Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gxg78 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T06:15:33.030Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

PRICING POLICIES AND INFLATION DYNAMICS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 June 2011

Luis Felipe Cespedes
Affiliation:
Universidade Adolfo Ibáñez
Michael Kumhof*
Affiliation:
International Monetary Fund
Eric Parrado
Affiliation:
Universidad Adolfo Ibáñez
*
Address correspondence to: Michael Kumhof, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC 20431, USA; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

The paper proposes a New Keynesian monetary model where firms' pricing policies feature a forward-looking optimal choice of the rate of price growth. The model can be thought of as a reduced form model of rational inattention that has only one additional state variable relative to the Calvo model [Journal of Monetary Economics 12 (1983), 383–398]. Like the model of backward-looking automatic indexation to past aggregate inflation, it generates a gradual and persistent reaction of the inflation rate, and output losses, following highly persistent monetary shocks. But unlike that model, its price setters behave very similarly to Calvo price setters when shocks are transitory.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Amato, Jeffrey D. and Laubach, Thomas (1999) Monetary Policy in an Estimated Optimization-Based Model with Sticky Wages and Sticky Prices. Research Working paper 99-09, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.Google Scholar
Ascari, Guido (2004) Staggered prices and trend inflation: Some nuisances. Review of Economic Dynamics 7, 642667.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, Larry (1994) Credible disinflation with staggered price-setting. American Economic Review 84 (1), 282289.Google Scholar
Benati, Luca (2008) Investigating inflation persistence across monetary regimes. Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 (3), 1005–60.Google Scholar
Bils, Mark and Klenow, Peter (2004) Some evidence on the importance of sticky prices. Journal of Political Economy 112 (5), 947985.Google Scholar
Boldrin, Michele, Christiano, Lawrence J., and Fisher, Jonas (2001) Habit persistence, asset returns and the business cycle. American Economic Review 91 (1), 149166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burstein, Ariel (2006) Inflation and output dynamics with state dependent pricing decisions. Journal of Monetary Economics 53 (7), 12351257.Google Scholar
Calvo, Guillermo A. (1983) Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12, 383398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvo, Guillermo A., Celasun, Oya, and Kumhof, Michael (2002) A theory of rational inflationary inertia. In Aghion, Philippe, Frydman, Roman, Stiglitz, Joseph, and Woodford, Michael (eds.), Knowledge, Information and Expectations in Modern Macroeconomics: In Honor of Edmund S. Phelps, pp. 87117. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Calvo, Guillermo A., Celasun, Oya, and Kumhof, Michael (2007) Inflation inertia and credible disinflation: The open economy case. Journal of International Economics 73 (1), 4868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, Yongsung and Kim, Sun-Bin (2005) On the aggregate labor supply. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 91 (1), 2137.Google Scholar
Christiano, Lawrence J., Eichenbaum, Martin, and Evans, Charles (1996) The effects of monetary policy shocks: Evidence from the flow of funds. Review of Economics and Statistics 78 (1), 1634.Google Scholar
Christiano, Lawrence J., Eichenbaum, Martin, and Evans, Charles (1998) Monetary Policy Shocks: What Have We Learned and To What End? Working paper 6400, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Christiano, Lawrence J., Eichenbaum, Martin, and Evans, Charles (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 113 (1), 145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarida, Richard, Galí, Jordi, and Gertler, Mark (1999) The science of monetary policy: A New Keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature 37, 16611707.Google Scholar
Dedola, Luca and Neri, Stefano (2007) What does a technology shock do? A VAR analysis with model-based sign restrictions. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 512549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erceg, Christopher J. and Levin, Andrew T. (2003) Imperfect credibility and inflation persistence. Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (4), 915944.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
European Central Bank (ECB) (2005) Inflation Persistence and Price Setting Behaviour in the Euro Area. European Central Bank, Inflation Persistence Network.Google Scholar
Fischer, Stanley (1977) Long-term contracts, rational expectations, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 85 (1), 191205.Google Scholar
Fuhrer, Jeffrey and Moore, George (1995) Inflation persistence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 127159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galí, Jordi (2003) New perspectives on monetary policy, inflation and the business cycle. In Dewatripont, Matthias, Hansen, Lars, and Turnovsky, Stephen (eds.), Advances in Economic Theory, Vol. III, pp. 151197. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Galí, Jordi and Gertler, Mark (1999) Inflation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics 44 (2), 195222.Google Scholar
Golosov, Mikhail and Lucas, Robert E. (2003) Menu Costs and Phillips Curves. Working paper 10187, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Gordon, Robert J. (1982) Why stopping inflation may be costly: Evidence from fourteen historical episodes. In Hall, Robert E. (ed.), Inflation: Causes and Consequences, pp. 1140. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Gordon, Robert J. (1997) The time-varying NAIRU and its implications for economic policy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (1), 1132.Google Scholar
Juillard, Michel, Kamenik, Ondra, Kumhof, Michael, and Laxton, Douglas (2007) Optimal price setting and inflation inertia in a rational expectations model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32 (8), 25842621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klenow, Peter and Kryvtsov, Oleg (2005) State-Dependent or Time-Dependent Pricing: Does It Matter for Recent U.S. Inflation? Working paper 11043, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Lane, Philip (2001) The new open economy macroeconomics: A survey. Journal of International Economics 54 (2), 235266.Google Scholar
Leeper, Eric M., Sims, Chris, and Zha, Tao (1996) What does monetary policy do? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. Jr. (1987) Models of Business Cycles. Oxford/New York: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Mankiw, Gregory N. (2001) The inexorable and mysterious tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. Economic Journal 111, 4561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mankiw, Gregory and Reis, Ricardo (2002) Sticky information versus sticky prices: A proposal to replace the New Keynesian Phillips curve. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4), 12951328.Google Scholar
Pencavel, John (1986) Labor supply of men. In Ashenfelter, Orley and Layard, Richard (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 1. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Reis, Ricardo (2006) Inattentive producers. Review of Economic Studies 73, 793821.Google Scholar
Rotemberg, Julio (1982) Sticky prices in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 90, 11871211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotemberg, Julio and Woodford, Michael (1997) An optimization-based econometric framework for the evaluation of monetary policy. In Bernanke, Ben and Rotemberg, Julio (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, pp. 297346. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Rudd, Jeremy and Whelan, Karl (2006) Can rational expectations sticky-price models explain inflation dynamics? American Economic Review 96 (1), 303320.Google Scholar
Rudd, Jeremy and Whelan, Karl (2007) Modelling inflation dynamics: A critical survey of recent research. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39, 155–70.Google Scholar
Rudebusch, Glenn (2002) Term structure evidence on interest rate smoothing and monetary policy inertia. Journal of Monetary Economics 49, 11611187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rudebusch, Glenn (2006) Monetary policy inertia: Fact or fiction? International Journal of Central Banking 2 (4), 85135.Google Scholar
Rudebusch, Glenn and Wu, Tao (2007) Accounting for a shift in term structure behavior with no-arbitrage and macro-finance models. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39 (2–3), 395422.Google Scholar
Smets, Frank and Wouters, Rafael (2003) An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro area. Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (5), 11231175.Google Scholar
Taylor, John B. (1980) Aggregate dynamics and staggered contracts. Journal of Political Economy 88, 124.Google Scholar
Taylor, John B. (1993). Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie–Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39, 195214.Google Scholar
Taylor, John B. (1998) Staggered Price and Wage Setting in Macroeconomics. Working paper 6754, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Woodford, Michael (2003) Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Yun, Tak (1996) Nominal price rigidity, money supply endogeneity, and business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 37, 345370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yun, Tak (2005) Optimal monetary policy with relative price distortions. American Economic Review 95 (1), 89109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar