Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-vdxz6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T02:08:54.208Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

BUSINESS CYCLES, GROWTH, AND ECONOMIC POLICY: SCHUMPETER AND THE GREAT DEPRESSION

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 December 2016

Muriel Dal Pont Legrand
Affiliation:
Université Cote d’Azur, CNRS, GREDEG, France. [email protected]
Harald Hagemann
Affiliation:
University of Hohenheim, Stuttgart. [email protected]

Abstract

Joseph A. Schumpeter’s theory of economic development analyzes how growth and cycle dynamics intertwine. The process of creative destruction plays an essential role in those dynamics: embodying a cleansing effect, it has a clear, beneficial impact on long-run development. For that reason, and also for some of his famous (and provocative) non-interventionist statements, Schumpeter is generally interpreted as a pure liquidationist. This paper contests this rather simplistic view and shows that Schumpeter not only expressed much more nuanced positions as far as practical economic issues were concerned, but also that his views on economic policy were rooted in his earlier contributions before the Great Depression, attesting that Schumpeter’s view on economic policy was consistent over time.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Backhouse, Roger, and Boianovsky, Mauro. Forthcoming. “Secular Stagnation: The History of a Macroeconomic Heresy.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 23 (6).Google Scholar
Boianovsky, Mauro, and Trautwein, Hans-Michael. 2010. “Schumpeter on Unemployment.” Journal of Evolutionary Economics 20 (2): 233263.Google Scholar
Clemence, Richard V., ed. [1951] 1989. Joseph A. Schumpeter. Essays on Entrepreneurs, Innovations, Business Cycles and the Evolution of Capitalism. Introduction by Richard Swedberg. New Brunswick, NJ, and Oxford, UK: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Dal Pont Legrand, Muriel, and Hagemann, Harald. 2007. “Business Cycles in Juglar and Schumpeter.” The History of Economic Thought 49 (1): 118.Google Scholar
Date, Kuniharu. 1991. “The Relation of Cycles and Trends in Schumpeter’s Model.” In Cunningham Wood, John, ed., J. A. Schumpeter: Critical Assessments. London: Taylor & Francis, pp. 349359.Google Scholar
Dockès, Pierre. 2015. “Les débats sur la stagnation séculaire dans les années 1937–1950. Hansen-Terborgh et Schumpeter-Sweezy.” Revue Economique 66 (5): 967992.Google Scholar
Garvy, George. 1943. “Kondratieff’s Theory of Long Cycles.” Review of Economic Statistics 25 (4): 203220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hagemann, Harald. 2003. “Schumpeter’s Early Contributions on Crises Theory and Business-Cycle Theory.” History of Economic Ideas XI (1): 4767.Google Scholar
Hagemann, Harald. 2008. “Schumpeter on Development.” In Shionoya, Yuichi and Nishizawa, Tamotsu, eds., Marshall and Schumpeter on Evolution: Economic Sociology of Capitalist Development. Cheltenham, UK, and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, pp. 225242.Google Scholar
Hagemann, Harald, and Landesmann, Michael. 1996. “Sombart and Economic Dynamics.” In Backhaus, Jürgen, ed., Werner Sombart (1863–1941): Social Scientist. Volume II. Marburg: Metropolis, pp. 179204.Google Scholar
Hansen, Alvin. 1938. “The Consequences of Reducing Expenditures.” Proceedings of the Academy of Political Science 17 (4): 6072.Google Scholar
Hansen, Alvin. 1939. “Economic Progress and Declining Population Growth.” The American Economic Review 29 (1): 115.Google Scholar
Heilbroner, Robert. 1980. The Wordly Philosophers. Fifth edition. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R. 1937. “Mr. Keynes and the ‘Classics’: A Suggested Interpretation.” Econometrica 5 (April): 147159.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. [1919] 1971. Economic Consequences of the Peace. Volume II of The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. London and Basingstoke: Macmillan, and Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Klausinger, Hansjörg. 1993. “Schumpeter und die Grosse Depression. Theorie-Diagnose-Politik.” Discussion Paper 78, Department of Economics, University of Hohenheim, Stuttgart.Google Scholar
Kurz, Heinz D. 2016. “Is There a ‘Ricardian Vice’? And What Is the Relationship between it and Economic Policy Ad-vice.” Journal of Evolutionary Economics 26 (5): 124.Google Scholar
Löwe, Adolf. 1930. “Lohn, Zins-Arbeitslosigkeit.” Die Arbeit 7: 425430.Google Scholar
Mensch, Gerhard. [1975] 1979. Stalemate in Technology: Innovations Overcome the Depression. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. English translation of Das technologische Patt. Innovationen überwinden die Depression. Frankfurt am Main: Umschau Verlag.Google Scholar
Potier, Jean-Pierre. 2015. “Joseph A. Schumpeter et la conjoncture économique des années 1930–1940. Dépression, stagnation ou signes avant-coureurs du déclin du capitalisme?” Revue économique 66 (5): 9811007.Google Scholar
Rostow, Walt W. 1975. “Kondratieff, Schumpeter, and Kuznets: Trend Periods Revisited.” The Journal of Economic History 35 (4): 719753.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 2015. “The Harvard Circle.” Journal of Evolutionary Economics 25 (1): 3136.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. [1911] 1934a. Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Munich and Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot. Second edition 1926. Engl. transl. as The Theory of Economic Development. An Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle, 1934. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1914–15. “Die Wellenbewegung des Wirtschaftslebens.” Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 39: 132.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1925. “Kreditkontrolle.” Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 54: 289328.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. [1926–27] 1985. “Die Arbeitslosigkeit.” In Stolper, Wolfgang F. and Seidl, Christian, eds., Joseph A. Schumpeter. Aufsätze zur Wirtschaftspolitik. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), pp. 153160.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1927a. “Sombarts dritter Band.” Schmollers Jahrbuch 51: 349369.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1927b. “The Explanation of the Business Cycle.” Economica VII (December): 286311.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1931a. “The Theory of the Business Cycle.” Keizaigaku Ronshu—The Journal of Economics 4: 132.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. [1931b; 1951] 1989. “The Present World Depression: A Tentative Diagnosis.” American Economic Review 21, Supplement (March): 179–182. Reprinted in R. V. Clemence, ed., 1951. Joseph A. Schumpeter. Essays on Entrepreneurs, Innovations, Business Cycles and the Evolution of Capitalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Re-published, with a new introduction by Richard Swedberg, 1989. New Brunswick, NJ, and Oxford, UK: Transaction Publishers, pp. 96–99.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. [1931–32a] 1985. “Dauerkrise?” In Stolper, Wolfgang F. and Seidl, Christian, eds., Joseph A. Schumpeter. Aufsätze zur Wirtschaftspolitik. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), pp. 202210.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. [1931–32b] 1985. “Kreditpolitische Krisentherapie in den USA.” In Stolper, Wolfgang F. and Seidl, Christian, eds., Joseph A. Schumpeter. Aufsätze zur Wirtschaftspolitik. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), pp. 210218.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. [1934b] 1989. “Depressions. Can We Learn from Past Experience?” In Clemence, R. V., ed., Joseph A. Schumpeter. Essays on Entrepreneurs, Innovations, Business Cycles and the Evolution of Capitalism. Introduction by Richard Swedberg. New Brunswick, NJ, and Oxford, UK: Transaction Publishers, pp. 108117.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1939. Business Cycles. A Theoretical, Historical and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process. Two volumes. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. [1941] 1991. “An Economic Interpretation of Our Time: The Lowell Lectures.” In Swedberg, R., ed., Joseph A. Schumpeter: The Economics and Sociology of Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 339400.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. [1942] 1947. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Second edition. New York and London: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1946a. “The Decade of the Twenties.” The American Economic Review 36 (2): 110.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1946b. “John Maynard Keynes 1883–1946.” The American Economic Review 36 (4): 495518.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1952. Aufsätze zur ökonomischen Theorie. Edited by Schneider, E. and Spiethoff, A.. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (P. Siebeck).Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 2000. Briefe/Letters. Selected and edited by Hedtke, U. and Swedberg, R.. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.Google Scholar
Sombart, Werner. [1927] 1987. Der moderne Kapitalismus: Historisch-systematische Darstellung des gesamteuropäischen Wirtschaftslebens von seinen Anfängen bis zur Gegenwart. Volume 3. Munich and Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot. Reprinted Munich: Deutscher Taschenbuch Verlag, 1987. (1902, two volumes; Leipsig 1916, three volumes.)Google Scholar
Stolper, Wolfgang F. 1984. “Schumpeter: Der politische Ökonom für die neunziger Jahre? Schumpeter versus Keynes oder Schumpeter und Keynes?” In Bös, D. and Stolper, H.-D., eds., Schumpeter oder Keynes? Zur Wirtschaftspolitik der neunziger Jahre. Berlin et al.: Springer, pp. 144.Google Scholar
Stolper, Wolfgang F., and Seidl, Christian, eds. 1985. Joseph A. Schumpeter. Aufsätze zur Wirtschaftspolitik. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).Google Scholar