Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-94fs2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T14:29:16.993Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Historical Development of Hierarchical Behavior in Economic Thought

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

S. A. Drakopoulos
Affiliation:
Department of Philosophy and History of Science, University of Athens, Panepistimioupolis 157 71, Athens, Greece
A. D. Karayiannis
Affiliation:
University of Piraeus, 80, Karaoli & Dimitriou St. 185 34, PiraeusGreece

Extract

One of the basic ideas underlying the established conception of rational behavior is the unlimited substitutability of preferences. Economic agents are assumed to compare and reduce everything to a common denominator: utility. The most obvious example of such preferences can be found in standard consumer theory where complete substitutability of every good is assumed in the sense that a loss of some units of one bundle can always be compensated by gain of some units of another commodity (such preferences are sometimes called Archimedian—see Borch 1968). This conception of preferences has a long history in economic thought and forms the basis of the standard rational choice theory (Hicks and Allen 1934, Samuelson 1938, Hicks 1946, Houthakker 1950).

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2004

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Alter, M. 1991. “Difficulties in reading Menger.” European Journal of Political Economy 7 (01): 93113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ardrey, R. 1970. The Social Contract. New York: Dell.Google Scholar
Aristotle, . Nicomachean Ethics. Athens: Papiros, 1949 (in Greek).Google Scholar
Banfield, T. C. 1845. Four Lectures on the Organization of Industry. London: Richard and John E. Taylor.Google Scholar
Barbon, N. 1690. A Discourse of Trade. London: printed by Tho. Milbourn for the Author.Google Scholar
Baxter, J. 1988. Social and Psychological Foundations of Economic Analysis. London: Harvester Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Bentham, J. 1823. An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Berkley, G. 1735–37. The Querist. Published in Dublin in three parts 1735, 1736, 1737. Anonymous.Google Scholar
Bettman, J. 1979. An Information Processing Theory of Consumer Choice. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Birch, T. 1985. “Marshall and Keynes Revisited.” Journal of Economic Issues 19 (03): 194–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borch, K. 1968. The Economics of Uncertainty. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Brooks, M. 1988. “Toward a Behavioral Analysis of Public Economics.” In Earl, P., ed., Psychological Economics. Boston, MA: Kluwer, pp. 169–88.Google Scholar
Canterbery, R. 1979. “Inflation, Necessities and Distributive Efficiency.” In Gapinski, James and Rockwood, Charles, eds, Essays in Post-Keynesian Inflation. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.Google Scholar
Cantillon, R. 1755. Essay on the Nature of Trade in General, translated by Higgs, H.. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1964.Google Scholar
Chipman, J. 1971. “On the Lexicographic Presentation of Preference Orderings.” In Chipman, John et al. , eds, Preferences, Utility and Demand. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Collison, B. R. 1987. “T. C. Banfield.” In Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. and Newman, P., eds, The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Vol. 1. London: Macmillan, p. 182.Google Scholar
Day, R. & Robinson, S. 1973. “Economic decision and L** utility.” In Cochrane, J. and Zeleny, M., eds, Multiple Criteria Decision Making. Columbia, SC: University of South Carolina.Google Scholar
Deaton, A. & Muellbauer, J. 1980. Economics and Consumer Behaviour. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Depreu, G. 1959. Theory of Value. John Wiley, New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Doyal, L. & Gough, I. 1984. “A Theory of Human Needs.” Critical Social Policy 10 (01): 638.Google Scholar
Drakopoulos, S. 1994. “Hierarchical Choice in Economics.” Journal of Economic Surveys 8 (02): 133–53.Google Scholar
Drakopoulos, S. 1997a. “Modelling Menger's Consumer Theory.” Ekonomia 1 (01): 8296.Google Scholar
Drakopoulos, S. 1997b. “Origins and Development of the Trend Toward Value-free Economics.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 19 (02): 286300.Google Scholar
Duesenberry, J. S. 1949. Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behaviour. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Earl, P. 1983. The Economic Imagination. New York: M. E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
Earl, P. 1986. Lifestyle Economics. Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books.Google Scholar
Earl, P. 1995. Microeconomics for Business and Marketing. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Eichner, A. 1987. The Macrodynamics of Advanced Market Economies. New York: M. E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
Encarnacion, J. 1964a. “A Note on Lexicographical Preference.” Econometrica 32 (1–2): 215–17.Google Scholar
Encarnacion, J. 1964b. “Constraints and the Firm's Utility Functions.” Review of Economic Studies 31 (02): 113–19.Google Scholar
Encarnacion, J. 1983. “Social Values and Individual Choices.” Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organisation 4 (2–3): 265–75.Google Scholar
Endres, A. 1991. Marshall's Analysis of Economising Behaviour with Particular Reference to the Consumers.” European Economic Review 35 (2–3): 333–41.Google Scholar
Endres, A. 1997. Neoclassical Microeconomic Theory: The Founding Austrian Version. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Falkinger, J. 1990. “On Growth Along a Hierarchy of Wants.” Metroeconomica 3 (03): 209–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferguson, C. E. 1965. “The Theory of Multidimensional Utility Analysis in Relation to Multiple-goal Business Behaviour: A Synthesis”. Southern Economic Journal 32 (2): 169–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fishburn, P. 1974. “Lexicographic Orders, Utilities and Decision Rules: A Survey.” Management Science 20 (11): 1442–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1954. “Choice, Expectations and Measurability.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 68 (11): 503–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1966. Analytical Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gravelle, H. & Rees, R. 1981. Microeconomics. London: Longman.Google Scholar
Hargreaves Heap, S., Hollis, M., Lyons, B., Sugden, R. & Weale, A., eds. 1992. The Theory of Choice. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. 1946. Value and Capital. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. & Allen, R. D. G. 1934. “A Reconsideration of the Theory of Value.” Economica 1 (02): 5276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Himmelweit, S., Simonetti, R. & Trigg, A. 2001. Microeconomics: Neoclassical and Institutional Perspectives on Economic Behaviour. London: Thomson Learning.Google Scholar
Houthakker, H. S. 1950. “Revealed Preference and the Utility Function.” Economica N. S. (17): 159–74.Google Scholar
Hume, D. 1970. Writings on Economics, edited by Rotwein, E.. Madison, WI: The University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Hutchison, T. 1953. A Review of Economic Doctrines 1870–1929. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Ironmoger, D. 1972. New Commodities and Consumer Behaviour. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jennings, R. 1855. Natural Elements of Political Economy. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1969.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. 1871. The Theory of Political Economy, 4th edition. London: Macmillan. 1911.Google Scholar
Karayiannis, A. 1990. “The Platonic Ethico-economic Structure of Society.” Quaderni di Storia dell' Economia Politica 8 (1): 345.Google Scholar
Karayiannis, A. 2001. “Behavioural Assumptions in Nassau Senior's Economics.” Contributions to Political Economy 20 (1): 1729.Google Scholar
Lancaster, K. 1966. “A New Approach to Consumer Theory.” Journal of Political Economy LXXIV (1): 132–57.Google Scholar
Launderdale, Eighth Earl of. 1804. An Inquiry into the Nature and Origin of Public Wealth and into the Means and Causes of Its Increase. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1966.Google Scholar
Lavoie, M. 1994. “Post-Keynesian Approach to Consumer Theory”. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 16 (4): 539–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levi, I. 1986. Hard Choices. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Little, I. M. D. 1957. A Critique of Welfare Economics. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Lloyd, W. F. 1833. The Notion of Value, in W. F. Lloyd Lectures on Population, Value, Poor-Laws and Rent. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1968.Google Scholar
Longfield, M. 1834. Lectures on Political Economy. In Black, R. D. Collison, ed., The Economic Writings of Mountifort Longfield. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1971.Google Scholar
Lutz, M. 1999. Economics for the Common Good: Two Centuries of Social Economic Thought in the Humanistic Tradition. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Lux, K. & Lutz, M. 1986. “Economic Psychology: the Humanistic Perspective.” In MacFayden, A. and MacFayden, H., eds, Economic Psychology: Intersections in Theory and Application. Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 383424.Google Scholar
McCulloch, J. R. 1826. A Treatise on the Circumstances which Determine the Rate of Wages and the Condition of the Labouring Classes Including an Inquiry into the Influence of Combinations, second edition. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1967.Google Scholar
Malinvaud, E. 1972. Lectures in Microeconomic Theory. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Malthus, T. R. 1815. An Inquiry into the Nature and Progress of Rent, and the Principles by Which It Is Regulated. In The Pamphlets of Thomas Robert Malthus. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1970.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of Economics, 8th edition. Macmillan: London.Google Scholar
Maslow, A. 1954. Motivation and Personality. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Mason, R. 1989. Robert Giffen and the Giffen Paradox. Oxford: Philip Allan.Google Scholar
Mason, R. 2002. “Conspicuous Consumption in Economic Theory and Thought.” In Fullbrook, Edward, ed., Inter subjectivity in Economics: Agents and Structures. London and New York: Routledge, pp. 85104.Google Scholar
Menger, C. 1871. Principles of Economics, translated by Dingwall, J. and Hoselitz, B.. Glencoe, IL: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Mill, J. 1821. Elements of Political Economy, 3rd edition, 1844. New York: A. M. Kelley. 1965.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. 1848. Principles of Political Economy, 7th edition. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1976.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P. 1989. More Heat than Light. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mosley, P. 1984. The Making of Economic Policy. Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books.Google Scholar
Newman, S. 1835. Elements of Political Economy. Clifton, NJ: A. M. Kelley, 1973.Google Scholar
Pareto, V. 1908. Manual of Political Economy, translated by Schwier, A.. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1971.Google Scholar
Parsons, S. 2000. “Shackle and the Project of Enlightenment: Reason, Time and Imagination.” In Earl, P. and Frowen, S., ed, Economics as an Art of Thought: Essays in Memory of G. L. S. Schackle. London: Routledge, pp. 124–48.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, L. 1981. Structural Change and Economic Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Peart, S. & Levy, D. 2003. “Denying Human Homogeneity: Eugenics and the Making of Post-classical Economics.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 25 (3): 261–88.Google Scholar
Pfouts, R. 2002. “On the Need for a More Complete Ontology of the Consumer.” In Fullbrook, Edward, ed., Intersubjectivity in Economics: Agents and Structures. London and New York: Routledge, pp. 7184.Google Scholar
Plato, . 1975 Republic. Athens: Papiros (in Greek).Google Scholar
Rae, J. 1834. Statement of Some New Principles on the Subject of Political Economy. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1964.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. 1971. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, A. 2000. Economics and Language: Five Essays. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. 1938. “A Note on the Pure Theory of Consumer's Behaviour.” Economica 5 (02): 6171.Google Scholar
Say, J. B. 1803. A Treatise on Political Economy, or The Production, Distribution and Consumption of Wealth, translated by Prinsep, C.. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1964.Google Scholar
Schabas, M. 1990. A World Ruled by Number: William Stanley Jevons and the Rise of Mathematical Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Senior, N. W. 1836. An Outline of the Science of Political Economy. A. M. Kelley, New York, 1965.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, edited by Campbell, R. H., Skinner, A., Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Sraffa, P. 1960. Production of Commodoties by Means of Commodities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Staley, C. 1989. A History of Economic Thought from Aristotle to Arrow. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Steinbruner, J. 1974. The Cybernetic Theory of Decision. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
SirSteuart, J. 1767. An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Oeconomy, edited by Skinner, A.. Edinburgh: Oliver & Boyd, 1966.Google Scholar
Streeten, P. 1981. First Things First Meeting Basic Human Needs in the Developing Countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Torrens, R. 1826. An Essay on the External Corn Trade. Clifton, NJ: A. M. Kelley, 1972.Google Scholar
Vint, J. 1994. Capital and Wages: A Lakatosian History of the Wages Fund Doctrine. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Whitaker, J. 1977. “Some Neglected Aspects of Alfred Marshall's Economic and Social Thought.” History of Political Economy 9 (2): 161–97.Google Scholar
White, L. 1990. “Restoring an ‘Altered’ Menger.” In Bruce Caldwell, ed., Annual Supplement to History of Political Economy 22 (5): 349–58.Google Scholar
White, M. 1992. “Diamonds are Forever?: Nassau Senior and Utility Theory.” Manchester School LX (1): 6478.Google Scholar
Wieser, F. von. 1889. Natural Value, translated by Malloch, C.. New York: A. M. Kelley, 1971.Google Scholar