Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-94fs2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-03T04:10:03.833Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

TAXATION AND PUBLIC HEALTH INVESTMENT: POLICY CHOICES AND TRADEOFFS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 June 2019

Manoj Atolia
Affiliation:
Florida State University
Chris Papageorgiou
Affiliation:
International Monetary Fund
Stephen J. Turnovsky*
Affiliation:
University of Washington
*
Address correspondence to: Stephen Turnovsky, Department of Economics, University of Washington, Box 353330, Seattle, WA 98195, USA, e-mail: [email protected]. Phone: +1(206) 685-8028. Fax: +1(206) 685 7477.

Abstract

In recent years, there has been an explosive increase in the demand for health products and services by people all around the globe, and particularly in advanced economies. Aiming to enhance longevity and also to improve quality of life, individual consumption of pharmaceutical products and services has risen exponentially since the early 1980s. This paper develops a model in which agents invest part of their resources in medical products and time in physical exercise to enhance their health status. In the first part of the paper, we study the steady state and transitional dynamics of the model with special emphasis on the effects of health decisions on aggregate outcomes. In the second part, we explore how public health policies may alter private economic decisions that promote healthier and more productive lives.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2019

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We thank David Canning, Shankha Chakraborty, Oksana Leukhina, Fidel Perez-Sebastian, Kenichi Ueda, and Marios Zachariadis, two referees, and an associate editor for valuable comments and suggestions. We also thank Suhaib Kebhaj for excellent research assistance. The views expressed in this study are the sole responsibility of the authors and should not be attributed to the International Monetary Fund, its Executive Board, or its management.

References

REFERENCES

Agénor, P.-R. (2008) Health and infrastructure in a model of endogenous growth. Journal of Macroeconomics 30, 14071422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Agénor, P.-R. (2010) A theory of infrastructure-led development. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34, 932950.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Agénor, P.-R. (2013) Public Capital, Growth and Welfare: Analytical Foundations for Public Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Aísa, R. and Pueyo, F. (2004a) Endogenous longevity, health and economic growth: A slow growth for a longer life? Economics Bulletin 9, 110.Google Scholar
Aísa, R. and Pueyo, F. (2004b) Government Health Spending and Growth in a Model of Endogenous longevity. Economic Analysis Department, University of Zaragoza.Google Scholar
Allen, J. and Chakraborty, S. (2018) Aspirations, health and the cost of inequality. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 86, 144164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auster, R. D., Leveson, I. and Sarachek, D. (1969) The production of health: An exploratory study. Journal of Human Resources 4, 411436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhattacharya, J. and Chakraborty, S. (2016) Contraception and the demographic transition. Economic Journal 127, 22632301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birchenall, J. and Soares, R. R. (2009) Altruism, fertility, and the value of children: Health policy evaluation and intergenerational welfare. Journal of Public Economics 93, 280295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchard, O. J. (1985) Models with endogenous rate of time preference debt, deficits and finite horizon. Journal of Political Economy 93, 223247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloom, D. and Canning, D. (2005) Population Health and Economic Growth. Commission on Growth and Development, Washington, DC: World Bank, Working Paper No. 24.Google Scholar
Bloom, D., Canning, D. and Sevilla, J. (2004) The effect of health on economic growth: A production function approach. World Development 32, 113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bom, P. D. and Ligthart, J. E. (2014) What have we learned from three decades of research on the productivity of public capital? Journal of Economic Surveys 28, 889916.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucekkine, R., de la Croix, D. and Licandro, O. (2002) Vintage human capital, demographic trends, and endogenous growth. Journal of Economic Theory 104, 340375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bureau of Labor Statistics (2016) Industry-Occupation Matrix Data, by Industry, Table 1.9, 2014–24. http://www.bls.gov/emp/ep_table_109.htm.Google Scholar
Center for Disease Control and Prevention (2006) Trends in strength training-United States, 1998–2004. MMWR 55, 769-772. http://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/preview/mmwrhtml/mm5528a1.htm.Google Scholar
Chakraborty, S. (2004) Endogenous lifetime and economic growth. Journal of Economic Theory 116, 119137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chakraborty, S., Papageorgiou, C. and Sebastian, F. P. (2013) Health Cycles and Health Transitions, MPRA Paper No. 50588, University Library of Munich, Germany.Google Scholar
Chamley, C. (1986) Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica 54, 607622.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de la Croix, D. and Licandro, O. (1999) Life expectancy and economic growth. Economics Letters 65, 255263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cutler, D. M. and Richardson, E. (1997) Measuring the health of the US population. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Microeconomics 28, 217282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deaton, A. (1981) Optimal taxes and the structure of preferences. Econometrica 49, 12451260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deaton, A. (2003) Health, inequality, and economic development. Journal of Economic Literature 41, 113158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ehrlich, I. and Chuma, H. (1990) A model of the demand for longevity and the value of life extension. Journal of Political Economy 98, 761782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Faruqee, H. (2003) Debt, deficits, and age-specific mortality. Review of Economic Dynamics 6, 300-312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finkelstein, A., Luttmer, E. and Notowidigdo, M. J. (2013) What good is wealth without health? The effect of health on the marginal utility of consumption. Journal of the European Economic Association 11, 221258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finlay, J. (2006) Endogenous Longevity and Economic Growth. School of Economics Faculty, July 24, 2006.Google Scholar
Grossman, M. (1972) On the concept of health capital and the demand for health. Journal of Political Economy 80, 223255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guvenen, F. (2006) Reconciling conflicting evidence on the elasticity of intertemporal substitution: A macroeconomic perspective. Journal of Monetary Economics 53, 14511472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, R. E. and Jones, C. I. (2007) The value of life and the rise in health spending. Quarterly Journal of Economics 122, 3972.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halliday, T., He, H., Ning, L. and Zhang, H. (2019) Health investment over the life-cycle. Macroeconomic Dynamics 23, 178215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haskell, W. L., Lee, I.-M., Pate, R. P., Powell, K. E., Blair, S.N., Franklin, B.A., Macera, C. A., Heath, G. W., Thompson, P. D. and Bauman, A. (2007) Physical activity and public health: Updated recommendation for adults from the American College of Sports Medicine and the American Heart Association. Circulation 116, 14231434.Google ScholarPubMed
Himmelstein, D. U. and Woolhandler, S. (2016) The current and projected taxpayer shares of U.S. health costs. American Journal of Public Health 106, 449452.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hosoya, K. (2009) Tax financed government health expenditure and growth with capital deepening externality. Economics Bulletin 5, 110.Google Scholar
Hugonnier, J., St-Amour, P. and Pelgrin, F. (2013) Health and (other asset holdings). Review of Economic Studies 80, 663710.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
IMF (2015) Estimating Public, Private, and PPP Capital Stocks, Annex to Making Public Investment More Efficient.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judd, K. L. (1985) Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics 28, 5981.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jung, J. and Tran, C. (2016) Market inefficiency, insurance mandate and welfare: U.S. health care reform 2010. Review of Economic Dynamics 20, 132159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keane, M. and Rogerson, R. (2012) Micro and macro labor supply elasticities: A reassessment of conventional wisdom. Journal of Economic Literature 50, 464476.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelly, M. (2017). Health capital accumulation, health insurance, and aggregate outcomes: A neoclassical approach. Journal of Macroeconomics 52, 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lorentzen, P., McMillan, J. and Wacziarg, R. (2006) Death and Development. 2006 Meeting Papers No. 61, Society for Economic Dynamics.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDaniel, C. (2007) Average Tax Rates on Consumption, Investment, Labor and Capital in the OECD 1953–2003. Mimeo, Arizona State University.Google Scholar
McLachlan, G. and Maynard, A. (eds.) (1982) The Public/Private Mix for Health. London: The Nuffield Provincial Hospitals Trust.Google Scholar
Mendoza, E. G., Razin, A. and Tesar, L. L. (1994) Effective tax rates in macroeconomics: Cross-country estimates of tax rates on factor incomes and consumption. Journal of Monetary Economics 34, 297323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Navarro, V. (1985) The public/private mix in the funding and delivery of health services: An international survey. American Journal of Public Health 75, 13181320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2015) Health at Glance 2015, OECD Indicators. Paris: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
Pelgrin, F. and St-Amour, P. (2016) Life cycle responses to health insurance status. Journal of Health Economics 49, 7996.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Physical Activity Council (2013) Participation Report.Google Scholar
Preston, S. H. (1975) The changing relation between mortality and level of economic development. Population Studies 29, 231248.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rampell, C. (2012) A jobs boom built on sweat in an age of belt-tightening. The New York Times [New York] 30 June 2012. http://www.nytimes.com/2012/07/01/business/for-personal-trainers-a-boom-fueled-by-a-belt-tightening-age.html?pagewanted=all&_r=0.Google Scholar
Soares, R. R. (2005) Mortality reductions, educational attainment, and fertility choice. American Economic Review 95, 580601.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Strauss, J. and Thomas, D. (1998) Health, nutrition, and economic development. Journal of Economic Literature 36, 766817.Google Scholar
Suen, R. M. H. (2017) Technological Advance and the Growth in Health Care Spending. University of Connecticut, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Turnovsky, S. J. (2000) Fiscal policy, elastic labor supply, and endogenous growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 45, 185210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (1996) Physical Activity and Health: A Report of the Surgeon General. Atlanta, GA: CDC. http://www.cdc.gov/nccdphp/sgr/sgr.htm.Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (2008) Physical Activity Guidelines for Americans. Washington, DC: DHHS. http://www.health.gov/paguidelines/guidelines/default.aspx.Google Scholar
Weil, D. N. (2007) Accounting for the effect of health on economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 122, 12651306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Health Organization (WHO) (2017) Global Health Expenditure Database. http://www.who.int/health-accounts/ghed/en/.Google Scholar