Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rcrh6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T17:32:24.709Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

MISALLOCATION OF RESOURCES, TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY, AND THE CLEANSING HYPOTHESIS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 October 2020

George Vachadze*
Affiliation:
City University of New York
*
Address correspondence to: George Vachadze, Department of Economics, College of Staten Island and Graduate Center, City University of New York, Staten Island, NY 10314, USA. e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

Imperfections in the credit market can hamper the flow of factors from less productive to more productive firms and result in a lower aggregate total factor productivity (TFP). Depth of such misallocation will depend on per capita income, the level of imperfections in the credit market, and the distribution of entrepreneurial productivity. Under some parameter configurations, we find that per capita income and TFP may affect each other so that an economic boom may cause higher resource misallocation, lower TFP, and economic recession. At the same time, an economic recession may have a “cleansing effect” on TFP leading to a lower resource misallocation, higher TFP, and economic boom. In other words, economic success may breed the failure and the failure can become a precondition for success so that the boom-bust cycles in resource misallocation, TFP, and per capita income may become endogenous.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© 2020 Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I benefited from comments and suggestions made by Thomas Hauner, Richard Nugent, and Bryan Weber. This work was supported by the Provost’s Research Scholarship Award and City University of New York PSC-CUNY Research Award TRADA-46-127.

References

REFERENCES

Aghion, P., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P. and Prantl, S. (2009) The effects of entry on incumbent innovation and productivity. The Review of Economics and Statistics 91(1), 2032.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1998) Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Aghion, P. and Saint-Paul, G. (1998) On the virtue of bad times: Interaction between productivity growth and economic fluctuations. Macroeconomic Dynamics 2(3), 322344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andrews, D. and Cingano, F. (2014) Public policy and resource allocation: Evidence from firms in OECD countries. Economic Policy 29(78), 253296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azariadis, C. and Smith, B. (1996) Private information, money, and growth: Indeterminacy, fluctuations, and the Mundell-Tobin effect. Journal of Economic Growth 1(3), 309332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azariadis, C. and Smith, B. (1998) Financial intermediation and regime switching in business cycles. American Economic Review 88(3), 516536.Google Scholar
Banerjee, A. and Newman, A. F. (1993) Occupational choice and the process of development. Journal of Political Economy 101(2), 274298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, A. V. and Duflo, E. (2005) Growth theory through the lens of development economics. In: Volume 1, Part A of Handbook of Economic Growth, pp. 473–552. Elsevier.Google Scholar
Barinci, J. and Cheron, A. (2001) Sunspots and the business cycle in a finance constrained economy. Journal of Economic Theory 97(1), 3049.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartelsman, E., Haltiwanger, J. and Scarpetta, S. (2009) Measuring and analyzing cross-country differences in firm dynamics. In Dunne, T., Jensen, B. and Roberts, M. (eds.), Producer Dynamics: New Evidence from Micro Data, pp. 1576. University of Chicago Press: National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartelsman, E., Scarpetta, S. and Schivardi, F. (2005) Comparative analysis of firm demographics and survival: evidence from micro-level sources in OECD countries. Industrial and Corporate Change 14(3), 365391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernanke, B. and Gertler, M. (1989) Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations. American Economic Review 79(1), 1431.Google Scholar
Bloom, N. and Van Reenen, J. (2010) Why do management practices differ across firms and countries? Journal of Economic Perspectives 24(1), 203224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bresnahan, T. and Raff, D. (1991) Intra-industry heterogeneity and the great depression: The American motor vehicles industry, 1929–1935. Journal of Economic History 51(2), 317331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buera, F. and Moll, B. (2015) Aggregate implications of a credit crunch: The importance of heterogeneity. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7(3), 142.Google Scholar
Burton, T. (1931) Financial Crises and Periods of Industrial and Commercial Depression. New York and London: D. Appleton and Company.Google Scholar
Busso, M., Madrigal, L. and Pages, C. (2013) Productivity and resource misallocation in Latin America. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 13(1), 130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caballero, R. and Hammour, M. (1994) The cleansing effect of recessions. American Economic Review 84(5), 13501368.Google Scholar
Camacho, A. and Conover, E. (2010) Misallocation and productivity in Colombia’s manufacturing industries. Working Paper, Inter-American Development Bank 123, 142.Google Scholar
Caselli, F. (2005) Accounting for cross-country income differences. In Aghion, P. and Durlauf, S. (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth. Amsterdam, Netherlands: North Holland.Google Scholar
Cazzavillan, G., Lloyd-Braga, T. and Pintus, P. (1998) Multiple steady states and endogenous fluctuations with increasing returns to scale in production. Journal of Economic Theory 80(1), 60107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, K. and Irarrazabal, A. (2013) Misallocation and the recovery of manufacturing TFP after a financial crisis. Working Paper, Norges Bank 1, 136.Google Scholar
Concheiro, I. (2011) Spain interrupted: On the form of the financial bubble. Digital Architectural Papers.Google Scholar
Davis, S. and Haltiwanger, J. (1992) Gross job creation, gross job destruction, and employment reallocation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(3), 818863.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easterly, W. and Levine, R. (2001) It’s not factor accumulation: Stylized facts and growth models. The World Bank Economic Review 15(2), 177219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foster, L., Grim, C. and Haltiwanger, J. (2016) Reallocation in the great recession: Cleansing or not? Journal of Labor Economics 34(1), 293331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. and Zeira, J. (1993) Income distribution and macroeconomics. The Review of Economic Studies 60(1), 3552.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardini, L., Sushko, I. and Naimzada, A. K. (2008) Growing through chaotic intervals. Journal of Economic Theory 143(1), 541557.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gopinath, G., Kalemli-Ozcan, S., Karabarbounis, L. and Villegas-Sanchez, C. (2017) Capital allocation and productivity in South Europe. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 132(4), 19151967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grandmont, J., Pintus, P. and Vilder, R. (1998) Capital-labor substitution and competitive nonlinear endogenous business cycles. Journal of Economic Theory 80(1), 1459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G. M. and Helpman, E. (1991) Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Harberger, A. (1998) A vision of the growth process. American Economic Review 88(1), 132.Google Scholar
Hart, O. and Moore, J. (1994) A theory of debt based on the inalienability of human capital. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(4), 841879.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckle, H. (2012) Spain ghost towns develop from real estate crash. Huffington Post.Google Scholar
Holmström, B. and Tirole, J. (1997) Financial intermediation, loanable funds, and the real sector. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(3), 663691.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmström, B. and Tirole, J. (2011) Inside and Outside Liquidity. Cambridge and London: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsieh, C. and Klenow, P. (2008) Misallocation and manufacturing TFP in China and India. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(4), 14031448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kellogg, A. (2010) Detroit shrinks itself, historic homes and all. The Wall Street Journal.Google Scholar
Kennedy, G. and McIndoe, C. (2011) The Irish mortgage market: Stylized facts, negative equity and arrears. Research Technical Papers, Central Bank of Ireland 12.Google Scholar
Kikuchi, T. and Vachadze, G. (2015) Financial liberalization: Poverty trap or chaos. Journal of Mathematical Economics 59, 19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kikuchi, T. and Vachadze, G. (2018) Minimum investment requirement, financial market imperfection and self-fulfilling belief. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 28(2), 305332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiyotaki, N. and Moore, J. (1997) Credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy 105(2), 211248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kongsamut, P., Rebelo, S. and Xie, D. (2001) Beyond balanced growth. Review of Economic Studies 68, 869882.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kunieda, T. and Shibata, A. (2014) Credit market imperfections and macroeconomic instability. Pacific Economic Review 19(5), 592611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kunieda, T. and Shibata, A. (2017) Entrepreneurs, financiers, and boom-bust cycles. Macroeconomic Dynamics 21(3), 785816.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, M. (2011) When Irish eyes are crying. Vanity Fair.Google Scholar
Lucas, R., E. (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics 22, 342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Machicado, C. and Birbuet, J. (2012) Misallocation and manufacturing TFP in Bolivia during the market liberalization period. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 12(1), 145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matsuyama, K. (2007) Credit traps and credit cycles. American Economic Review 97(1), 503516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matsuyama, K. (2008) Aggregate implications of credit market imperfections. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 22, 160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matsuyama, K. (2013) The good, the bad and the ugly: An inquiry into the causes and nature of credit cycles. Theoretical Economics 8(3), 623651.Google Scholar
Moll, B. (2014) Productivity losses from financial frictions: Can self-financing undo capital misallocation? American Economic Review 104(10), 31863221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parente, S. and Prescott, E. (1996) Barriers to technology adoption and development. Journal of Political Economy l02(2), 298–321.Google Scholar
Piketty, T. (1997) The dynamics of the wealth distribution and the interest rate with credit rationing. The Review of Economic Studies 64(2), 173189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Restuccia, D. and Rogerson, R. (2008) Policy distortions and aggregate productivity with heterogeneous plants. Review of Economic Dynamics 11(4), 707720.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romer, P. (1990) Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98, 71102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romer, P. M. (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of political economy 92, 10021037.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rupp, L. (2011) BofA donates then demolishes houses to cut glut. Bloomberg.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. (1939) Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical, and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process. New York: Mc-Graw-Hill.Google Scholar
Townsend, R. M. (1979) Optimal contracts and competitive markets with costly state verification. Journal of Economic Theory 21(2), 265293.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wedell, K. (2011) City needs millions more to raze nuisance housing. Dayton Daily News.Google Scholar
Yang, M. (2016) Micro-level misallocation and selection: Estimation and aggregate implications. Mimeo, UC Berkeley 1452, 169.Google Scholar