Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gxg78 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T16:21:51.694Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Uncovering the Secrets of the Common Law

Review products

Kim Lane Scheppele. Legal Secrets: Equality and Efficiency in the Common Law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988. xiii + 363 pp. Appendix, references, table of cases, name and subject indexes. $54.00 (cloth); $17.95 (paper).

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 July 2024

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Extract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

“Legal secrets” are secrets that the law of torts or contracts either require to be—or protect from being—divulged. The secrets themselves are without limit: a professor's past as a former priest, things learned while in a previous job, that a house has running water only twelve hours each day, that land was worth more than its owner realized, that a patient told his psychotherapist that he planned to kill his girlfriend, that the Treaty of Ghent was signed ending the War of 1812, and on and on. The legal flags under which these battles for the control of secret information are fought reduce to the law of fraud, privacy, trade secrets, and implied warranties. And the underlying economic or other principles that are proposed to explain the decisions in these areas of law are even fewer.

Type
Review Essay
Copyright
Copyright © 1990 The Law and Society Association.

References

References

BRAITHWAITE, Richard B. (1953) Scientific Explanation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
HAAR, Charles M., SAWYER, John P., and Stephen J., CUMMINGS (1977) “Computer Power and Legal Reasoning: A Case Study of Judicial Decision Prediction in Zoning Amendment Cases, 1977 American Bar Foundation Research Journal 651.Google Scholar
HARRIS, Marvin (1979) Cultural Materialism: The Struggle for a Science of Culture. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
HARRIS, Marvin (1974) Cows, Pigs, Wars, and Witches: The Riddles of Culture. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
HOVENKAMP, Herbert (1990) “The First Great Law & Economics Movement,” 42 Stanford Law Review 993.Google Scholar
KAPLAN, Abraham (1964) The Conduct of Inquiry. San Francisco: Chandler Publishing.Google Scholar
KRONMAN, Anthony (1978) “Mistake, Disclosure, Information, and the Law of Contracts,” 7 Journal of Legal Studies 1.Google Scholar
NAGEL, Ernst (1961) The Structure of Science. New York: Harcourt, Brace, & World.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
POPPER, Karl (1959) The Logic of Scientific Discovery. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
POSNER, Richard A. (1981) The Economics of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
SAKS, Michael J. (1988) “Enhancing and Restraining Accuracy in Adjudication,” 51 Law and Contemporary Problems 243.Google Scholar
WHITMORE, Peter (1990) “A Statistical Analysis of Noncompetition Clauses in Employment Contracts,” 15 Journal of Corporation Law 483.Google Scholar
WITTGENSTEIN, Ludwig (1922) Tractatus Logico-Philosophicus. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar

Cases Cited

Barber v. Time, 159 S.W.2d 291 (1942).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Briscoe v. Reader's Digest, 483 P.2d 34 (1971).Google Scholar
Laidlaw v. Organ, 15 U.S. (2 Wheat.) 178 (1817).Google Scholar
Melvin v. Reid, 297 P. 91 (1931).Google Scholar
Virgil v. Time, 527 F.2d 1122 (1975).Google Scholar
Wheeler v. P. Sorenson Mfg. Co., 415 S.W.2d 582 (Ky. 1967).Google Scholar