Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-tf8b9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T19:49:00.290Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A CLASSICAL MODEL OF EDUCATION, GROWTH, AND DISTRIBUTION

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 November 2018

Amitava Krishna Dutt
Affiliation:
University of Notre Dame and FLACSO-Ecuador
Roberto Veneziani*
Affiliation:
Queen Mary University of London
*
Address correspondence to: Roberto Veneziani, School of Economics and Finance, Queen Mary University of London, Mile End Road, London E1 4NS, United Kingdom; e-mail: [email protected]

Abstract

We develop a classical macroeconomic model to examine the growth and distributional consequences of education. Contrary to the received wisdom, we show that human capital accumulation is not necessarily growth-inducing and inequality-reducing. Expansive education policies may foster growth and reduce earning inequalities between workers, but only by transferring income from workers to capitalists. Further, the overall effect of an increase in education depends on the actual characteristics of the educational system and on the nature of labor market relations. Although the primary aim of the paper is theoretical, we argue that the model identifies some causal mechanisms that can contribute to shed light on recent stylized facts on growth, distribution, and education for the USA.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2018

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Special thanks go to Peter Skott, Luca Zamparelli, and two anonymous referees for detailed and perceptive comments. We are grateful to Richard Arena, Philip Arestis, Deepankar Basu, Riccardo Bellofiore, Laura Carvalho, Meghnad Desai, Gerald Epstein, Giulio Fella, Peter Flaschel, John King, Gilberto Lima, Neri Salvadori, Rajiv Sethi, Engelbert Stockhammer, Daniele Tavani, Alessandro Vercelli, and audiences in London, Paris, Bristol, New York, Berlin, Kingston, and Washington for comments and suggestions. We also thank Kurt von Seekam for excellent research assistance. Roberto Veneziani worked on this project while visiting the University of Massachusetts, Amherst. Their hospitality and support are gratefully acknowledged. The usual disclaimer applies.

References

Acemoglu, Daron (2002a) Directed technical change. Review of Economic Studies 69, 781809. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-937X.00226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron (2002b) Technical change, inequality and the labor market. Journal of Economic Literature 40, 772. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.40.1.7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Aghion, Philippe and Violante, Gianluca (2001) Deunionization, technical change and inequality. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 55, 229264. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2231(01)00058-6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, Philippe and Howitt, Peter (1998) Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto and Glaeser, Edward (2004) Fighting Poverty in the US and Europe: A World of Difference. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allegretto, Sylvia A. (2011) The State of Working America’s Wealth. EPI briefing paper no. 292, March 23, 2011.Google Scholar
Alonso-Carrera, Jaime, Caballè, Jordi and Raurich, Xavier (in press) Intergenerational mobility in education and occupation. Macroeconomic Dynamics.Google Scholar
Autor, David, Katz, Lawrence and Krueger, Alan B. (1998) Computing inequality: Have computers changed the labor market? Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 11691213. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355398555874.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baran, Paul and Sweezy, Paul M. (1966) Monopoly Capital. New York and London: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Barbosa-Filho, Nelson and Taylor, Lance (2006) Distributive and demand cycles in the US economy—Astructuralist Goodwin model. Metroeconomica 57, 389411. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-999X.2006.00250.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barone, Guglielmo and Mocetti, Sauro (2016) Intergenerational Mobility in the Very Long Run: Florence 1427–2011. Bank of Italy WP 1060, April 2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Basu, Deepankar (2009) A simple test of the neoclassical view of production, technical change and distribution. Metroeconomica 61, 593621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bénabou, Roland and Tirole, Jean (2006) Belief in a just world and redistributive politics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121, 699746.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blau, Francine D. and Kahn, Lawrence M. (1996) International differences in male wage inequality: Institutions versus market forces. Journal of Political Economy 104, 791837. https://doi.org/10.1086/262043.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borghans, Lex and de Grip, Andries (eds.) (2000) The Overeducated Worker? The Economics of Skill Utilization. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Bowles, Sam and Gintis, Herbert (1975) The problem with human capital theory—A Marxian critique. American Economic Review 65(May), 7482.Google Scholar
Bowles, Sam and Gintis, Herbert (1976) Schooling in Capitalist America. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Bowles, Sam and Gintis, Herbert (2002) Schooling in capitalist America revisited. Sociology of Education 75, 118. https://doi.org/10.2307/3090251.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Card, David, Kramarz, Francis and Lemieux, Thomas (1999) Changes in the relative structure of wages and employment: A comparison of the United States, Canada, and France. Canadian Journal of Economics 32, 843877. https://doi.org/10.2307/136408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Card, David and Lemieux, Thomas (1996) Wage dispersion, returns to skills, and black-white wage differentials. Journal of Econometrics 74, 319361. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(95)01757-7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carvalho, Laura and Rezai, Armon (2016) Personal income inequality and aggregate demand. Cambridge Journal of Economics 40, 491505. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/beu085.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duménil, Gérard and Lévy, Dominique (1999) Being Keynesian in the short term and classical in the long term. Manchester School 67, 684716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duménil, Gérard and Lévy, Dominique (2003) Technology and distribution: Historical trajectories à la Marx. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 52, 201233. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2681(03)00022-2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutt, Amitava K. (2016) Accumulation, distribution and inflation in a Marxian-Post Keynesian model with a rentier class. Review of Radical Political Economics 21, 1826. https://doi.org/10.1177/048661348902100305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutt, Amitava K. (1990) Growth, Distribution and Uneven Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dutt, Amitava K. (2005) Globalization, South-North migration and uneven development. In: Gangopadhyay, Partha and Chatterji, Manas (eds.), Economics of Globalization, pp. 115129. Aldershot: Ashgate.Google Scholar
Dutt, Amitava K. (2010) Keynesian growth theory in the 21st century. In: Arestis, Philip and Sawyer, Malcolm (eds.), Twenty-First Century Keynesian Economics, pp. 3980. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutt, Amitava K. (2011) The role of aggregate demand in classical-Marxian models of economic growth. Cambridge Journal of Economics 35, 357382. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/beq025.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutt, Amitava K. and Veneziani, Roberto (2011) Education, growth and distribution: Classical-Marxian economic thought and a simple model. Cahiers d’économiepolitique 61, 157185.Google Scholar
Dutt, Amitava K. and Veneziani, Roberto (in press) Education and human capitalists in a classical-Marxian model of growth and distribution. Cambridge Journal of Economics.Google Scholar
Egger, Hartmut and Grossmann, Volker (2004) Non Cognitive Abilities and Within-Group Wage Inequality. IZA discussion paper no. 1024.Google Scholar
Flaschel, Peter (2009) Topics in Classical Micro- and Macro-economics. New York and Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
Foley, Duncan K. (1986) Understanding Capital. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Foley, Duncan K. and Michl, Thomas R. (1999) Growth and Distribution. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Franzini, Maurizio and Raitano, Michele (2014) Wage gaps and human capital: Looking for an explanation. Mimeo, University of Rome I.Google Scholar
Freeman, Richard B. and Katz, Lawrence F. (eds.) (1996) Differences and Changes in Wage Structures. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Galor, Oded and Moav, Omer (2006) Das Human-Kapital: A theory of the demise of the class structure. Review of Economic Studies 73, 85117. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-937X.2006.00370.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, Oded and Tsiddon, Daniel (1997) The distribution of capital and economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth 2, 93124https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1009785714248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, Oded and Zeira, Joseph (1993) Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies 60, 3552. https://doi.org/10.2307/2297811.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garcìa-Peñalosa, Cecilia and Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2015) Income inequality, mobility, and the accumulation of capital. Macroeconomic Dynamics 19, 13321357. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1365100513000850.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giddens, Anthony (1973) The Class Structure of the AdvancedSocieties. London: Hutchison and Co.Google Scholar
Glyn, Andrew, Hughes, Alan, Lipietz, Alain and Singh, Ajit (1990) The rise and fall of the Golden Age. In: Marglin, Steven A. and Schor, Juliet (eds.), The Golden Age of Capitalism. Reinterpreting the Postwar Experience, pp. 39125. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Goodwin, Richard M. (1967) A growth cycle. In: Feinstein, Charles H. (ed.), Socialism, Capitalism and Economic Growth, pp. 5458. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Greenstone, Michael, Looney, Adam, Patashnik, Jeremy and Yu, Muxin (2013) Thirteen Economic Facts about Social Mobility and the Role of Education. Brookings Institution, June 26, 2013. https://www.brookings.edu/research/thirteen-economic-facts-about-social-mobility-and-the-role-of-education/.Google Scholar
Harris, Donald J. (1978) Capital Accumulation and Distribution. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Hirsch, Barry T. and Macpherson, David A. (2016) Union membership and coverage database from the current population survey: Note. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 56, 349354CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaumotte, Florence and Buitron, Carolina Osorio (2015) Inequality and Labor Market Institutions. IMF staff discussion note, SDN/15/14. https://doi.org/10.1177/001979390305600208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, Nicholas (1961) Capital accumulation and economic growth. In: Lutz, Friedrich A. and Hague, Douglas C. (eds.), The Theory of Capital, pp. 177222. New York: St. Martin’s Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, Nicholas (1966) Marginal productivity and the macroeconomic theories of distribution. Review of Economic Studies 33, 309319. https://doi.org/10.2307/2974428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katz, Lawrence F. and Murphy, Kevin M. (1992) Changes in relative wages, 1963–87: Supply and demand factors. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 3578. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Dirk, Mitman, Kurt and Perri, Fabrizio (2016) Macroeconomics and household heterogeneity. In: Taylor, John B. and Uhlig, Harald (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, pp. 843921. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Lemieux, Thomas (2006) Increasing residual wage inequality: Composition effects, noisy data, or rising demand for skill? American Economic Review 96, 461498. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.96.3.461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics 22, 342. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marglin, Stephen A. (1984) Growth, Distribution and Prices. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl (1867) Capital, Vol. 1. Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1948.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl and Engels, Friedrich (19752005) Collected Works. Moscow: Progress Publishers, London: Lawrence and Wishart, and New York: International Publishers.Google Scholar
McCulloch, John R. (1825) The Principles of Political Economy, 5th ed. Edinburgh: Adam and Charles Black, 1864.Google Scholar
Mill, John S. (1848) Principles of political economy with some of their applications to social philosophy. In: Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Vol. 2. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1965.Google Scholar
Nakajima, Tetsuya, and Nakamura, Hideki (2012) How do elementary and higher education affect human capital accumulation and inequality? A note. Macroeconomic Dynamics 16, 151158. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1365100511000770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norton, Michael I. and Ariely, Dan (2011) Building a better America—One wealth quintile at a time. Perspectives on Psychological Science 6, 912. https://doi.org/10.1177/1745691610393524.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Nussbaum, Martha C. (2010) Not for Profit! Why Democracy Needs the Humanities. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
O’Brien, Denis P. (1975) The Classical Economists. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
O’Donnell, Margaret G. (1985) The Educational Thought of the Classical Political Economists. Lanham, New York and London: University Press of America.Google Scholar
Onaran, Ozlem, Stockhammer, Engelbert and Grafl, Lucas (2011) Financialisation, income distribution and aggregate demand in the USA. Cambridge Journal of Economics 35, 637661. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/beq045.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pasinetti, Luigi L. (1960) A mathematical formulation of the Ricardian system. Review of Economic Studies 27, 7898. https://doi.org/10.2307/2296129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petith, Howard (2008) Land, technical progress and the falling rate of profit. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 66, 687702. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2006.08.004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piketty, Thomas (2014) Capital in the 21st Century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Romer, Paul M. (1990) Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98, S71S102. https://doi.org/10.1086/261725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skott, Peter and Slonimczyk, Fabian (2012) Employment and distribution effects of the minimum wage. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 84, 245264. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2012.03.005.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1776) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations, Vol. 1. In: Campbell, Roy H. and Skinner, Andrew S. (eds.), The Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, Vol. 2. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Stokey, Nancy J. (1991) Human capital, product quality and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 587616. https://doi.org/10.2307/2937948.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavani, Daniele (2013) Bargaining over productivity and wages when technical change is induced: Implications for growth, distribution, and employment. Journal of Economics 109, 207244. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-012-0287-3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavani, Daniele and Vasudevan, Ramaa (2014) Capitalists, workers, and managers: Wage inequality and effective demand. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 30, 120131. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.strueco.2014.05.001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Unger, Roberto M. (2007) Free trade re-imagined. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Uzawa, Hirofumi (1965) Optimum technical change in an aggregative model of growth. International Economic Review 6, 1831. https://doi.org/10.2307/2525621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wood, Adrian (1994) North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Dutt and Veneziani supplementary material

Dutt and Veneziani supplementary material 1

Download Dutt and Veneziani supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 144.2 KB