Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-4rdpn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T05:22:02.578Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A RECONSIDERATION OF THE DOCTRINAL FOUNDATIONS OF MONETARY POLICY RULES: FISHER VERSUS CHICAGO

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 February 2021

George S. Tavlas*
Affiliation:
Bank of Greece and the Hoover Institution, Stanford University.
*
Correspondence may be addressed to George Tavlas, Bank of Greece, 21 E Venizelos Ave, Athens, 10250, Greece, Tel. no. +30 210 320 2370; Fax. no. +30 210 320 2432. Email address: [email protected].

Abstract

There has long been a presumption that the price-level stabilization frameworks of Irving Fisher and Chicagoans Henry Simons and Lloyd Mints were essentially equivalent. I show that there were subtle, but important, differences in the rationales underlying the policies of Fisher and the Chicagoans. Fisher’s framework involved substantial discretion in the setting of the policy instruments; for the Chicagoans the objective of a policy rule was to tie the hands of the authorities in order to reduce discretion and, thus, monetary policy uncertainty. In contrast to Fisher, the Chicagoans provided assessments of the workings of alternative rules, assessed various criteria—including simplicity and reduction of political pressures—in the specification of rules, and concluded that rules would provide superior performance compared with discretion. Each of these characteristics provided a direct link to the rules-based framework of Milton Friedman. Like Friedman’s framework, Simons’s preferred rule targeted a policy instrument.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The History of Economics Society, 2021

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

For encouragement and inspiration, I am grateful to Thomas Humphrey. I thank the editor, Pedro Duarte, and two referees, for constructive comments. I also thank Harris Dellas, Samuel Demeulemeester, Ed Nelson, John Taylor, Richard Timberlake, and Michael Ulan for many helpful suggestions. I also thank Elisavet Bosdelekidou and Maria Monopoli for research assistance.

References

REFERENCES

Asso, Pier F., and Leeson, Robert. 2012. “Monetary Policy Rules: From Adam Smith to John Taylor.” In Koenig, E., Leeson, R., and Kahn, G., eds., The Taylor Rule and the Transformation of Monetary Policy. Stanford: Hoover Institution Press, pp. 362.Google Scholar
Barber, William J. 1998. “Irving Fisher as a Policy Advocate.” In Rutherford, M., ed., The Economic Mind in America: Essays in the History of American Economics. London: Routledge, pp. 3142.Google Scholar
Barber, William J.. 1999. “Irving Fisher (1867–1947): Career Highlights and Formative Influences.” In Loef, Hans-E. and Monissen, Hans G., eds., The Economics of Irving Fisher. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, pp. 321.Google Scholar
Barber, William, Tobin, James, Dimand, Robert W., and Foster, Kevin. 1997. The Works of Irving Fisher. Volume 11. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Bordo, Michael D. 2019. “Rules versus Discretion: A Perennial Theme in Monetary Economics.” In Bordo, Michael, ed., The Historical Performance of the Federal Reserve: The Importance of Rules. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press, pp. 327.Google Scholar
Bordo, Michael D., and Rockoff, Hugh. 2013. “The Influence of Irving Fisher on Milton Friedman’s Monetary Economics.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 35 (2): 153177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunner, Karl. 1980. “The Control of Monetary Aggregates.” In Controlling Monetary Aggregates III. Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, pp. 165.Google Scholar
Cagan, Phillip. 1978. “Monetarism in Historical Perspective.” In Mayer, T. Thomas, ed., The Structure of Monetarism. New York: W.W. Norton, pp. 8593.Google Scholar
Dellas, Harris, and Tavlas, George S.. 2019. “The Dog that Didn’t Bark: The Curious Case of Lloyd Mints, Milton Friedman and the Transformation of the Chicago Quantity-Theory Tradition.” CEPR Discussion Paper 13858, July. Forthcoming in History of Political Economy.Google Scholar
Dimand, Robert W. 1993. “The Dance of the Dollar: Irving Fisher’s Monetary Theory of Economic Fluctuations.” History of Economics Review 20 (1): 161172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimand, Robert W.. 1998. “The Fall and Rise of Irving Fisher’s Macroeconomics.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 20: 191201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimand, Robert W.. 1999a. “Irving Fisher’s Macroeconomics.” In Loef, Hans-E. and Monissen, Hans G., eds., The Economics of Irving Fisher. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, pp. 3558.Google Scholar
Dimand, Robert W.. 1999b. “Irving Fisher and the Fisher Relation: Setting the Record Straight.” Canadian Journal of Economics 32 (3): 744750.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Director, Aaron. 1948. “Prefatory Note.” In Simons, Henry C., Economic Policy for a Free Society. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, pp. vvii.Google Scholar
Dorn, James A. 2018. “Monetary Policy in an Uncertain World: The Case for Rules.” In Dorn, James A., ed., Monetary Policy in an Uncertain World: Ten Years after the Crisis. Washington, DC: The Cato Institute, pp. 179206.Google Scholar
Douglas, Paul H. 1927. “The Modern Technique of Mass Production and Its Relation to Wages.” Proceedings of the Academy of Political Science 12 (July): 17–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Douglas, Paul H., and Director, Aaron. 1931. The Problem of Unemployment. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Fischer, Stanley.1990. “Rules Versus Discretion in Monetary Policy.” In Friedman, Benjamin M. and Hahn, Frank H., eds., Handbook of Monetary Economics. Volume II. Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 11551184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1896. Appreciation and Interest. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving, with Brown, Harry G.. 1911. The Purchasing Power of Money. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving, with Brown, Harry G.. 1913a. The Purchasing Power of Money. Second edition. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1913b. “A Remedy for the Rising Cost of Living: Standardizing the Dollar.” American Economic Review 3 (1): 2028.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1919. “Stabilizing the Dollar.” American Economic Review Supplement (March): 156–160.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1920. Stabilizing the Dollar: A Plan to Stabilize the General Price Level without Fixing Individual Prices. New York: The Macmillan Company.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1922. Stabilization of Purchasing Power of Money. Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency of the House of Representatives, Sixty-seventh Congress, fourth session on H.R. 11788, to stabilize the purchasing power of money. December 18, 19, 20, and 21. Washington: U.S. G.P.O. Available at: https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/title/3940. Accessed November 20, 2020.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1928. The Money Illusion. New York: Adelphi Company.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1929. “Fisher Sees Stocks Permanently High.” New York Times, October 16, p. 8.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1932. Booms and Depressions. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1933a. “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depression.” Econometrica 1 (4): 337357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1933b. Stamp Scrip. New York: Adelphi Company.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1933c. Mastering the Crisis. New York: Adelphi Company.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving, with Cohrssen, Hans. 1934. Stable Money: A History of the Movement. New York: Adelphi Company.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1935a. 100% Money. New York: Adelphi Company.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1935b. Banking Act of 1935. Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency of the House of Representatives, Seventy-fourth Congress, first session on H.R. 5357, to provide for the sound, effective, and uninterrupted operation of the banking system, February 21 to April 8. Washington: U.S. G.P.O. Available at: https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/title/5309. Accessed November 20, 2020.Google Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1936. 100% Money. Revised second edition. New York: Adelphi Company.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1948. “A Monetary and Fiscal Framework for Economic Stability.” The American Economic Review 38 (3): 245264. Reprinted in Friedman, Milton, ed., Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953, pp. 133–156.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1951. “The Effects of a Full-Employment Policy on Economic Stability: A Formal Analysis.” Reprinted in Friedman, Milton, ed., Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953, pp. 117132 .Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1960. A Program for Monetary Stability. New York: Fordham University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1967. “The Monetary Theory and Policy of Henry Simons.” Journal of Law and Economics 10: 113. Reprinted in Friedman, Milton, ed., The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays. Chicago: Aldine, 1969, pp. 111–139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1969. “The Optimum Quantity of Money.” In The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays. Chicago: Aldine, pp. 150.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1983. “Monetarism in Rhetoric and in Practice.” Bank of Japan Monetary and Economic Studies 1: 114.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton, and Schwartz, Anna J.. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Glasner, David. 2017. “Rules versus Discretion in Monetary Policy Historically Contemplated.” Journal of Macroeconomics 54 (Part A): 2741.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris Foundation. 1931. Unemployment as a World Problem. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Humphrey, Thomas M. 1971. “Role of Non-Chicago Economists in the Evolution of the Quantity Theory in America 1930–1950.” Southern Economic Journal 38 (1): 1218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Humphrey, Thomas M.. 1990. “Fisherian and Wicksellian Price-Stabilization Models in the History of Monetary Thought.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 76 (3): 312.Google Scholar
Keynes, John M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H., Cox, Garfield, Director, Aaron, Douglas, Paul H., Hart, Albert G., Mints, Lloyd, Schultz, Henry, and Simons, Henry C.. 1933. Untitled memorandum, April.Google Scholar
Laidler, David. 1993. “Hawtrey, Harvard, and the Origins of the Chicago Tradition.” Journal of Political Economy 101 (6): 10681103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laidler, David. 1999. Fabricating the Keynesian Revolution: Studies of the Inter-War Literature on Money, the Cycle, and Unemployment. Cambridge: The Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Laidler, David. 2002. “Rules, Discretion, and Financial Crises in Classical and Neoclassical Economics.” Economic Issues 7 (2): 1134.Google Scholar
Laidler, David. 2010. “Chicago Monetary Traditions.” In Emmett, R., ed., The Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, pp. 7080.Google Scholar
Loef, Hans-E., and Monissen, Hans G.. 1999. “Irving Fisher’s Contributions to Monetary Macroeconomics.” In Loef, Hans-E. and Monissen, Hans G., eds., The Economics of Irving Fisher: Reviewing the Scientific Work of a Great Economist. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, pp. 81108.Google Scholar
Lothian, James R., and Tavlas, George S.. 2018. “How Friedman and Schwartz Became Monetarists.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 50 (4): 757787.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, Alfred. 1887. “Remedies for Fluctuations in General Prices.” Contemporary Review 51 (March): 355375.Google Scholar
McCallum, Bennett, and Nelson, Edward. 2005. “Targeting versus Instrument Rules for Monetary Policy.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 87 (5): 597611.Google Scholar
Mints, Lloyd W.. 1923a. “Open Market Borrowing to Finance the Production of Goods Sold for Future Delivery.” Journal of Political Economy 31 (1): 128138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mints, Lloyd W.. 1923b. “Expansion of Fixed and Working Capital by Open Market Borrowing.” Journal of Political Economy 31 (2): 299302.Google Scholar
Mints, Lloyd W.. 1930. “The Elasticity of Bank Notes.” Journal of Political Economy 38 (4): 458471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mints, Lloyd W.. 1945A History of Banking Theory in Great Britain and the United StatesChicagoUniversity of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Mints, Lloyd W.. 1946. “Monetary Policy.” Review of Economics and Statistics 28 (2): 6069.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mints, Lloyd W.1950Monetary Policy for a Competitive SocietyNew YorkMcGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Mints, Lloyd W.1951“Monetary Policy and Stabilization.” American Economic Review 41 (2): 188193.Google Scholar
Nelson, Edward. 2008. “Friedman and Taylor on Monetary Policy Rules: A Comparison.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review (March/April): 95116.Google Scholar
Nelson, Edward. 2020. Milton Friedman and Economic Debate in the United States, 1932–1972. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Parkin, Michael. 1986. “Essays on and in the Chicago Tradition: A Review Essay.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 18 (1): 104116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patinkin, Don. 1969. “The Chicago Tradition, the Quantity Theory, and Friedman.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 1 (1): 4670.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patinkin, Don. 1973. “On the Monetary Economics of Chicagoans and Non-Chicagoans: Comment.” Southern Economic Journal 39 (3): 454459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patinkin, Don. 1993. “Irving Fisher and His Compensated Dollar Plan.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 79 (3): 134.Google Scholar
Phillips, Ronnie J. 1995. The Chicago Plan and New Deal Banking Reform. New York: M.E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
Reeve, Joseph E. 1943. Monetary Reform Movements: A Survey of Recent Plans and Panaceas. Washington, DC: American Council on Public Affairs.Google Scholar
Simons, Henry C., et al. 1933. “Banking and Currency Reform,” including Appendix, “Banking and Business Cycles,” and Supplementary Memorandum, “Long-term Objectives of Monetary Management.” Unsigned mimeograph. Department of Economics, University of Chicago.Google Scholar
Simons, Henry C. 1934a. “New Deal Queen Jumble; Aims Conflict.” Chicago Tribune, Finance and Business Section, March 3.Google Scholar
Simons, Henry C.. 1934b. “A Positive Program for Laissez Faire: Some Proposals for a Liberal Policy.” University of Chicago, Public Policy Pamphlet. Reprinted in Simons, Henry S., ed., Economic Policy for a Free Society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1948, pp. 4077.Google Scholar
Simons, Henry C.. 1934c. Letter to Paul Douglas. October 2.Google Scholar
Simons, Henry C.. 1935. “Review of The Supply and Control of Money in the United States by Lauchlin Currie.” Journal of Political Economy 43 (4): 555558.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simons, Henry C.. 1936a. “Rules versus Authorities in Monetary Policy.” Journal of Political Economy 44 (1): 130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simons, Henry C.. 1936b. “Keynes’ Comments on Money.” The Christian Century (July 2): 1016–1017.Google Scholar
Simons, Henry C.. 1942. “Hansen on Fiscal Policy.” Journal of Political Economy 50 (2): 161196. Reprinted in Simons, Henry S., ed., Economic Policy for a Free Society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1948, pp. 184–219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simons, Henry C.. 1945. “The Beveridge Program: An Unsympathetic Interpretation.” Journal of Political Economy 53 (3): 212233. Reprinted in Simons, Henry S., ed., Economic Policy for a Free Society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1948, pp. 277–312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, Lars. 2003. “What is Wrong with Taylor Rules? Using Judgement in Monetary Policy through Targeting Rules.” Journal of Economic Literature 41 (2): 426477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavlas, George S. 1982. “Notes on Garvy, Snyder, and the Doctrinal Foundations of Monetarism.” History of Political Economy 14 (1): 89100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavlas, George S.. 1997. “Chicago, Harvard, and the Doctrinal Foundations of Monetary Economics.” Journal of Political Economy 105 (1): 153177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavlas, George S.. 2015. “In Old Chicago: Simons, Friedman and the Development of Monetary-Policy Rules.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 47 (1): 99121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavlas, George S.. 2019a. “The Group: The Making of the Chicago Monetary Tradition, 1927–36.” History of Political Economy 51 (2): 259296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavlas, George S.. 2019b. “The Intellectual Origins of the Monetarist Counter-revolution Reconsidered: How Clark Warburton Influenced Milton Friedman’s Monetary Thinking.” Oxford Economic Papers 71 (3): 645665.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavlas, George S.. 2020. “On the Controversy Over the Origins of the Chicago Plan for 100 Percent Reserves: Sorry, Frederick Soddy, it was Knight and (Most Probably) Simons!” Hoover Institution Working Paper No. 20102, March. Forthcoming in Journal of Money, Credit and Banking.Google Scholar
Taylor, John B. 1993. “Discretion Versus Policy Rules in Practice.” Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy 39: 195214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, John B.. 2017. “Rules Versus Discretion: Assessing the Debate over the Conduct of Monetary Policy.” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 24149.Google Scholar
Tobin, James. 1987. “Irving Fisher (1867–1947).” In Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., and Newman, P., eds., The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. Volume 2. London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 369376.Google Scholar
Warburton, Clark. 1953. “Rules and Implements for Monetary Policy.” Journal of Finance 8 (1): 121. Reprinted in Warburton, C., ed., Depression, Inflation, and Monetary Policy: Selected Papers, 1945–53. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1966, pp. 371–391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, Warren E. 1980. “The Effect of Real and Monetary Disturbances on the Price Level under Alternative Commodity Reserve Standards.” International Economic Review 21 (3): 673690.CrossRefGoogle Scholar