Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-29T01:02:55.186Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Economic Science Wars

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

E. Roy Weintraub
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Duke University, Durham, NC 27708-0097.

Extract

It is not news that the history of economics is disesteemed by most economists. There have been almost annual discussions at professional meetings about the institutional role of the history of economics. Indeed, a conference in 2001 documented the precarious state of the field in North America, and its even more perilous position in the United Kingdom and the Antipodes (Weintraub 2002b). With the exception of Duke University there are no longer any regularly scheduled graduate courses, let alone programs, in the history of economics at any “top” university in North America (Gayer 2002).

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Ashmore, Malcolm, Mulkay, Michael, Pinch, Trevor (1989) Health and Efficiency: A Sociology of Health Economics (Milton Keynes: Open University Press).Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E. (2004) History of Economics: Economics and Economic History in Britain, 1824–2000, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 11(1), pp. 107–27.Google Scholar
Bagioli, Mario (Ed) (1999) The Science Studies Reader (New York and London: Routledge).Google Scholar
Bird, Kai and Sherwin, Martin J. (2006) American Prometheus: The Triumph and Tragedy of J. Robert Oppenheimer (New York: Vintage Books).Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark (1962) Economic Theory in Retrospect (New York: Richard D. Irwin, Inc).Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark (1980) The Methodology of Economics (New York: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark (2001) No History of Ideas Please, We're Economists, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15 (1), pp. 145–64.Google Scholar
Brodbeck, May (Ed) (1968) Readings in the Philosophy of the Social Sciences (New York: Macmillan).Google Scholar
Conant, James B. (Ed) (1957) Harvard Case Histories in Experimental Science (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Cosell, Howard (1985) I Never Played the Game (New York: William Morrow).Google Scholar
Curtis, George W. (1861) Trumps: A Novel (New York: Harper, 1872).Google Scholar
Fleck, Ludwig (1935) Genesis and Development of a Scientific Fact (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1979).Google Scholar
Fontaine, Philippe (2002) Blood, Politics and Social Science: Richard Titmuss and the Institute of Economic Affairs, 1957–1973, Isis, 93 (3), pp. 401–34.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fuller, Steve (2000) Thomas Kuhn: A Philosophical History for Our Times (Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Gayer, Ted (2002) Graduate Studies in the History of Economic Thought, in: Weintraub, E. Roy (Ed) The Future of the History of Economics (Durham, NC: Duke University Press), pp. 3561.Google Scholar
Goodwin, Craufurd D. W. (forthcoming) The History ofthe History of Economics, in: Steven Durlaufand Lawrence Blume (Eds), The New Palgrave, Second Edition (London: Palgrave Macmillian).Google Scholar
Gross, Paul R. and Norman, Levitt (1994) Higher Superstition: The Academic Left and Its Quarrels with Science (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press).Google Scholar
Guillory, John (2002) The Sokol Affair and the History of Criticism, Critical Inquiry, 28 (2), pp. 470508.Google Scholar
Hands, D. Wade (2001) Reflection Without Rules (New York and Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Heilbroner, Robert L. (1953) The Worldly Philosophers (New York: Simon and Schuster).Google Scholar
Hempel, Carl (1965) Aspects of Scientific Explanation (New York: Free Press).Google Scholar
Hoover, Kevin D. and Siegler, Mark V. (2005) Sound and Fury: McCloskey and Significance Testing in Economics. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=860984.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hughes, Jeff (1997) Whigs, Prigs, and Politics: Problems in the Contemporary History of Science, in: Söderquist, Thomas (Ed) The Historiography of Contemporary Science and Technology (Amsterdam: Harwood Academic Publishers), pp. 1937.Google Scholar
Hutchison, Terence W. (1977) Knowledge and Ignorance in Economics (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (New York: Harcourt Brace).Google Scholar
Koyré, Alexandre (1961) La révolution astronomique: Copernic, Kepler, Borelli (Paris: Hermann).Google Scholar
Kuhn, Thomas S. (1962) The Structure of Scientific Revolutions (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996).Google Scholar
Kuhn, Thomas S. (1977) The Function of Measurement in Modern Physical Theory, in: Kuhn, Thomas S. (Ed) The Essential Tension (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Leavitt, Norman (undated) Latour at IAS? You Can Make a Better Case for Jerry Springer, http://humannature.com/articles/levitt.html. 2005.Google Scholar
Leonard, Robert (1998) Ethics and the Excluded Middle: Karl Menger and Social Science in Interwar Vienna, Isis, 89 (1), pp. 126.Google Scholar
Maskin, Eric (2004) Review of How Economics Became a Mathematical Science, Journal of Economic Literature, XLII (03), pp. 173–74.Google Scholar
Mata, Tiago (2004) Constructing Identity: The Post Keynesians and the Capital Controversies, Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 26 (2), pp. 241–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mata, Tiago (2005) Dissent and Identity in Economics: Radical Political Economics and Post Keynesian Economics, 1960–1980, Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Economic History, (London: London School of Economics).Google Scholar
Mayer, Anna K. (2000) Setting Up a Discipline: Conflicting Agendas of the Cambridge History of Science Committee, 1936–1950, Studies in History and Philosophy of Science, 31 (4), pp. 665–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayer, Anna K. (2004) Setting Up a Discipline, II: British History of Science and “The End of Ideology,” 1931–1948, Studies in History and Philosophy of Science, 35 (1), pp. 4172.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Donald N. (1986) The Rhetoric of Economics (Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press).Google Scholar
McMillen, Liz (1997) The Science Wars Flare at the Institute for Advanced Study, The Chronicle of Higher Education, (05 16), p. A13.Google Scholar
Merton, Robert (1938) Science, Technology, and Society in Seventeeth-Century England (New York: Fertig, 1967).Google Scholar
Mills, C. Wright (1959) The Sociological Imagination (New York: Grove Press, 1961).Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip (1989) More Heat Than Light (New York and Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip (2002) Machine Dreams (New York and Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip (2004a) Philosophizing with a Hammer: Reply to Binmore, Davis and Klaes, Journal of Economic Methodology, 11 (4), pp. 499513.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip (2004b) The Effortless Economy of Science (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip (2005) Email letter to E. R. Weintraub.Google Scholar
Monaghan, Peter (2003) Taking on Rational Economic Man, The Chronicle of Higher Education, (01 24), p. A12.Google Scholar
Pearson, Karl (1892) The Grammar of Science (New York: The Macmillan Co., 1911).Google Scholar
Piaget, Jean (1970) Genetic Epistemology (New York: Columbia University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Popper, Karl (1934) The Logic of Scientific Discovery (London: Hutchinson, 1959).Google Scholar
Porter, Ted M. (1992) Comment on Schabas, History of Political Economy, 24 (1), pp. 234–36.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, Alexander (1976) Microeconomic Laws: A Philosophical Analysis (Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press).Google Scholar
Rosenberg, Alexander (1992) Economics: Mathematical Politics of the Science of Diminishing Returns? (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Ross, Andrew (Ed) (1996) Science Wars (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).Google Scholar
Schabas, Margaret (1992) Breaking Away: History of Economics as History of Science, History of Political Economy, 24 (1), pp. 187203.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1954) History of Economic Analysis (New York: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Smith, Barbara Herrnstein (1997) Belief and Resistence: Dynamics of Contemporary Intellectual Controversy (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Smith, Barbara Herrnstein (2006) Scandalous Knowledge: Science, Truth and the Human (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snow, Charles Percy (1959) The Two Cultures and the Scientific Revolution (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1961).Google Scholar
Weintraub, E. Roy (2002a) How Economics Became a Mathematical Science (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).Google Scholar
Weintraub, E. Roy (Ed) (2002b) The Future of the History of Economics (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).Google Scholar
Yonay, Yuval P. (1998) The Struggle over the Soul of Economics: Institutionalist and Neoclassical Economics in America between the Wars (Princeton: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar