Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T15:15:34.083Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A NOTE ON THE VOLATILITY OF THE TRADEABLE AND NONTRADEABLE SECTORS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 March 2012

Laura Povoledo*
Affiliation:
University of the West of England
*
Address correspondence to: Laura Povoledo, Coldharbour Lane, Bristol BS16 1QY, UK; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

This note evaluates whether a New Open Economy model can reproduce qualitatively the observed fluctuations of the tradeable and nontradeable sectors of the U.S. economy. The answer is positive: both in the model and in the data, the standard deviations of tradeable inflation, output, and employment are significantly higher than the standard deviations of the corresponding nontradeable sector variables. The key role in generating this result is played by the greater responsiveness of tradeable sector variables to monetary shocks.

Type
Notes
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Barsky, Robert B., House, Christopher L., and Kimball, Miles S. (2007) Sticky-price models and durable goods. American Economic Review 97 (3), 984998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benigno, Gianluca and Thoenissen, Christoph (2003) Equilibrium exchange rates and UK supply side performance. Economic Journal 113, 103124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benigno, Pierpaolo (2009) Price stability with imperfect financial integration. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 41, 121149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergin, Paul R. (2003) Putting the “New Open Economy Macroeconomics” to a test. Journal of International Economics 60, 334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Betts, Caroline and Devereux, Michael B. (2000) Exchange rate dynamics in a model of pricing to market. Journal of International Economics 50, 215244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burnside, Craig, Eichenbaum, Martin, and Rebelo, Sergio (1993) Labor hoarding and the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy 101 (2), 245273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvo, Guillermo A. (1993) Staggered prices in a utility-maximising framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12 (3), 383398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campa, José Manuel and Goldberg, Linda S. (2005) Exchange rate pass-through into import prices. Review of Economics and Statistics 87 (4), 679690.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chari, V. V., Kehoe, Patrick J., and McGrattan, Ellen R. (2002) Can sticky price models generate volatile and persistent real exchange rates? Review of Economic Studies 69 (3), 533563.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corsetti, Giancarlo and Pesenti, Paolo (2005) International dimensions of optimal monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 52 (2), 281305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Faruqee, Hamid, Laxton, Douglas, Muir, Dirk, and Pesenti, Paolo (2005) Smooth Landing or Crash? Model-Based Scenarios of Global Current Account Rebalancing. NBER Working Paper 11583, National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghironi, Fabio (2000) Towards New Open Economy Macroeconometrics. Staff Report 100, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Justiniano, Alejandro and Preston, Bruce (2010a) Can structural small open-economy models account for the influence of foreign disturbances? Journal of International Economics 81 (1), 6174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Justiniano, Alejandro and Preston, Bruce (2010b) Monetary policy and uncertainty in an empirical small open-economy model. Journal of Applied Econometrics 25 (1), 93128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lubik, Thomas and Schorfheide, Frank (2006) A Bayesian look at New Open Economy macroeconomics. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2005, vol. 20, pp. 313382. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lubik, Thomas and Schorfheide, Frank (2007) Do central banks respond to exchange rate movements? A structural investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (4), 10691087.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Newey, Whitney K. and West, Kenneth D. (1987) A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55 (3), 703708.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Obstfeld, Maurice and Rogoff, Kenneth (1995) Exchange rate dynamics redux. Journal of Political Economy 103, 624660.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Obstfeld, Maurice and Rogoff, Kenneth S. (2005) Global current account imbalances and exchange rate adjustments. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 36 (1), 67146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Povoledo, Laura (2010) The Volatility of the Tradeable and Nontradeable Sectors: Theory and Evidence. MPRA Paper 14852, University Library of Munich, Germany.Google Scholar
Rabanal, Pau and Tuesta, Vicente (2010) Euro-dollar real exchange rate dynamics in an estimated two-country model: An assessment. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34 (4), 780797.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogerson, Richard (1988) Recursive competitive equilibrium in multi-sector economies. International Economic Review 29 (3), 419430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uhlig, Harald (1999) A Toolkit for Analyzing Nonlinear Dynamic Stochastic Models Easily. In Marimon, Ramon and Scott, Andrew (eds.), Computational Methods for the Study of Dynamic Economies, pp. 3061. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar