Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T14:25:58.783Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

ENERGY IN A MODEL OF FIRM ENTRY

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2018

Soma Patra*
Affiliation:
California State University at Northridge
*
Address correspondence to: Soma Patra, Department of Economics, California State University, Northridge, 18111 Nordhoff Street, Northridge, CA91330, USA; e-mail: [email protected]; website: https://somapatra.weebly.com/

Abstract

Nine out of the last ten recessions in the United States have been preceded by an increase in the price of oil as noted by Hamilton [Palgrave Dictionary of Economics]. Given the small share of energy in gross domestic product this phenomenon is difficult to explain using standard models. In this paper, I show that firm entry can be an important transmission and amplifying channel for energy price shocks. The results from the baseline dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model predict a drop in output that is two times the impact in a model without entry. The model also predicts an increase in energy prices would lead to a decline in real wages, investment, consumption, and return on investment. Additionally, using US firm level data, I demonstrate that a rise in energy prices has a negative impact on firm entry as predicted by the DSGE model. This lends further support toward endogenizing firm entry when analyzing the effects of energy price shocks.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2018

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I am indebted to Nathan Balke for all his suggestions and continuous encouragement. I would also like to thank Thomas Fomby, Anna Kormilitsina, Mine Yucel, Michael Plante, Enrique Martinez Garcia, Mario Crucini, Mark Wynne, and two anonymous referees for their comments and suggestions. In addition, I am grateful to Paul Bergin for sharing his data. All remaining errors are mine.

References

REFERENCES

Atkeson, A. and Kehoe, P. J. (1999) Models of energy use: Putty-putty versus putty-clay. American Economic Review 89 (4), 10281043.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backus, D. and Crucini, M. (2000) Oil prices and the terms of trade. Journal of International Economics 50, 185213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balke, N. S., Brown, S. P. A., and Yücel, M. K. (2002) Oil price shocks and the U.S. economy: Where does the asymmetry originate? Energy Journal 23 (3), 2752.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergin, Paul R. and Corsetti, Giancarlo (2008) The extensive margin and monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 55 (7), 12221237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilbiie, Florin O., Ghironi, Fabio, and Melitz, Marc J. (2012) Endogenous entry, product variety, and business cycles. Journal of Political Economy 120 (21), 304345.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchard, Olivier J. and Gali, Jordi (2007) The Macroeconomic Effects of Oil Price Shocks: Why are the 2000s so Different from the 1970s? NBER working paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carruth, Alan A., Hooker, Mark A. and Oswald, Andrew J. (1998) Unemployment equilibria and input prices: Theory and evidence from the united states. Review of Economics and Statistics 80 (4), 621628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chatterjee, S. and Cooper, R. (2014) Entry and exit, product variety and the business cycle. Economic Inquiry 52 (4), 14661484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, S. J. and Haltiwanger, J. (2001) Sectoral job creation and destruction responses to oil price changes. Journal of Monetary Economics 48, 465512.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, S. J., Loungani, P., and Mahidhara, R. (1997) Regional Labor Fluctuations: Oil Shocks, Military Spending and Other Driving Forces. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System International Finance Discussion Papers Number 578.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Devereux, M., Head, A., and Lapham, B. (1996) Aggregate fluctuations with increasing returns to specialization and scale. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 20 (4), 627657.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elder, J. and Serletis, A. (2010) Oil price uncertainty. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42, 11381159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elder, J., Serletis, A., and Elder, John (2011) Volatility in oil prices and manufacturing activity: An investigation of real options. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15, 379395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engemann, Kristie M., Kliesen, Kevin L., and Owyang, Michael T. (2011) Do oil shocks drive business cycles? Some U.S. and international evidence. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15, 498517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finn, Mary G. (2000) Perfect competition and the effects of energy price increases on economic activity. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 32, 400416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gospodinov, Nikolay, Herrera, A. M., and Pesavento, E. (2013) Unit roots, cointegration and pre-testing in VAR models. Advances in Econometrics: VAR Models in Macroeconomics – New Developments and Applications: Essays in Honor of Christopher A. Sims 32, 81115.Google Scholar
Hamilton, J. D. (1983) Oil and the Macroeconomy since World War II. Journal of Political Economy 91, 228248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, J. D. (1996) This is what happened to the oil price-macroeconomy relationship. Journal of Monetary Economics 38, 215220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, J. D. (2008) Oil and the macroeconomy. In Durlauf, Steven and Blume, Lawrence (eds.), New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd edition. London: Palgrave McMillan Ltd.Google Scholar
Hamilton, James (2009) Causes and consequences of the oil shock of 2007–08. Brookings papers on economic activity. Spring 2009, 215259.Google Scholar
Hamilton, J. D. (2011) Nonlinearities and the Macroeconomic effects of oil prices. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15, 364378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrera, A. M. (2018) Oil price shocks, inventories and macroeconomic dynamics. Macroeconomic Dynamics 22 (3), 620639.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrera, A. M., Lagalo, L. Gupta, and Wada, T. (2011) Oil price shocks and industrial production: Is the relationship linear? Macroeconomic Dynamics 15, 472497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrera, A. M. and Karaki, M. B. (2015) The effect of oil prices on job reallocation. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 61, 95113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrera, A. M., Karaki, M. B., and Rangaraju, S. K. (2017) Where do jobs go when oil prices drop? Energy Economics 64, 469482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaimovich, Nir and Floetotto, Max (2008) Firm dynamics, markup variations, and the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 55, 12381252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keane, M. P. and Prasad, E. S. (1996) The employment and wage effects of oil price changes: A sectoral analysis. Review of Economics and Statistics 78, 389399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kilian, Lutz (2008) The Economic Effects of Energy Price Shocks. Journal of Economic Literature 46 (4), 871909.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kilian, Lutz (2009) Not all oil price shocks are alike: Disentangling demand and supply shocks in the crude oil market. American Economic Review 99 (3), 1053–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kilian, Lutz and Vigfusson, R. J. (2011) Nonlinearities in the oil price-output relationship. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15, 337363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, I.-M. and Loungani, P. (1992) The role of energy in real business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 29, 173189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kormilitsina, Anna (2016) An amplificaion mechanism in a model of energy. Canadian Journal of Economics 49 (4), 14251440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, J., List, J. A., and Strazicich, M. C. (2006) Non-renewable resource prices: Deterministic or stochastic trends? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 53 (3), 354370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, K. and Ni, S. (2002) On the dynamic effects of oil price shocks: A study using industry level data. Journal of Monetary Economics 49, 823852.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, K., Kang, W., and Ratti, R. A. (2011) Oil price shocks, firm uncertainty and investment. Macroeconomics Dynamics 15, 416436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, J. and Thompson, H. (2010) A note on the oil price trend and GARCH shocks. Energy Journal 31, 185191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melitz, Marc J. (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71, 16951725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mork, Knut A. (1989) Oil and the macroeconomy when prices go up and down: An extension of Hamilton's results. Journal of Political Economy 97, 740744.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patra, S. (2016) Oil Prices, Firm Entry, Exit and Aggregate Output Fluctuations. Ph.D. Dissertation, Southern Methodist University.Google Scholar
Pieschacon, A (2012) The value of fiscal discipline for oil-exporting countries. Journal of Monetary Economics 59, 250268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rahman, S. and Serletis, A., (2011) The asymmetric effects of oil price shocks. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15, 437471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotemberg, Julio J. and Woodford, Michael (1996) Imperfect competition and the effects of energy price increases on economic activity. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 28, 549577.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wei, Chao (2003) Energy, the stock market and the putty-clay investment model. American Economic Review 93 (1), 311324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar