Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T18:27:39.146Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Sexual Division of Labor in Adam Smith's Work

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Sumitra Shah
Affiliation:
Division of Administration and Economics, St. John's University, Jamaica, NY 11439.

Extract

It is a fact universally acknowledged that a woman's work is never done and often not counted. It is a fact equally universally acknowledged that most people in the economics profession are not terribly interested in such a fact. It is my purpose to explore this lack of interest by tracing it to the place of sexual division of labor in Adam Smith's work.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2006

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Bodkin, R. G. (1999) Women's Agency in Classical Economic Thought: Adam Smith, Harriet Taylor Mill and J. S. Mill, Feminist Economics, 5 (1), pp. 4560.Google Scholar
Boulding, K. E. (1986) What Went Wrong with Economics, American Economist, 30 (1), pp. 512.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
England, P. (1993) The Separative Self: Androcentric Bias in Neoclassical Assumptions, in: Ferber, Marianne A. and Nelson, Julie A. (Eds) Beyond Economic Man (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 3753.Google Scholar
Ferber, A. M. and Nelson, J. A. (1993) Introduction, in: Ferber, M. A. and Nelson, J. A. (Eds) Beyond Economic Man (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 122.Google Scholar
Folbre, N. (1988) The Black Four of Hearts: Toward a New Paradigm in Household Economics, in: Dwyer, D. and Bruce, J. (Eds) A Home Divided (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press), pp. 249–89.Google Scholar
Folbre, N. (1993) “The Improper Arts”: Sex in Classical Political Economy, Population and Development Review, 18 (1), pp. 105–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Groenewegen, P. (1987) Division of Labor, in: Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. and Newman, P. (Eds) The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (New York: Stockton Press), pp. 901907.Google Scholar
Heilbroner, R. (1986) The Essential Adam Smith (New York: W. W. Norton & Company).Google Scholar
Henderson, W. and Samuels, W. J. (2003) The Etiology of Adam Smith's Division of Labor: Alternative Accounts and Smith's Methodology Applied to Them, paper presented at the annual conference of History of Economics Society, Duke University, Durham, NC.Google Scholar
Hodgskin, T. (1827) Popular Political Economy: Four Lectures (London: Charles Tate).Google Scholar
Hunt, E. K. (1979) History of Economic Thought: A Critical Perspective (Belmont, CA: Wadsworth).Google Scholar
Ingram, J. K. (1888) A History of Political Economy, McMaster Archives, html at socserv2.mcmaster.caGoogle Scholar
Justman, S. (1993) The Autonomous Male in Adam Smith (Norman, OK and London: University of Oklahoma Press).Google Scholar
Keynes, J. N. (1973) The Scope and Method of Political Economy (Clifton, NJ: A. M. Kelley).Google Scholar
Kuiper, E. (2001) “The Most Valuable of All Capital”: A Gender Reading of Economic Texts (Amsterdam: Universiteit van Amsterdam).Google Scholar
Kuiper, E. (2003) The Construction of Masculine Identity in Adam Smith's Theory of Moral Sentiments, in: Barker, D. and Kuiper, E. (Eds) Toward a Feminist Philosophy of Economics (New York: Routledge), pp. 145–60.Google Scholar
Lerner, M. (1937) Introduction to Adam Smith's The Wealth of Nations (New York: The Modern Library).Google Scholar
Leslie, T. E. C. (1870) The Political Economy of Adam Smith, Fortnightly Review, McMaster Archives: html at socserv2.mcmaster.ca.Google Scholar
Lewis, T. J. (2000) Persuasion, Dominance and Exchange: Adam Smith on the Political Consequences of Markets, Canadian Journal of Political Science, 33 (2), pp. 273289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myers, M. (1983) The Soul of Modern Economic Man: Ideas of Self-interest, Thomas Hobbs to Adam Smith (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Nelson, J. A. (1993) The Study of Choice or the Study of Provisioning? Gender and the Definition of Economics, in: Ferber, M. A. and Nelson, J. A. (Eds) Beyond Economic Man (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press), pp. 2336.Google Scholar
Nelson, J. A. (2002) Feminism and the Economics of Deception: An Examination of Adam Smith's “Spirit of System,” in: Gerschlager, C. and Mokre, M. (Eds) Exchange and Deception: A Feminist Perspective (Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers), pp. 4354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nyland, C. (1993) Adam Smith, Stage Theory and the Status of Women, History of Political Economy, 25 (4), pp. 617–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pocock, J. G. A. (1983) Cambridge Paradigms and Scotch Philosophers: A Study of the Relationship Between the Civic Humanist and the Civic Jurisprudential Interpretations of Eighteenth Century Social Thought, in: Hont, I., and Ignatieff, M. (Eds) Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), pp. 235–52.Google Scholar
Pujol, M. A. (1992) Feminism and Anti-Feminism in Early Economic Thought. (Aldershot U. K. and Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar).Google Scholar
Pujol, M. (2003) Into the Margin, in: Kuiper, E. and Sap, J. et al. (Eds) Out of the Margin: Feminist Perspectives on Economics (London and New York: Routledge), pp. 1734.Google Scholar
Redman, D. A. (1997) The Rise of Political Economy as a Science (Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rendall, J. (1987) Virtue and Commerce: Women in the Making of Adam Smith's Political Economy, in: Kennedy, E. and Mendus, S. (Eds) Women in Western Political Philosophy: Kant to Nietzsche (New York, NY: St. Martin's Press), pp. 4477.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. (1954) History of Economic Analysis (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Skinner, A. S. (1999) The Wealth of Nations, Books 1–111 (London: Penguin Books).Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1759) The Theory of Moral Sentiments (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1976).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Adam (17621763) Lectures on Rhetoric and Belles Letters, Glasgow edition, The Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, Vol. 3 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1983).Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1766) Lectures on Jurisprudence (Oxford: The Clarendon Press, 1978).Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1776) The Wealth of Nations (New York: The Modern Library, 1937).Google Scholar
Staveren, I. V. (2001) Caring Economy (London: Routledge).Google Scholar
Steuart, Sir J. (1767) An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Economy (London: The Scottish Economic Society, 1966).Google Scholar
Tribe, K. (1999) Adam Smith: Critical Theorist? Journal of Economic Literature, XXXVII (06), pp. 609–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, T. (1899) The Theory of the Leisure Class (New York: Penguin Books, 1979).Google Scholar
Veblen, T. (18981899) The Barbarian Status of Women, American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 4, McMaster Archives.Google Scholar
Waring, M. (1988) If Women Counted (San Francisco: Harper & Row).Google Scholar
West, E. G. (1964) Adam Smith's Two Views on the Division of Labor, Economica, 31 (121), pp. 2332.Google Scholar