Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T07:55:22.940Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE PHILLIPS CURVE AND AN ASSUMED UNIQUE MACROECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM IN HISTORICAL CONTEXT

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 November 2016

Richard G. Lipsey*
Affiliation:
Emeritus Professor of Economics, Simon Fraser University, [email protected].

Abstract

An early post-WWII debate concerned the most desirable demand and inflationary pressures at which to run the economy. Context was provided by Keynesian theory devoid of a full employment equilibrium and containing its mainly forgotten, but still relevant, microeconomic underpinnings. A major input came with the estimates provided by the original Phillips curve. The debate seemed to be rendered obsolete by the curve’s expectations-augmented version with its natural rate of unemployment, and associated unique equilibrium GDP, as the only values consistent with stable inflation. The current behavior of economies with the successful inflation targeting is inconsistent with this natural-rate view, but is consistent with evolutionary theory in which economies have a wide range of GDP-compatible stable inflation. Now the early post-WWII debates are seen not to be as misguided as they appeared to be when economists came to accept the assumptions implicit in the expectations-augmented Phillips curve.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Ambler, Steven. 2014. Price-Level Targeting: A post Mortem? Commentary No 400. Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute.Google Scholar
Altomonte, Carlo, Barattieri, Alessandro, and Basu, Susanto. 2015. “Average-Cost Pricing: Some Evidence and Implications.” European Economic Review 79: 281296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1992. The Methodology of Economics. Second edition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blinder, Alan S. 1979. Economic Policy and the Great Stagflation. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Carlaw, Kenneth I., and Lipsey, Richard G.. 2012. “Does History Matter?: Empirical Analysis of Evolutionary versus Stationary Views of the Economy.” Journal of Evolutionary Economics 22 (4): 735766.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckstein, Otto. 1981. Core Inflation. Englewood: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Freeman, Christopher, and Louçã, Francisco. 2001. As Time Goes By: From the Industrial Revolutions to the Information Revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1968. “The Role of Monetary Policy.” American Economic Review 58: 117.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1975. Unemployment Versus Inflation. London: Institute for Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
Hall, Robert L., and Hitch, Charles J.. 1939. “Price Theory and Business Behaviour.” Oxford Economic Papers 2: 1245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnston, John. 1960. Statistical Cost Analysis. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 1965. “Structural and Deficient Demand Unemployment Reconsidered.” In Ross, Arthur M., ed., Employment Policy and the Labor Market. Berkeley: University of California Press, pp. 210255.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 1981. “The Understanding and Control of Inflation and Unemployment: Is There a Crisis in Macro-Economics?” Canadian Journal of Economics 14: 545576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G, ed. 1990. Zero Inflation: The Goal of Price Stability. Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute. Policy Study 8.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 2000. “IS-LM, Keynesianism and the New Classicism.” In Backhouse, Roger E. and Salanti, Andrea, eds., Macroeconomics and the Real World. Volume 2: Keynesian Economics, Unemployment, and Policy. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 5782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 2010. “Evolutionary Economics and the Disappearing NAIRU and Phillips Curve.” In Hanusch, Horst, Kurz, Heinz D., and Seidl, Christian, eds., Schumpeter for Our Century: Homo Oeconomicus Special Issue 27 (1/2): 145176.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 2011. “The Phillips Curve.” In Blaug, Mark and Lloyd, Peter, eds., Famous Figures and Diagrams in Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 377392.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 2013. “Some Contentious Issues in Theory and Policy in Memory of Mark Blaug.” In Boumans, Marcell and Klaes, Matthias, eds., Mark Blaug: Rebel with Many Causes. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 3162.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G., Carlaw, Kenneth I., and Bekar, Clifford T.. 2005. Economic Transformations: General Purpose Technologies and Long-Term Economic Growth. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G., and Chrystal, Alec. 2015. Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G., and Scarth, William. 2011. “The History, Significance and Policy Context of the Phillips Curve.” In Lipsey, Richard G. and Scarth, William, eds., Inflation and Unemployment: The Evolution of the Phillips Curve. Volume 1. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. Jr., and Rapping, Leonard A.. 1969. “Real Wages, Employment, and Inflation.” Journal of Political Economy 77 (5): 721754.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mankiw, N. Gregory, and Scarth, William. 2001. Macroeconomics. Sixth edition. New York: Worth Publishers.Google Scholar
Paish, Frank W. 1958. “Inflation in the United Kingdom, 1948–1957.” Economica 25 (98): 94105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paish, Frank W. 1962. Studies in an Inflationary Economy: The United Kingdom 1948–1961. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Paish, Frank W. 1970. How the Economy Works and Other Essays. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Phelps, Edmund S. 1967. “Phillips Curves, Expectations of Inflation and Optimal Unemployment over Time.” Economica NS 34: 254281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwarzer, Johannes A. 2012. “A. W. Phillips and His Curve: Stabilisation Policies, Inflation Expectations and the ‘Menu of Choice.’” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 19 (6): 9761003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwarzer, Johannes A. 2013. “Samuelson and Solow on the Phillips Curve and the ‘Menu of Choice’: A Retrospective.” Œconomia 3 (3): 359388.Google Scholar
Schwarzer, Johannes A. 2014. “Growth as an objective of economic policy in the early 1960s: the role of aggregate demand.” Cahiers d’économie politique/ Papers in Political Economy 67 (2): 175206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar