Building a composite help-wanted index. Economics Letters 109, 175178.Google Scholar
Barnichon, Regis and Figura, Andrew (2011a) Labor Market Heterogeneities, Matching Efficiency, and the Cyclical Behavior of the Job Finding Rate. Mimeo, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.Google Scholar
Barnichon, Regis and Figura, Andrew (2011b) What Drives Movements in the Unemployment Rate? A Decomposition of the Beveridge Curve. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2010-48.Google Scholar
Beauchemin, Kenneth and Tasci, Murat (2011) Diagnosing Labor Market Search Models: A Multiple-Shock Approach. Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchard, Olivier Jean and Diamond, Peter (1990) The cyclical behavior of the gross flows of U.S. workers. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1990 (2), 85143.Google Scholar
Chari, V.V., Kehoe, Patrick, and McGratten, Ellen R. (2007) Business cycle accounting. Econometrica 75 (3), 781836.Google Scholar
Cheremukhin, Anton A. and Restrepo-Echavarria, Paulina (2010) The Labor Wedge as a Matching Friction. Working paper #1004, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiano, Lawrence (2002) Solving dynamic equilibrium models by a method of undertermined coefficients. Computational Economics 20 (1–2), 2155.Google Scholar
Cole, Harold L. and Rogerson, Richard (1999) Can the Mortensen–Pissarides matching model match the business cycle facts? International Economic Review 40 (4), 933959.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costain, J.S. and Reiter, M. (2008) Business cycles, unemployment insurance and the calibration of the matching models. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32 (4), 11201155.Google Scholar
Darby, Michael R., Haltiwanger, John C., and Plant, Mark W. (1986) The Ins and Outs of Unemployment: The Ins Win. Working paper 1997, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Davis, Steven and Haltiwanger, John (1992) Gross job creation, gross job destruction, and employment reallocation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (3), 819863.Google Scholar
Davis, Steven, Haltiwanger, John, and Schuh, Scott (1996) Job Creation and Destruction. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Den Haan, W., Ramey, Garey, and Watson, Joel (2000) Job destruction and propagation of shocks. American Economic Review 90 (3), 482498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elsby, Michael, Michaels, Ryan, and Solon, Gary (2009) The ins and outs of cyclical unemployment. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1 (1), 84110.Google Scholar
Fallick, B. and Fleischman, C.A. (2004) Employer-to-Employer Flows in the U.S. Labor Market: The Complete Picture of Gross Worker Flows. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2004-34.Google Scholar
Fujita, Shigeru and Ramey, Gary (2009) The cyclicality of separation and job finding rates. International Economic Review 50 (2), 415430.Google Scholar
Hagedorn, M. and Manovskii, I. (2007) The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies revisited. American Economic Review 98 (5), 16921706.Google Scholar
Hall, Robert E. (2004) The Amplification of Unemployment Fluctuations through Self-Selection. NBER working paper 11186.Google Scholar
Hall, Robert E. (2005) Employment fluctuations with equilibrium wage stickiness. American Economic Review 95 (1), 5065.Google Scholar
Hornstein, A., Krusell, Per, and Violante, G.L. (2006) Frictional wage dispersion in search models: A quantitative assessment. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond working paper 06-07.Google Scholar
Hosios, Arthur (1990) On the efficiency of matching and related models of search and unemployment. Review of Economic Studies 57 (2), 279298.Google Scholar
Ingram, B.F., Kocherlakota, Narayana, and Savin, N. Eugene (1994) Explaining business cycles: A multiple-shock approach. Journal of Monetary Economics 34 (3), 415428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kennan, John (2010) Private information, wage bargaining and employment fluctuations. Review of Economic Studies 77 (2), 633664.Google Scholar
Krause, M.U. and Lubik, T.A. (2006) The cyclical upgrading of labor and on-the-job search. Labour Economics 13 (4), 459477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merz, Monika (1995) Search in the labor market and the real business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 36 (2), 269300.Google Scholar
Merz, Monika (1999) Heterogeneous job-matches and the cyclical behavior of labor turnover. Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1), 91124.Google Scholar
Mortensen, Dale and Nagypal, Eva (2007) More on unemployment and vacancy fluctuations. Review of Economic Dynamics 10 (3), 327347.Google Scholar
Mortensen, Dale and Pissarides, Christopher A. (1994) Job creation and job destruction in the theory of unemployment. Review of Economic Studies 61 (3), 397415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nagypal, Eva (2004) Worker Reallocation over the Business Cycle: The Importance of Job-to-Job Transitions. Northwestern University working paper.Google Scholar
Nagypal, Eva (2006) Amplification of productivity shocks: Why don't vacancies like to hire the unemployed? In Bunzel, H.et al. (eds.), Structural Models of Wage and Employment Dynamics, pp. 481506. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Pescatori, Andrea and Tasci, Murat (2011) Search Frictions and the Labor Wedge. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland working paper 11-11.Google Scholar
Petrongolo, Barbara and Pissarides, Christopher A. (2001) Looking into the black box: A survey of the matching function. Journal of Economic Literature 39 (2), 390431.Google Scholar
Pissarides, Christopher A (2000) Equilibrium Unemployment Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Pissarides, Christopher A (2009) The unemployment volatility puzzle: Is wage stickiness the answer? Econometrica 77 (5), 1339–69.Google Scholar
Ramey, Garey (2008) Exogenous vs. Endogenous Separation. UCSD working paper.Google Scholar
Sahin, Aysegul, Song, J., Topa, G., and Violante, G.L. (2011) Measuring Mismatch in the U.S. Labor Market. Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.Google Scholar
Shimer, Robert (2004) The consequences of rigid wages in search models. Journal of the European Economic Association (Papers and Proceedings) 2 469479.Google Scholar
Shimer, Robert (2005a) The cyclical behavior of unemployment and vacancies: Evidence and theory. American Economic Review 95 (1), 2549.Google Scholar
Shimer, Robert (2005b) The cyclicality of hires, separations, and job-to-job transitions. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 87 (4), 493-507.Google Scholar
Silva, J.I. and Toledo, M. (2009) Labor turnover costs and the cyclical behavior of vacancies and unemployment. Macroeconomic Dynamics 13 (1), 7696.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stock, James H. and Watson, Mark W. (2010) Monthly Estimates of GDP and GDI. Research Memorandum, Princeton University, September.Google Scholar
Tasci, Murat (2007) On-the-Job Search and Labor Market Reallocation. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland working paper 0725.Google Scholar
Tasci, Murat (2011) The Ins and Outs of Unemployment in the Long Run: A New Estimate for the Natural Rate? Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland working paper 10-17R.Google Scholar
Veracierto, Marcelo (2011) Worker flows and matching efficiency. Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 35, 147169.Google Scholar