Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-g7gxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T20:34:21.915Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A Reassessment of Scholastic Monetary Theory

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Extract

During the sixteenth century, successive waves of gold and silver reached Spain from America and then rolled across Europe to the North and East. Contemporaries made two observations. First, the inflow of bullion was associated with inflation. Second, a given amount of money in a country with relatively low prices tended to exchange for a larger amount of money in a country with relatively high prices. The scholastic doctors in Salamanca who interpreted these observations are traditionally credited with two modern insights, namely the quantity theory of money, and the principle of purchasing-power parity.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1993

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Barro, Robert J. 1979. “Money and the Price Level under the Gold Standard,” Economic Journal, 89, no. 1, 1333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernholz, Peter. 1992. “The Discovery of the New World and the Development of the Purchasing Power Parity Theory,” in José, Casas Pardo, ed., Economic Effects of the European Expansion: Beiträge zur Wirtschafts- und Sozialgeschichte, Steiner, Stuttgart, 234–61.Google Scholar
Bodin, Jean. 1932. La Response de Jean Bodin à M. de Malestroit, 1568, edited by Hauser, H., Colin, Paris.Google Scholar
Boeck, Louis. 1988. “Spanish Economic Thought: The School of Salamanca and the Arbitristas,” History of Political Economy, 20, no. 3, 381408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bordo, Michael D. 1992. “Gold Standard: Theory,” The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance, 2, Macmillan, London, 267–71.Google Scholar
Bordo, Michael D. and Ellson, Richard W.. 1985. “A Model of the Classical Gold Standard with Depletion,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 16, no. 1, 109–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braudel, Fernand. 1972. The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World in the Age of Philip II, translated by Reynolds, S., 2 vols., Collins, London.Google Scholar
Braudel, Fernand and Frank S, ooner. 1967. “Prices in Europe from 1450 to 1750,” in Rich, E. E. and Wilson, C. H., eds., The Cambridge History of Europe, 4, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 374486.Google Scholar
Dempsey, Bernard W. 1935. “The Historical Emergence of Quantity Theory,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 50, no. 1, 174–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doughty, Robert A. 1975. “Industrial Prices and Inflation in Southern England, 1401–1640,” Explorations in Economic History, 12, no. 2, 177–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Einzig, Paul. 1970. The History of Foreign Exchange, 2d ed., Macmillan, London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flynn, Dennis O. 1978. “A New Perspective on the Spanish Price Revolution: The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments,” Explorations in Economic History, 15, no. 4, 388406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grice-Hutchison, Marjorie. 1952. The School of Salamanca: Readings in Spanish Monetary Theory 1544–1605, Clarendon, Oxford.Google Scholar
Grice-Hutchison, Marjorie. 1978. Early Economic Thought in Spain, 1177–1740, Allen and Unwin, London.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Earl J. 1934. American Treasure and the Price Revolution in Spain, 1501–1650, Harvard University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckscher, Eli F. 1935. Mercantilism, translated by Shapiro, M., 2 vols., Allen and Unwin, London.Google Scholar
Niehans, Jürg. 1978. The Theory of Money, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Officer, Lawrence. 1982. Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rates: Theory, Evidence and Relevance, JAI, Greenwich.Google Scholar
Roover, Raymond de. 1974. Business, Banking, and Economic Thought in Late Medieval and Early Modern Europe, edited by Kirshner, J., University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis, edited by Schumpeter, E. B., Oxford University Press, New York.Google Scholar
Spiegel, Henry W. 1983. The Growth of Economic Thought, rev. ed., Duke University Press, Durham.Google Scholar
Spiegel, Henry W. 1987. “Scholastic Economic Thought,” in John, Eatwell, Murray, Milgate and Peter, Newman, eds., The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 4, Macmillan, London, 259–61.Google Scholar
Spooner, Frank C. 1972. The International Economy and Monetary Movements in France, 1493–1725, Harvard University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Vilar, Pierre. 1976. A History of Gold and Money, 1450–1920, translated by White, J., NLB, London.Google Scholar
Viner, Jacob. 1937. Studies in the Theory of International Trade, Harper, New York.Google Scholar