Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-8bhkd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T20:30:43.780Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

ALTERING THE PATTERN OF TRADE IN THE WEALTH OF NATIONS: ADAM SMITH AND THE HISTORIOGRAPHY OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE THEORY

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 February 2020

Abstract

There are three different interpretations of Adam Smith’s trade theory in modern literature: first, the neoclassical theory of absolute advantage; second, an interpretation based on increasing returns; third, an interpretation of uneven development. These interpretations come to widely different conclusions, especially considering the development of the pattern of trade in Smith’s theory. I discuss how these three interpretations emerged. They do not stem from a more detailed analysis of Smith’s works itself but reflect changes within international trade theory. They all result from the fact that economists have imposed nineteenth- and twentieth-century modes of thoughts on Smith’s theory, forcing his writings into later-developed theoretical frameworks. In contrast to classical economists in the nineteenth century, these subsequent interpretations misrepresent Smith’s trade theory in order to portray him as a forerunner of later theories. The differing interpretations can thus be explained only against the backdrop of the development of international trade theory.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The History of Economics Society 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Department for Economic and Social Services, University of Potsdam, Germany; email: [email protected]. I would like to thank Maria Pia Paganelli, Craufurd Goodwin, Anja Mücke, the participants of the CHOPE Seminar at Duke University in November 2014, two anonymous referees, as well as Stephen Meardon and Jimena Hurtado as editors of this journal, whose comments were very helpful while writing this article.

References

REFERENCES

Alam, M. Shahid. 2000. Poverty from the Wealth of Nations: Integration and Polarization in the Global Economy since 1760. Basingstoke: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alam, M. Shahid. 2016. “Commodities in Economics: Loving or Hating Complexity.” Economic Thought 5 (1): 118.Google Scholar
Anderson, James E. 2011. “The Gravity Model.” Annual Review of Economics 3: 133160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angas, Lawrence L. B. 1935. The Problems of the Foreign Exchanges. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Angell, James W. 1926. The Theory of International Prices: History, Criticism and Restatement. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
, Kenneth J. 1979. “The Division of Labor in the Economy, the Polity, and Society.” In O’Driscoll, Gerald P., ed., Adam Smith and Modern Political Economy: Bicentennial Essays on the Wealth of Nations. Ames: The Iowa State University Press, pp. 153164.Google Scholar
Bastable, Charles F. 1897. The Theory of International Trade: With Some of Its Applications to Economic Policy. Second edition. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bastable, Charles F. 1899. The Commerce of Nations. Second edition. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Batchelder, Alan B., and Haitani, Kanji. 1981. International Economics: Theory and Practice. Columbus: Grid.Google Scholar
Bickel, Wilhelm. 1926. Die Ökonomische Begründung der Freihandelspolitik: Eine Dogmenhistorische Untersuchung. Zürich: Girsberger.Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 2007. “The Fundamental Theorems of Modern Welfare Economics, Historically Contemplated.” History of Political Economy 39 (2): 185207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blecker, Robert A. 1997. “The ‘Unnatural and Retrograde Order’: Adam Smith’s Theories of Trade and Development Reconsidered.” Economica 64 (255): 527537.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloomfield, Arthur I. 1975. “Adam Smith and the Theory of International Trade.” In Skinner, Andrew S. and Wilson, Thomas, eds., Essays on Adam Smith. Oxford: Clarendon Press, pp. 455481.Google Scholar
Brown, Harry Gunnison. 1914. International Trade and Exchange: A Study of the Mechanism and Advantages of Commerce. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., and Yoon, Yong J.. 2000. “A Smithean Perspective on Increasing Returns.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22 (1): 4348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M., and Yoon, Yong J.. 2002. “Globalization as Framed by the Two Logics of Trade.” The Independent Review 6 (3): 399405.Google Scholar
Bye, Raymond T. 1924. Principles of Economics. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Bye, Raymond T., and Hewett, William W.. 1928. Applied Economics: The Application of Economic Principles to the Problems of Economic Life. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Cairnes, John E. 1874. Some Leading Principles of Political Economy Newly Expounded. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Cannan, Edwin. 1894. A History of the Theories of Production and Distribution in English Political Economy from 1776 to 1848. London: Rivington, Percival & Co.Google Scholar
Cannan, Edwin. 1902. “The Practical Utilty of Economic Science.” The Economic Journal 12 (48): 459471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cannan, Edwin. 1929. A Review of Economic Theory. London: P. S. King and Son.Google Scholar
Carbaugh, Robert J. 2013. International Economics. Fourteenth edition. Mason: South-Western Cengage Learning.Google Scholar
Carver, Thomas Nixon, and Carmichael, Maude. 1929. Elementary Economics. Revised edition. Boston: Ginn.Google Scholar
Chacholiades, Miltiades. 1973. The Pure Theory of International Trade. Chicago: Aldine.Google Scholar
Chacholiades, Miltiades. 1981. Principles of International Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Chandra, Ramesh. 2004. “Adam Smith, Allyn Young, and the Division of Labor.” Journal of Economic Issues 38 (3): 787805.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cherunilam, Francis. 2008. International Economics. Fifth edition. New Delhi: Tata McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Chipman, John S. 1965. “A Survey of the Theory of International Trade: Part 2, The Neo-Classical Theory.” Econometrica 33 (4): 685760.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clay, Henry. 1918. Economics: An Introduction for the General Reader. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Darity, William A. Jr., and Davis, Lewis S.. 2005. “Growth, Trade and Uneven Development.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 29 (1): 141170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deibler, Frederick S. 1929. Principles of Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Eicher, Theo S., Mutti, John H., and Turnovsky, Michelle H.. 2009. International Economics. Seventh edition. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elmslie, Bruce. 1994. “Positive Feedback Mechanisms in Adam Smith’s Theories of International Trade.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 1 (2): 253271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elmslie, Bruce. 2018. “Adam Smith’s Discovery of Trade Gravity.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 32 (2): 209222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elmslie, Bruce, and James, Antoinette M.. 1993. “The Renaissance of Adam Smith in Modern Theories of International Trade.” In Hébert, Robert F., ed., Perspectives on the History of Economic Thought. Volume IX: Themes on Economic Discourse, Method, Money and Trade. Aldershot: Elgar, pp. 6376.Google Scholar
Eltis, Walter. 1988. “The Contrasting Theories of Industrialization of François Quesnay and Adam Smith.” Oxford Economic Papers 40 (2): 269288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eltis, Walter. 2004. “Emma Rothschild on Economic Sentiments: And the True Adam Smith.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 11 (1): 147159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ely, Richard T., Adams, Thomas S., Lorenz, Max O., and Young, Allyn A.. 1916. Outlines of Economics. Third edition. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Eßlen, Joseph B. 1925. Die Politik des Auswärtigen Handels: Ein Lehrbuch. Stuttgart: Enke.Google Scholar
Eulenburg, Franz. 1929. Außenhandel und Außenhandelspolitik: Die Internationalen Wirtschaftsbeziehungen. Tübingen: Mohr.Google Scholar
Garver, Frederic B., and Hansen, Alvin Harvey. 1928. Principles of Economics. Boston: Ginn.Google Scholar
Gide, Charles. 1904. Principles of Political Economy. Second American edition. Boston: Heath.Google Scholar
Gide, Charles, and Rist, Charles. [1915] 2000. A History of Economic Doctrines: From the Time of the Physiocrats to the Present Day. Edited by Backhouse, Roger E.. Second edition. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Gomes, Leonard. 1987. Foreign Trade and the National Economy: Mercantilist and Classical Perspectives. Basingstoke: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goode, Walter. 2007. Dictionary of Trade Policy Terms. Fifth edition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griffin, Clare E. 1924. Principles of Foreign Trade. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Haberler, Gottfried. [1933] 1950. The Theory of International Trade with its Applications to Commercial Policy. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Harpham, Edward J. 1984. “Liberalism, Civic Humanism, and the Case of Adam Smith.” American Political Science Review 78 (3): 764774.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, Seymour E. 1957. International and Interregional Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Harrod, Roy F. 1933. International Economics. London: Nisbet.Google Scholar
Ho, P. Sai-wing. 1996. “Rethinking Classical Trade Analyses Within a Framework of Capitalist Development.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 20 (4): 413432.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ho, P. Sai-wing. 2016. “Linking the Insights of Smith, Marx, Young and Hirschman on the Division of Labour: Implications for Economic Integration and Uneven Development.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 40 (3): 913939.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobson, John A. 1904. International Trade: An Application of Economic Theory. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Hodgskin, Thomas. 1827. “Popular Political Economy: Four Lectures Delivered at the London Mechanics’ Institution.” London: S. and R. Bentley. http://galenet.galegroup.com/servlet/MOME?af=RN&ae=U104674826&srchtp=a&ste=14. Accessed February 8, 2016.Google Scholar
Hollander, Samuel. 1973. The Economics of Adam Smith. London: Heinemann.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hong, Wontack. 1984. “A Note on Adam Smith and International Trade.” Korean Economic Journal 23 (2): 195202.Google Scholar
Horn, Paul V. 1935. International Trade: Principles and Practices. New York: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Imbs, Jean, and Wacziarg, Romain. 2003. “Stages of Diversification.” American Economic Review 93 (1): 6386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ingram, James C., and Dunn, Robert M.. 1993. International Economics. Third edition. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Kaldor, Nicholas. 1978. “The Nemesis of Free Trade.” In Collected Economic Essays. Volume VI: Further Essays on Applied Economics. London: Duckworth, pp. 234241.Google Scholar
Kibritçioglu, Aykut. 2002. “On the Smithian Origins of ‘New’ Trade and Growth Theories.” Economics Bulletin 2 (1): 115.Google Scholar
Kidd, Howard C. 1921. Kidd on Foreign Trade. Second edition. New York: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Killough, Hugh B. 1938. International Trade. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Kobatsch, Rudolf. 1907. Internationale Wirtschaftspolitik: Ein Versuch Ihrer Wissenschaftlichen Erklärung auf Entwicklungsgeschichtlicher Grundlage. Wien: Manz.Google Scholar
Koo, Wŏn-hoe, and Kennedy, Philip Lynn. 2005. International Trade and Agriculture. Malden: Blackwell.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, Paul R. 1990. Rethinking International Trade. Cambridge: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laveleye, Émile de. 1884. The Elements of Political Economy. New York: G. P. Putnam’s Sons.Google Scholar
Litman, Simon. 1923. Essentials of International Trade. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Lutz, Harley L., Foote, Edmund W., and Stanton, Benjamin F.. 1933. A New Introduction to Economics. Evanston: Row, Peterson and Co.Google Scholar
Magee, James Dysart. 1922. Introduction to Economic Problems. New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons.Google Scholar
Maneschi, Andrea. 1998. Comparative Advantage in International Trade: A Historical Perspective. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Marrewijk, Charles Van. 2009. “Absolute Advantage.” In Reinert, Kenneth A. and Rajan, Ramkishen S., eds., The Princeton Encyclopedia of the World Economy. Volume I. Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 13.Google Scholar
McCulloch, John Ramsay. 1825. The Principles of Political Economy: With a Sketch of the Rise and Progress of the Science. Edinburgh: Tait.Google Scholar
McCulloch, John Ramsay. 1833. "On Commerce." London: Baldwin and Cradock. http://galenet.galegroup.com/servlet/MOME?af=RN&ae=U104857266&srchtp=a&ste=14. Accessed April 3, 2016.Google Scholar
McNally, David. 1988. Political Economy and the Rise of Capitalism: A Reinterpretation. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Meek, Ronald L. 1954. “Adam Smith and the Classical Concept of Profit.” Scottish Journal of Political Economy 1 (2): 138153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mehmet, Ozay. 1999. Westernizing the Third World: The Eurocentricity of Economic Development Theories. Second edition. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milberg, William, and Elmslie, Bruce. 1993. “The Advantages of Relative Backwardness: An Input-Output Approach.” In Rima, Ingrid H., ed., The Political Economy of Global Restructuring. Aldershot: Edward Elgar, pp. 3756.Google Scholar
Mill, James. [1807] 2006. “Commerce Defended.” In Winch, Donald, ed., James Mill: Selected Economic Writings. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers, pp. 85159.Google Scholar
Mill, James. [1821] 2006. “Elements of Political Economy.” In Winch, Donald, ed., James Mill: Selected Economic Writings. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers, pp. 203366.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. [1848] 1965. Principles of Political Economy: With Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy. Edited by Robson, John M.. In Collected Works of John Stuart Mill. Volumes 2–3. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Moon, Bruce E. 2001. “Absolute Advantage.” In Jones, R. J. Barry, ed., Routledge Encyclopedia of International Political Economy. Volume 1: Entries A–F. London: Routledge, p. 1.Google Scholar
Morales Meoqui, Jorge. 2014. “Reconciling Ricardo’s Comparative Advantage with Smith’s Productivity Theory.” Economic Thought 3 (2): 2137.Google Scholar
Myint, Hla. 1958. “The ‘Classical Theory’ of International Trade and the Underdeveloped Countries.” The Economic Journal 68 (270): 317337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myint, Hla. 1977. “Adam Smith’s Theory of International Trade in the Perspective of Economic Development.” Economica 44 (175): 231248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Negishi, Takashi. 1985. Economic Theories in a Non-Walrasian Tradition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Negishi, Takashi. 1989. History of Economic Theory. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Negishi, Takashi. 2004. “Adam Smith and Disequilibrium Economic Theory.” The Adam Smith Review 1: 3039.Google Scholar
O’Brien, Denis P. 1975. The Classical Economists. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Paganelli, Maria Pia, and Schumacher, Reinhard. 2019. “Do Not Take Peace for Granted: Adam Smith’s Warning on the Relation between Commerce and War.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 43 (3): 785797.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peng, Mike W. 2011. Global Business. Second edition. Mason: South-Western Cengage Learning.Google Scholar
Pomfret, Richard. 1986. “On the Division of Labour and International Trade: Or, Adam Smith’s Explanation of Intra-Industry Trade.” Journal of Economic Studies 13 (4): 5663.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Power, Simon. 1987. “The Origins of the Heckscher–Ohlin Concept.” History of Political Economy 19 (2): 289298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prendergast, Renee. 2010. “Accumulation of Knowledge and Accumulation of Capital in Early ‘Theories’ of Growth and Development.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 34 (3): 413431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Price, Langford L. 1902. “Free Trade and Protection.” The Economic Journal 12 (47): 305319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pugel, Thomas A. 2004. International Economics. Twelfth edition. Boston: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Rae, John. 1895. Life of Adam Smith. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Rashid, Salim. 1998. The Myth of Adam Smith. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Rassekh, Farhad. 1998. “The Convergence Hypothesis: History, Theory, and Evidence.” Open Economies Review 9: 85105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rassekh, Farhad. 2015. “Comparative Advantage in Smith’s Wealth of Nations and Ricardo’s Principles: A Brief History of its Early Development.” History of Economic Ideas 23 (1): 5975.Google Scholar
Ricardo, David. [1817] 2004. “On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation.” In Sraffa, Piero, ed., The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo. Volume I. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Roesler, Hermann. 1864. “Zur Lehre von der internationalen Arbeitstheilung.” Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 20 (2): 276319.Google Scholar
Rothbard, Murray N. 1995. Economic Thought Before Adam Smith: An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought. Volume 1. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Rothschild, Emma, and Sen, Amartya. 2006. “Adam Smith’s Economics.” In Haakonssen, Knud, ed., The Cambridge Companion to Adam Smith. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 319365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Donald, ed. 2013. Routledge Dictionary of Economics. Third edition. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salvatore, Dominick. 1987. International Economics. Second edition. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1949. “International Factor-Price Equalisation Once Again.” The Economic Journal 59 (234): 181197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1969. “The Way of an Economist.” In Samuelson, Paul A., ed., International Economic Relations: Proceedings of The Third Congress of the International Economic Association. London: Macmillan, pp. 111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1987. “Out of the Closet: A Program For the Whig History of Economic Science.” History of Economics Society Bulletin 9 (1): 5160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Santos, Raul Cristovão dos. 1998. “Smith’s Glasgow Lectures: A Foundation or an Obstacle for the Wealth of Nations?Estudos econômicos 28 (3): 475489.Google Scholar
Sapsford, David. 2008. “Smith, Ricardo and the World Marketplace, 1776–2007: Back to the Future?” In Desai, Vandan and Potter, Robert B., eds., The Companion to Development Studies. London: Hodder Education, pp. 7581.Google Scholar
Schabas, Margaret. 1992. “Breaking Aaway: History of Economics as History of Science.” History of Political Economy 24 (1): 187203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumacher, Reinhard. 2012. “Adam Smith’s Theory of Absolute Advantage and the Use of Doxography in the History of Economics.” Erasmus Journal for Philosophy and Economics 5 (2): 5480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumacher, Reinhard. 2013. “Deconstructing the Theory of Comparative Advantage.” World Economic Review 2: 83105.Google Scholar
Schumacher, Reinhard. 2015. “Adam Smith’s ‘Two Distinct Benefits’ from Trade: The Dead End of ‘Vent-for-Surplus’ Interpretations.” History of Political Economy 47 (4): 577603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumacher, Reinhard. 2016. “Adam Smith and the ‘Rich Country–Poor Country’ Debate: Eighteenth-Century Views on Economic Progress and International Trade.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 23 (5): 764793.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumacher, Reinhard. 2018. “Adam Smith, the Patterns of Foreign Trade and the Division of Labour: A Country as a Jack-of-All-Trades Rather Than a Specialist.” The Adam Smith Review 10: 421.Google Scholar
Seager, Henry Rogers. 1913. Principles of Economics. London: G. Bell and Sons.Google Scholar
Senior, Nassau W. 1836. An Outline of the Science of Political Economy. London: Clowes and Sons.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. [1762] 1978. Early Draft of Part of the Wealth of Nations [ED]. Edited by Meek, Ronald L., Raphael, D. D., and Stein, Peter. The Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith. Volume 5. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. [1762–1766] 1978. Lectures on Jurisprudence [LJ]. Edited by Meek, Ronald L., Raphael, D. D., and Stein, Peter. The Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith. Volume 5. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. [1776] 1976. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations [WN]. Edited by Campbell, R. H. and Skinner, A. S.. The Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith. Volumes 2a–2b. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Södersten, Bo. 1970. International Economics. New York: Harper & Row.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spann, Othmar. 1922. Die Haupttheorien der Volkswirtschaftslehre auf Dogmengeschichtlicher Grundlage. Eleventh edition. Leipzig: Quelle und Meyer.Google Scholar
Spengler, Joseph J. 1959. “Adam Smith’s Theory of Economic Growth: Part I.” Southern Economic Journal 25 (4): 397415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Surányi-Unger, Theo. 1923. Philosophie in der Volkswirtschaftslehre: Ein Beitrag zur Geschichte der Volkswirtschaftslehre. Volume 1. Jena: Fischer.Google Scholar
Syme, James. 1821. "The Principles of Political Economy Applied to the Financial State of Great Britain Anno Domini 1821." London: Printed for J.M. Richardson. http://galenet.galegroup.com/servlet/MOME?af=RN&ae=U104395583&srchtp=a&ste=14. Accessed March 5, 2016.Google Scholar
Taussig, Frank W. 1911. Principles of Economics. Volume 1. New York: Mamillan.Google Scholar
Thompson, Chales Manfred. 1928. Principles and Practices of Economics: An Introductory Course. Chicago: Benj. H. Sanborn.Google Scholar
Torrens, Robert. 1808. The Economists Refuted; Or, An Inquiry into the Nature and Extent of the Advantages Derived from Trade. London: S. A. Oddy.Google Scholar
Torrens, Robert. 1821. An Essay on the Production of Wealth with an Appendix, in which the Principles of Political Economy are Applied to the Actual Circumstances of this Country. London: Printed for Longman, Hurst, Rees, Orme, and Brown.Google Scholar
Tribe, Keith. 2006. “Reading Trade in the Wealth of Nations.” History of European Ideas 32 (1): 5879.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsoulfidis, Lefteris, and Paitaridis, Dimitris. 2012. “Revisiting Adam Smith’s Theory of the Falling Rate of Profit.” International Journal of Social Economics 39 (5): 304313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tucker, Graham Shardalow Lee. 1960. Progress and Profits in British Economic Thought 1650–1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Verdera, Francisco. 1992. “Adam Smith on the Falling Rate of Profit: A Reappraisal.” Scottish Journal of Political Economy 39 (1): 100110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viner, Jacob. 1927. “Adam Smith and Laissez Faire.” Journal of Political Economy 35 (2): 198232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viner, Jacob. 1932. “The Doctrine of Comparative Costs.” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 36: 356414.Google Scholar
Viner, Jacob. 1937. Studies in the Theory of International Trade. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Wasserman, Max J., and Hultman, Charles W.. 1962. Modern International Economics: A Balance of Payments Approach. New York: Simmons-Boardman.Google Scholar
Weintraub, E. Roy. 2016. “Paul Samuelson’s Historiography: More Wag Than Whig.” History of Political Economy 48 (2): 349363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wells, Sidney J. 1969. International Economics: A General Textbook. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Wexler, Imanuel. 1968. Fundamentals of International Economics. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Whale, Barrett. 1932. International Trade. London: Thornton Butterworth.Google Scholar
Williams, John H. 1929. “The Theory of International Trade Reconsidered.” The Economic Journal 39 (154): 195209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, John. 1983. The Open Economy and the World Economy: A Textbook in International Economics. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Wilson, Peter. 1986. International Economics: Theory, Evidence, and Practice. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.Google Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1978. Adam Smith’s Politics: An Essay in Historiographic Revision. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1996. Riches and Poverty: An Intellectual History of Political Economy in Britain, 1750–1834. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Yarbrough, Beth V., and Yarbrough, Robert M.. 2006. The World Economy: Trade and Finance. Seventh edition. Mason: Thomson/South-Western.Google Scholar
Young, Allyn A. 1928. “Increasing Returns and Economic Progress.” The Economic Journal 38 (152): 527542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, John P. 1938. International Trade and Finance. New York: Ronald Press.Google Scholar
Zhang, Wei-Bin. 2008. International Trade Theory: Capital, Knowledge, Economic Structure, Money, and Prices over Time. Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar