Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T16:23:26.109Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF EDUCATION IN POST-WAR AMERICA: NEW INSIGHTS FROM THEODORE SCHULTZ AND JOHN KENNETH GALBRAITH

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 February 2020

Abstract

Human capital theory has suffered much criticism. The filter theory of education (Arrow 1973), the theory of education as a “signal” (Spence 1973), and the theory of “screening” (Stiglitz 1975), for instance, have seriously challenged it from within mainstream economics, and heavy criticism has also come from other paradigms, with Franck Bailly (2016) recently documenting the critique from the radical school. Within this set of ideas that flourished in the post-WW II period and challenged human capital theory, John Kenneth Galbraith’s analysis of the dynamics of the education process is often neglected. In his original institutionalist and firm-based approach to the evolution of education, Galbraith placed great emphasis on the issue of the requirements of the planning system when he tackled the issue of human capital investment. More surprisingly—since he is unanimously recognized as the “founding father” of the “human capital revolution”—Theodore Schultz himself developed a substantial critique of human capital theory that shares some ground with Galbraith’s. The aim of this contribution is to provide new insights into the history of post-WW II ideas in the field of economics of education by reviewing Schultz’s and Galbraith’s respective analyses of education and highlighting their proximities. Both authors raise doubts regarding the idea that the aggregation of individual choices must be regarded as the relevant generative mechanism of the dynamic of education and the basis of the allocation of education resources. Consequently, both question the equivocal concept of student sovereignty.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The History of Economics Society 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Alexandre Chirat: Université Lumière, Lyon 2. Charlotte Le Chapelain: Université Jean Moulin, Lyon 3. Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the twenty-first annual conference of the ESHET (Anvers 2017) and at the workshop “Industrial Revolution and Human Capital in the Long Run” (Lyon 2017). We thank the participants of both meetings for their questions and remarks. We also thank two anonymous referees for their helpful comments. The usual disclaimer applies.

References

REFERENCES

Arrow, Kenneth. 1973. “Higher Education as a Filter.” Journal of Public Economics 2 (3): 193216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bailly, Franck. 2016. “The Radical School and the Economics of Education.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 38 (03): 351369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1962. “Investment in Human Capital: A Theoretical Analysis.” The Journal of Political Economy 70 (5): 949.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1964. Human Capital. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Berle, Adolf A. 1910. “Business Men and Education.” The Journal of Education 72 (24): 653654.Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1976. “The Empirical Status of Human Capital Theory: A Slightly Jaundiced Survey.” Journal of Economic Literature 14 (3): 827855.Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1992. The Methodology of Economics: Or, How Economists Explain. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre, and Passeron, Jean-Claude. 1977. Reproduction in Education, Culture and Society . Translated by Nice, R.. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert. 1975. “The Problem with Human Capital Theory—A Marxian Critique.” The American Economic Review 65 (2): 7482.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert. 1976. Schooling in Capitalist America. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert. 2002. “Schooling in Capitalist America Revisited.” Sociology of Education 75 (1): 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowman, Mary J. 1980. “On Theodore W. Schultz’s Contributions to Economics.” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 82 (1): 80107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chirat, Alexandre. 2020. “Preferences, Welfare and the Non-neutrality Thesis: A Reappraisal of Galbraith’s Challenge to Consumer Sovereignty.” European Journal of History of Economic Thought. Forthcoming.Google Scholar
Dunn, Stephen P. 2002. “The Origins of the Galbraithian System: Stephen P. Dunn in Conversation with J. K. Galbraith.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 24 (3): 347– 365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunn, Stephen P. 2011. The Economics of John Kenneth Galbraith: Introduction, Persuasion, and Rehabilitation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dunn, Stephen P., and Pressman, Steven. 2005. “The Economic Contributions of John Kenneth Galbraith.” Review of Political Economy 17 (2): 161209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunn, Stephen P. 2006. “The Lasting Economic Contributions of John Kenneth Galbraith, 1908–2006.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 29 (2): 179190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galbraith, James K. 1984. “Galbraith and the Theory of the Corporation.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 7 (1): 4360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1938. “Rational and Irrational Consumer Preference.” The Economic Journal 48 (190): 336342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1950. “Review of Production and Welfare of Agriculture by TW. Schultz.”. The American Economic Review 40 (3): 460463.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1951. “Conditions for Economic Change in Underdeveloped Countries.” Journal of Farm Economics 33 (4): 689696.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1952. American Capitalism. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1954a. “Agriculture and Competitive Structure.” Journal of Farm Economics 36 (5): 743747.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1954b. “Economic Preconceptions and the Farm Policy.” The American Economic Review 44 (1): 4052.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. [1958] 1998. The Affluent Society. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1960. Liberal Hour. London: Hamish Hamilton.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1962. Economic Development in Perspective. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. [1967] 2007. The New Industrial State. Fourth edition. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1967. “The Public Sector Is Still Starved.” Challenge 15 (3): 1821.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1970. “Economics as a System of Belief.” The American Economic Review 60 (2): 469478.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1973. “Power and the Useful Economist.” American Economic Review 63 (1): 111.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. [1979] 1984. The Nature of Mass Poverty. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1982. A Life in Our Times: Memoirs. New York: Ballantine Books.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1983a. The Voice of the Poor, Essay in Economic and Political Persuasion. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1983b. Anatomy of Power. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 1996. The Good Society. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John K. 2004. Interviews with John Kenneth Galbraith. Edited by Stanfield, J. R.. Jackson: University Press of Mississippi.Google Scholar
Gintis, Herbert. 1972. “Consumer Behavior and the Concept of Sovereignty: Explanations of Social Decay.” The American Economic Review 62 (1/2): 267278.Google Scholar
Gruchy, Allan G. 1978. “Institutional Economics: Its Influence and Prospects.” American Journal of Economics and Sociology 37 (3): 271281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. 1919. “The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory.” The American Economic Review 9 (1): 309318.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 2000. “What Is the Essence of Institutional Economics?Journal of Economic Issues 34 (2): 317329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 2001From Veblen to Galbraith: What Is the Essence of Institutional Economics?” In Keaney, Michael, ed., Economist with a Public Purpose, Essays in Honour of John Kenneth Galbraith. London: Routledge, pp. 95114.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 2002. “Frank Knight as an Institutional Economist.” In Biddle, Jeff, Davis, John, and Medema, Steven, eds., Economics Broadly Considered: Essays in Honour of Warren J. Samuels. Routledge Studies in the History of Economics. New York: Routledge, pp. 6189.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 2007. “Meanings of Methodological Individualism.” Journal of Economic Methodology 14 (2): 211226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 2014. “What Is capital? Economists and Sociologists Have Changed Its Meaning: Should It Be Changed Back?Cambridge Journal of Economics 5: 10631086.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Humbert, Marc. 2005. “With John Kenneth Galbraith: A ‘Political and Moral Philosophy’ Conception to Study Economic Activities.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 28 (1): 4764.Google Scholar
Kiker, Billy F. 1966. “The Historical Roots of the Concept of Human Capital.” The Journal of Political Economy 75 (4): 481499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leathers, Charles G., and Evans, John S.. 1993. “Thorstein Veblen and the New Industrial State.” In Wood, J., ed., Thorstein Veblen: Critical Assessments . London and New York: Routledge, pp. 138152.Google Scholar
Mincer, Jacob. 1957. “A Study of Personal Income Distribution.” PhD diss., Columbia University, New York.Google Scholar
Mincer, Jacob. 1958Investment in Human Capital and Personal Income Distribution.” The Journal of Political Economy 66 (4): 281302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, Mary S., and Rutherford, Malcolm. 1998. “American Economics: The Character of the Transformation.” History of Political Economy 30 (Supplement): 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mulligan, Casey B. 2008. “Becker, Gary S.” In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics . Second edition. London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 425433.Google Scholar
Parker, Richard. 2005. John Kenneth Galbraith: His Life. His Politics, His Economics . New York: Farrar, Straus & Giroux.Google Scholar
Pressman, Steven. 2007. “Economic Power, the State, and Post-Keynesian Economics.” International Journal of Political Economy 35 (4): 6786.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pressman, Steven. 2008. “John Kenneth Galbraith and the Post Keynesian Tradition in Economics.” Review of Political Economy 20 (4): 475489.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. [1980] 1993. “Veblen on Owners, Managers, and the Control of Industry.” In Wood, J., ed., Thorstein Veblen: Critical Assessments. London and New York: Routledge, pp. 263269.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 1981. “Veblen on Owners, Managers, and the Control of Industry: A Rejoinder.” History of Political Economy 13 (1): 156158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 2010. “Chicago Economics and Institutionalism.” In Emmett, R. B., ed., The Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 2539.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 2011. The Institutionalist Movement in American Economics, 1918–1947: Science and Social Control. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuels, Warren J. 1984. “Galbraith on Economics as a System of Professional Belief.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 7 (1): 6176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1949. Production and Welfare of Agriculture. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1953. The Economic Organization of Agriculture. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1959. “Investment in Man: An Economist’s View.” Social Service Review 33 (2): 109117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1960. “Capital Formation by Education.” The Journal of Political Economy 68 (6): 571583.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1961a. “Investment in Human Capital.” The American Economic Review 51(1): 117.Google Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1961b. “Investment in Human Capital: Reply.” The American Economic Review 51 (5): 10351039.Google Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1963. The Economic Value of Education. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1967. “The Rate of Return in Allocating Investment Resources to Education.” The Journal of Human Resources 2 (3): 293309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1968a. “Resources for Higher Education: An Economist’s View.” The Journal of Political Economy 76 (3): 327347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1968b. “Institutions and the Rising Economic Value of Man.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 50 (5): 11131122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1970a. “The Reckoning of Education as Human Capital.” In Hanson, W. Lee, ed., Education, Income, and Human Capital. NBER Book Series in Income and Wealth. Cambridge, MA: NBER, pp. 297306.Google Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1970b. “The Human Capital Approach to Education.” In Johns, R. L.et al., eds., Economic Factors Affecting the Financing of Education in the Decade Ahead. Gainsville: National Educational Finance Project, ch. 2.Google Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1971. “Education and Productivity.” Prepared for the National Commission on Productivity. US Govt. Printing Office, pp. 110.Google Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1972a. “Human Capital: Policy Issues and Research Opportunities.” In Economic Research: Retrospect and Prospect. Volume 6, Human Resources. Cambridge, MA: NBER, pp. 184.Google Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1972b. “Optimal Investment in College Instruction: Equity and Efficiency.” Journal of Political Economy 80 (3): S2S30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W.. 1979. “Review of The Nature of Mass Poverty by J. K. Galbraith.” Journal of Political Economy 87 (5): 11441146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1980. “Investment in Entrepreneurial Ability.” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics: 437448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scitovsky, Tibor. 1992. The Joyless Economy: The Psychology of Human Satisfaction . Revised edition. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Sobel, Irvin. 1983. “Human Capital and Institutional Theories of the Labor Market: Rivals or Complements?Journal of Economic Issues 16 (1): 255272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spence, Andrew M. 1973. “Job Market Signaling.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 87 (3): 355374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stanfield, John R., and Wrenn, Mary. 2005. “John Kenneth Galbraith and Original Institutional Economics.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 28 (1): 2645.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1975. “The Theory of ‘Screening,’ Education, and the Distribution of Income.” The American Economic Review 65 (3): 283300.Google Scholar
Teixeira, Pedro N. 2000. “A Portrait of the Economics of Education, 1960–1997.” History of Political Economy 32 (1): 257288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teixeira, Pedro N. 2005. “The ‘Human Capital Revolution’ in Economics.” History of Economic Ideas 13 (2): 129148.Google Scholar
Teixeira, Pedro N. 2010. “Theodore William Schultz.” In Emmett, R. B., ed., The Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 326330.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein. 1921. The Engineers and the Price System. New York: BW Huebsch.Google Scholar
Waligorski, Conrad. 2006. John Kenneth Galbraith: The Economist as Political Theorist. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield.Google Scholar
Walker, James R. 2008. “Schultz T. W. (1902–1998).” In Durlauf, S. and Blume, L., eds., The New Palgrave Dictionnary of Economics . Second edition. London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 15.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, Burton A. 1962. “Education and Investment in Human Capital.” Journal of Political Economy 70 (5): 106123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar