Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T13:11:12.668Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

OPTIMAL TAXATION AND SOCIAL NETWORKS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 June 2013

Marcelo Arbex*
Affiliation:
University of Windsor
Dennis O'Dea
Affiliation:
University of Washington
*
Address correspondence to: Marcelo Arbex, Department of Economics, University of Windsor, 401 Sunset Avenue, Windsor, Ontario N9B 3P4, Canada; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

We study optimal taxation when jobs are found through a social network. The network determines employment, which workers may influence by engaging in social activities. The network parameters play an important role in determining the economy's employment level and the optimal income tax. The optimal labor income tax depends on both the traditional intensive margin of labor supply and a new extensive margin that depends on the structure of the social network. Social activities that promote social connections are instrumental to acquiring job information; taxation thus discourages both social activities and labor supply, reducing employment. Labor taxes vary positively with labor supply and negatively with employment. When networking is absent, taxes are higher and the economy's employment rate is lower. The optimal capital tax rate is zero, independent of labor market frictions. Social networking reduces job search frictions and is welfare-enhancing.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2013 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Addison, John T. and Portugal, Pedro (2002) Job search methods and outcomes. Oxford Economic Papers 54 (3), 505533.Google Scholar
Aiello, William, Chung, Fan, and Lu, Linyuan (2000) A random graph model for massive graphs. Proceedings of the Thirty-Second Annual ACM Symposium on Theory of Computing, Portland, OR, pp. 171180. New York: Association for Computing Machinery.Google Scholar
Andolfatto, D. (1996) Business cycles and labor-market search. American Economic Review 86 (1), 112132.Google Scholar
Barro, R. (1979) On the determination of the public debt. Journal of Political Economy 87 (5), 940971.Google Scholar
Basu, P. and Renström, T. (2007) Optimal dynamic labor taxation. Macroeconomic Dynamics 11 (5), 567588.Google Scholar
Bramoullé, Y. and Saint-Paul, G. (2010) Social networks and labor market transitions. Labour Economics 17 (1), 188195.Google Scholar
Calvó-Armengol, Antoni and Jackson, Matthew (2004) The effects of social networks on employment and inequality. American Economics Review 94 (3), 426454.Google Scholar
Calvó-Armengol, Antoni and Zenou, Yves (2005) Job matching, social network and word-of-mouth communication. Journal of Urban Economics 57 (3), 500522.Google Scholar
Carey, D. and Tchilingurian, H. (2000) Average Effective Tax Rates on Capital, Labor and Consumption. Working paper 258, OECD.Google Scholar
Chamley, Christophe (1986) Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica 54 (3), 607622.Google Scholar
Chari, V.V., Christiano, L., and Kehoe, P. (1991) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy: Some recent results. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 23, 519539.Google Scholar
Chari, V.V. and Kehoe, P. (1999) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy. In Taylor, J.B. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 1C, pp. 16711745. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Corcoran, Mary, Datcher, Linda, and Duncan, Greg (1980) Information and influence networks in labor markets. In Duncan, Greg and Morgan, James (eds.), Five Thousand American Families: Patterns of Economic Progress, vol. 7, 137. Ann Arbor, MI: Institute for Social Research.Google Scholar
Domeij, D. (2005) Optimal capital taxation and labor market search. Review of Economic Dynamics 8, 623650.Google Scholar
Ebel, H., Mielsch, L. I., and Bornholdt, S. (2002) Scale-free topology of e-mail networks. Physical Review E 66, 035103.Google Scholar
Faia, E. (2008) Optimal monetary policy rules with labor market frictions. Journal of Economic Dynamic and Control 32, 16001621.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark (1995) Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers, 2nd ed.Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Gregg, P. and Wadsworth, J. (1996) It Takes Two: Employment Polarisation in the OECD. Technical report, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE, September.Google Scholar
Holzer, Harry (1987) Hiring Procedures in the Firm: Their Economic Determinants and Outcomes. NBER working paper 2185.Google Scholar
Holzer, Harry J. (1988) Search method use by unemployed youth. Journal of Labor Economics 6 (1), 120.Google Scholar
Ioannides, Yannis and Loury, Linda (2004) Job information networks, neighborhood effects, and inequality. Journal of Economic Literature 43, 10561093.Google Scholar
Jackson, Matthew (2008) Social and Economic Networks. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Jones, Larry E., Manuelli, Rodolfo E., and Rossi, Peter E. (1997) On the optimal taxation of capital income. Journal of Economic Theory 73 (1), 93117.Google Scholar
Judd, Kenneth L. (1985) Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics 28 (1), 5983.Google Scholar
Krauth, B. (2004) A dynamic model of job networking and social influences on employment. Journal of Economic Dynamic and Control 28, 11851204.Google Scholar
Kyndland, F. and Prescott, E. (1980) A competitive theory of fluctuations and the feasibility of stabilization policy. In Fischer, Stanley (ed.), Rational Expectations and Economic Policy, pp. 169198. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Lucas, R. and Stokey, N. (1983) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy in an economy without capital. Journal of Monetary Economics 12, 5593.Google Scholar
Mardsen, Peter V. (2001) Interpersonal ties, social capital, and employer staffing practices. In Lin, Nan, Cook, Karen, and Burt, Ronald S. (eds.), Social Capital: Theory and Research, pp. 105125. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Merz, M. (1995) Search in the labor market and the real business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 36, 269300.Google Scholar
Montgomery, James D. (1991) Social networks and labor-market outcomes: Toward an economic analysis. American Economic Review 81 (5), 14081418.Google Scholar
Newman, M.E., Forrest, S., and Balthrop, J. (2002) Email networks and the spread of computer viruses. Physical Review E 66 (3), 035101.Google Scholar
Reinhorn, Leslie J. (2009) Dynamic optimal taxation with human capital. B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 9 (1) (Topics), Article 38.Google Scholar
Scott, A. (2007) Optimal taxation and OECD labor taxes. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 925944.Google Scholar
Shi, S. and Wen, Q. (1999) Labor market search and the dynamic effects of taxes and subsidies. Journal of Monetary Economics 43, 457495.Google Scholar
Topa, Giorgio (2001) Social interactions, local spillovers and unemployment. Review of Economic Studies 68 (2), 261295.Google Scholar
Vega-Redondo, Fernando (2007) Complex Social Networks, Econometric Society Monographs 44. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Watts, D.J. (1999a) Networks, dynamics, and the small-world phenomenon. American Journal of Sociology 105 (2), 493527.Google Scholar
Watts, D.J. (1999b) The Dynamics of Networks between Order and Randomness, Princeton Studies in Complexity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhu, X. (1992) Optimal fiscal policy in a stochastic growth model. Journal of Economic Theory 58, 250589.Google Scholar