We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
An abstract is not available for this content so a preview has been provided. Please use the Get access link above for information on how to access this content.
Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)
References
Baumol, William J.1986. Superfaimess, Application and Theory. Cambridge, Mass.: M.I.T. Press.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S.1968. Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach. Journal of Political Economy76:169–217.Google Scholar
Chaing, Alpha1984. Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics. 3d ed. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co.Google Scholar
Coleman, Jules L.1982. The Economic Analysis of Law. In NOMOS XXIV: Ethics, Economics, and the Law, edited by Roland Pennock, J. and Chapman, John W.New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Coleman, Jules. 1985. Crime, Kickers, and Transaction Structures. In Nomos XXVII: Criminal Justice, edited by Roland Pennock, J., & Chapman, John W.New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Crespi, Gregory. 1991. The Mid-Life Crisis of the Law and Economics Movement: Confronting the Problems of Nonfalsifiability and Normative Bias. Notre Dame Law Review67:231–52.Google Scholar
Crespi, Gregory S.1997. Does the Chicago School Need to Expand Its CurriculumLaw and Social Inquiry21:149–69.Google Scholar
Dau-Schmidt, Kenneth. 1990. An Economic Analysis of the Criminal Law as a Preference-Shaping Policy. Duke Law Journal1990:1–38.Google Scholar
Dau-Schmidt, Kenneth G.1991. Relaxing Traditional Economic Assumptions and Values: Toward a New Multidisciplinary Discourse on Law. Syracuse Law Review42:181–95.Google Scholar
Dau-Schmidt, Kenneth G.1995. Legal Prohibitions as More than Prices: The Economic Analysis of Preference Shaping Policies in the Law. In Law and Economics: New and Critical Perspectives, edited by Malloy, Robin P. and Braun, Christopher K. 1995. New York: Peter Lang Publishers.Google Scholar
Devlin, Patrick B.1965. The Enforcement of Morals. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Ehrlich, Isaac. 1975. The Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment: A Question of Life and Death. American Economic Review65:397–417.Google Scholar
Ferguson, C. E., and Gould, J. P.1975. Microeconomics Theory. Homewood, Ill.: Richard B. Irwin, Inc.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1953. The Methodology of Positive Economics. In Essays on Positive Economics, edited by Friedman, Milton. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Gibband, Allen, and Varian, Hal. 1978. Economic Models. Journal of Philosophy10:664–77.Google Scholar
Hart, H. L. A.1967. Social Solidarity and the Enforcement of Morality. University of Chicago Law Review35:1–13.Google Scholar
Klevorick, Alvin. 1985. On the Economic Theory of Crime. In Nomos XXVII: Criminal Justice, edited by Pennock, J., & Chapman, J.New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
McManus, M.1978. Social Welfare Optimization with Tastes as Variables. 114Welttwrt-schaftUches Archive114:101–22.Google Scholar
Menninger, Karl A.1968. The Crime of Punishment. New York: Viking Press.Google Scholar
Parker, Jeffrey S.1993. The Economics of Mens Rea. 79Virginia Law Review79:741–811.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard. 1980. Optimal Sentences for the White Collar Criminals. American Criminal Law Review17:409–18.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard. 1985. An Economic Theory of the Criminal Law. Columbia Law Review85:1193–1231.Google Scholar