Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-g8jcs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-29T12:48:28.811Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Institutional Choice and Political Faith

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 December 2018

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Review Section Symposium
Copyright
Copyright © American Bar Foundation, 1997 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Ackerman, Bruce A. 1985. Beyond Carolene Products. Harvard Law Review 98: 713–46.Google Scholar
Ackerman, Bruce A., and Hassler, William T. 1981. Clean Coal/Dirty Air. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Arnold, Douglas R. 1990. The Logic of Congressional Action. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Axline, Michael. 1996. Forest Health and the Politics of Expediency. Environmental Law 26: 613–40.Google Scholar
Bernstein, Marver H. 1955. Regulating Business by Independent Commission. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bickel, Alexander M. 1962. The Least Dangerous Branch. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merril.Google Scholar
Blumm, Michael C. Public Choice and the Public Lands: Why “Multiple Use” Failed. 18 Harvard Environmental Law Review 18: 405–32.Google Scholar
Breyer, Stephen. 1993. Breaking the Vicious Circle. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., and Tullock, Gordon. 1962. The Calculus of Consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Calabresi, Guido. 1970. The Costs of Accidents. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law & Economics 3: 144.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1957. Decision-making in a Democracy: The Supreme Court as a National Policy-maker. Journal of Public Law 6: 279–95.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1961. Who Governs? New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. 1969. Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint. Journal of Law & Economics 12: 122.Google Scholar
Egan, Timothy. 1995. In Battle Over Public Lands, Ranchers Push Public Aside. New York Times, 21 July, Al.Google Scholar
Easterbrook, Frank. 1983. Statutes' Domains. University of Chicago Law Review 50: 533–52.Google Scholar
Elhauge, Einer R. 1991. Does Interest Group Theory Justify More Intrusive Judicial Review? Yale Law Journal 101: 31110.Google Scholar
Ely, John Hart. 1980. Democracy and Distrust. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, Richard. 1985. Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent Domain. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, Richard. 1992. Forbidden Grounds: The Case Against Employment Discriminations Laws. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Eskridge, William N. Jr. 1991. Reneging on History? Playing the Court/Congress/Presi-dent Civil Rights Game. California Law Review 79: 613–84.Google Scholar
Eskridge, William N. Jr., and Ferejohn, John. 1992. The Article I, Section 7 Game. Georgetown Law Journal 80: 523–64.Google Scholar
Esposito, John C. 1970. Vanishing Air. New York: Grossman Publishers.Google Scholar
Esty, Daniel C. 1996. Revitalizing Environmental Federalism. Michigan Law Review 95: 570653.Google Scholar
Farber, Daniel A. 1995. Positive Theory as Normative Critique. Southern California Law Review 68: 1565–93.Google Scholar
Farber, Daniel A., and Frickey, Philip P. 1991. Law and Public Choice. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Fellmeth, Robert C., Schultz, John E., and Cox, Edward F. 1969. The Nader Report on the Federal Trade Commission. New York: R. W. Baron.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P. 1989. Congress: Keystone of the Washington Establishment. 2d ed. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1962. Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Green, Donald P., and Shapiro, Ian. 1994. Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Hart, Henry M. Jr., and Sacks, Albert M. 1994. The Legal Process: Basic Problems in the Making and Application of Law. Westbury, N.Y.: Foundation Press.Google Scholar
Hungerford, Andrea L. 1994. Changing the Management of Public Land Forests: The Role of the Spotted Owl Injunctions. Environmental Law 24: 13951434.Google Scholar
Inden, William L. 1996. Compensation Legislation: Private Property Rights vs. Public Benefits. Dickinson Journal of Environmental Law & Policy 5: 119–50.Google Scholar
Komesar, Neil K. 1988. A Job for Judges: The Judiciary and the Constitution in a Massive and Complex Society. Michigan Law Review 86: 657–50.Google Scholar
Landis, James M. 1938. The Administrative Process. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Landis, William M., and Posner, Richard A. 1975. The Independent Judiciary in an Interest-Group Perspective. Journal of Law & Economics 18: 875901.Google Scholar
Latham, Earl. 1952. The Group Basis of Politics. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Loftis, Randy Lee. 1996. The Latest Range Wars; Ranchers, Loggers Fight Environmentalists Who Seek to Lease Federal Land. Dallas Morning News, 22 April, 1A.Google Scholar
Lowi, Theodore J. 1969. The End of Liberalism. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Macey, Jonathan R. 1986. Promoting Public-Regarding Legislation Through Statutory Interpretation: An Interest Group Model. Columbia Law Review 86: 223–68.Google Scholar
Macey, Jonathan R. 1988. Transaction Costs and the Normative Elements of the Public Choice Model: An Application to Constitutional Theory. Virginia Law Review 74: 471518.Google Scholar
Madison, James M. 1787. The Federalist. No. 10.Google Scholar
Mashaw, Jerry L. 1997. Greed, Chaos, and Governance: Using Public Choice to Improve Public Law. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Mayhew, David. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Yaven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
McAdams, Richard H. 1995. Cooperation and Conflict: The Economics of Group Status Production and Race Discrimination. Harvard Law Review 108: 1003–84.Google Scholar
Merrill, Thomas W. 1993. Pluralism, The Prisoner's Dilemma, and the Behavior of the Independent Judiciary. Northwestern Law Review 88: 396409.Google Scholar
Merrill, Thomas W. 1995. Toward a General Theory of Minority Groups: Outsider Groups, Adversity Groups, and Transfer Groups. Annual Review of Law & Ethics 3: 69101.Google Scholar
Merrill, Thomas W. 1996. Three Models of Affirmative Action Beneficiaries. Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy 19: 779–84.Google Scholar
Merrill, Thomas W. Forthcoming. Capture Theory and the Courts: 1967–1983. Chicago-Kent Law Review.Google Scholar
Morrison, James F. 1987. The National Forest Management Act and Below Cost Timber Sales: Determining the Economic Suitability of Land for Timber Production. Environmental Law 17: 557–90.Google Scholar
Muller, Ingo. 1990. Hitler's Justice: The Courts of the Third Reich. Trans. Schneider, Deborah L. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Neely, Richard. 1988. The Product Liability Mess: How Business Can Be Rescued from the Politics of State Courts. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1974. Theories of Economic Regulation. Bell Journal of Economics & Management Science 5: 355–58.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1989. The Future of Law and Economics: A Comment on EUickson. Chicago-Kent Law Review 65: 5762.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1995. Overcoming Law. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Rabin, Robert. 1986. Federal Regulation in Historical Perspective. Stanford Law Review 38: 11891326.Google Scholar
Rauch, Jonafhan. 1994. Demosclerosis: The Silent Killer of American Government. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Rawls, John. 1971. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Rodriguez, Daniel B. 1994. The Positive Political Dimensions of Regulatory Reform. Washington University Law Quarterly 72: 1150.Google Scholar
Rubin, Paul H. 1982. Common Law and Statute Law. 11. Journal of Legal Studies 11: 205–23.Google Scholar
Shapiro, Martin. 1988. Who Guards the Guardians? Athens: Georgia University Press.Google Scholar
Stephen, Leslie. 1900. The English Utilitarians. London: Duckworth.Google Scholar
Stewart, Richard B. 1975. The Reformation of American Administrative Law. Harvard Law Review 88: 16671813.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1971. The Theory of Economic Regulation. 2. Bell Journal of Economics & Management Science 3.Google Scholar
Reprinted in Stigler, George J. 1975. The Citizen and the State. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 1985. Interest Groups in American Public Law. Stanford Law Review 38: 2987.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 1990. After the Rights Revolution: Reconceiving the Regulatory State. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Truman, David. 1951. The Governmental Process. New York: Knopf.Google Scholar
Turner, James S. 1970. The Chemical Feast. New York: Grossman Publishers.Google Scholar
Wilson, James Q. 1980. The Politics of Regulation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Wright, J. Skelly. 1972. Beyond Discretionary Justice. Yale Law Journal 81: 575–97.Google Scholar
Zwick, David, and Benstock, Marcy. 1971. Water Wasteland. New York: Grossman Publishers.Google Scholar