We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
An abstract is not available for this content so a preview has been provided. Please use the Get access link above for information on how to access this content.
Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)
References
Altman, Scott. 1993. A Patchwork Theory of Blackmail. University of Pennsylvania Law Review141: 1639–61.Google Scholar
Auerbach, Alan J.1991. Retrospective Capital Gains Taxation. American Economics Review81: 167–68.Google Scholar
Auerbach, Alan J., Kotlikoff, Laurence J., and Skinner, Jonathan. 1983. The Efficiency Gains from Dynamic Tax Reform. International Economics Review24: 81–100.Google Scholar
Barnett, Randy E.1986. A Consent Theory of Contract. Columbia Law Review86: 269–321.Google Scholar
Barnett, Randy E.1992. The Sound of Silence: Default Rules and Contractual Consent. VirginiaLaw Review78: 821–911.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary. 1974. A Theory of Social Interactions. Journal of Political Economy82: 1063–93.Google Scholar
Bradford, David. 1996. Consumption Taxes: Some Fundamental Transition Issues. In Frontiers of Tax Reform, ed. Boskin, Michael J., 123–50.Google Scholar
Calabresi, Guido, and Melamed., A. Douglas1972. Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral. Harvard Law Review85: 1089–1128.Google Scholar
Collard, David A.1978. Altruism and Economy. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Craswell, Richard. 1989. Contract Law, Default Rules, and the Philosophy of Promising. Michigan Law Review88: 489–529.Google Scholar
DeLong, Sidney W.1993. Blackmailers, Bribe Takers, and the Second Paradox. University of Pennsylvania Law Review141: 1663–93.Google Scholar
Epstein, Richard. 1983. Blackmail, Inc. University of Chicago LawReview 50: 553–66.Google Scholar
Fletcher, George. 1993. Blackmail: The Paradigmatic Crime. University of Pennsylvania Law Review141: 1617–38.Google Scholar
Fried, Charles. 1981. Contract as Promise. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Fromm, Erich. 1966. Marx's Concept of Man. New York: F. Unger.Google Scholar
Gergen, Mark P.1994. A Cautionary Tale about Contractual Good Faith in Texas. Texas Law Review72: 1235–75.Google Scholar
Gergen, Mark P.1995. A Defense of Judicial Reconstruction of Contracts. Indiana Law Journal71: 45–99.Google Scholar
Gergen, Mark P.1996a. A Grudging Defense of the Role of the Collateral Torts in Wrongful Termination Litigation. Texas Law Review74: 1693–1739.Google Scholar
Gergen, Mark P.1996b. Tortious Interference: How It Is Engulfing Commercial Law, Why This Is Not Entirely Bad, and a Prudential Response. Arizona Law Review38: 1175–1232.Google Scholar
Gordon, Wendy J.1993. Truth and Consequences: The Force of Blackmail's Central Case. University of Pennsylvania Law Review141: 1741–85.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 1988. Morality within the Limits of Reason. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 1993. Blackmailing for Mutual Good. University of Pennsylvania Law Review141: 1787–1816.Google Scholar
Isenbergh, Joseph. 1993. Blackmail from A to C. University of Pennsylvania Law Review141: 1905–33.Google Scholar
Kahn, Douglas A., and Lehman, Jeffrey S.1992. Tax Expenditure Budgets: A Critical View. Tax Notes54: 1661–65.Google Scholar
Landes, William A., and Posner, Richard. 1987. The Economic Structure of Tort Law. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Laycock, Douglas. 1985. The Ultimate Unity of Rights and Utilities. Texas Law Review64: 407–13.Google Scholar
Lindgren, Jim. 1984. Unraveling the Paradox of Blackmail. Columbia Law Review84: 670–717.Google Scholar
Nozick, Robert. 1974Anarchy, State, and Utopia. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar