Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-dh8gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T16:32:01.588Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

ADDRESSING THE AUDIENCE: PAUL SAMUELSON, RADICAL ECONOMICS, AND TEXTBOOK MAKING, 1967–1973

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 June 2020

Abstract

Historians of economics rarely consider textbooks as more than passive receptacles of previously validated knowledge. Therefore, their active role in shaping the discipline and its image is seldom addressed. In this paper, I study the making of Paul Samuelson’s successive editions of Economics from 1967 to 1973 as an instance of how textbooks stand at the crossroads between disciplinary knowledge, pedagogy, and larger political and societal concerns. In the mid-1960s, Economics, now at its sixth edition, was at the height of its success. Considered one cornerstone of modern economics, it was also at the center of a number of criticisms dealing with the current state of the economic discipline and its teaching in the universities. While the profession expressed its concern over the lack of relevance of economics to address the pressing issues of the day and pleaded for a new “problem-solving” approach to economic education, the late 1960s witnessed the emergence of a new generation of “radical” economists criticizing the economics orthodoxy. Their contention that mainstream theory had neglected the issues of class struggle and capitalist exploitation found a favorable echo among an increasingly politicized population. Using archival materials, I show how Samuelson, helped by his editorial team at McGraw-Hill, attempted to take into account these changes in order to ensure the continuing success of subsequent editions of his text in an increasingly competitive market. This study emphasizes Samuelson’s ambiguous attitude toward his contenders, revealing, on the one hand, his apparent openness to discussion and outsiders’ suggestions, and, on the other hand, his firm attachment to mildly liberal politics and aversion to Marxism, unchanged through revisions. It also helps refine a notion that is often invoked but never fully expounded in textbook studies: that of the audience.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The History of Economics Society 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Yann Giraud, ThEMA (UMR CNRS 8184), CY Cergy Paris Université, France. The research for this paper was funded in part by the project Labex MME-DII (ANR11-LBX-0023-01). This paper was initially presented at the History of Economics Society Conference at Université du Québec à Montréal in June 2014 and at the History of Postwar Social Science Workshop at the London School of Economics in December 2014. I want to thank the audiences at these meetings for their suggestions, as well as Jean-Baptiste Fleury for his detailed comments on a previous draft version of this paper. Thanks as well to the JHET editors and to two anonymous referees.

References

REFERENCES

Abbott, Lawrence 1967. Economics and the Modern World. Second edition. New York: Harcourt, Brace and World.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. Armen, and Allen, William R. 1964. University Economics. Belmont: Wadsworth.Google Scholar
Bach, George L. 1954. Economics: An Introduction to Analysis and Policy. New York: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Bach, George L., and Saunders, Phillip 1965. “Economic Education: Aspirations and Achievements.” American Economic Review 55 (3): 329356.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E. 2016. “A Short Note on the Place of Mainstream Economics in Samuelson’s Family Tree of Economics.” Working paper. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2783085. Accessed October 28, 2017.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E. 2017a. Founder of Modern Economics: Paul A. Samuelson. Volume 1: Becoming Samuelson, 1915–1948. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E. 2017b. “Samuelson and Kennedy: Textbook Author as Policy Adviser.” Working paper. Preliminary draft, March 2017.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E., and Cherrier, Béatrice 2019. “Paul Samuelson, Gender Bias and Discrimination.” The European Journal of The History of Economic Thought 26 (5): 10531080.10.1080/09672567.2019.1632366CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bronfenbrenner, Martin 1970. “Radical Economics in America: A 1970 Survey.” Journal of Economic Literature 8 (3): 747766.Google Scholar
Cherrier, Béatrice 2016. “How the Term ‘Mainstream Economics’ Became Mainstream: A Speculation.” Blog entry. https://beatricecherrier.wordpress.com/2016/05/23/how-the-term-mainstream-economics-became-mainstream-a-speculation/. Accessed October 28, 2018.Google Scholar
Colander, David 2012. “The Evolution of US Economics Textbooks.” In Augello, M. and Guidi, M., eds., The Economic Reader. London, UK: Routledge, pp. 324339.Google Scholar
Colander, David, Holt, Richard, and Rosser, Barkley Jr. 2004. “The Changing Face of Mainstream Economics.” Review of Political Economy 16 (4): 485499.10.1080/0953825042000256702CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, John B. 2006. “The Turn in Economics: Neoclassical Dominance to Mainstream Pluralism.” Journal of Institutional Economics 2 (1): 120.10.1017/S1744137405000263CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Vroey, Michel, and Pensieroso, Luca 2016. “The Rise of a Mainstream in Economics.” IRES Discussion Papers. http://hdl.handle.net/2078.1/178096. Accessed, July 25, 2017.Google Scholar
Edwards, Richard, Reich, Michael, and Weisskopf, Thomas 1971. The Capitalist System: A Radical Analysis of American Society. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Elzinga, Kenneth G. 1992. “The Eleven Principles of Economics.” Southern Economic Journal 58 (4): 861879.10.2307/1060226CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferguson, Charles E., and Kreps, Juanita M. 1965. Principles of Economics. Second edition. Toronto: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.Google Scholar
Fleury, Jean-Baptiste 2012. “The Evolving Notion of Relevance: An Historical Perspective to the Economics Made Fun Movement.” Journal of Economic Methodology 19 (3): 303319.10.1080/1350178X.2012.714145CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forder, James 2015. “Textbooks on the Phillips Curve.” History of Political Economy 47 (2): 207224.10.1215/00182702-2884309CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giraud, Yann 2014. “Negotiating the ‘Middle-of-the-Road’ Position: Paul Samuelson, MIT, and the Politics of Textbook Writing, 1945–55.” In “MIT and the Transformation of American Economics,” ed. Weintraub, E. Roy, supplement, History of Political Economy 46: 134152.10.1215/00182702-2716145CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giraud, Yann. 2018a. “Textbooks in the History of Recent Economics: The Case of Samuelson’s Economics.” History of Political Economy 50 (3): 579585.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giraud, Yann. 2018b. “Textbooks in the Historiography of Recent Economics.” In Düppe, Till and Weintraub, E. Roy, eds., A Contemporary Historiography of Economics. Oxon: Routledge, pp. 137154.10.4324/9781315169194-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gottesman, Aron A., Ramrattan, Lall, and Szenberg, Michael 2005. “Samuelson’s Economics: The Continuing Legacy.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 8 (2): 95104.10.1007/s12113-005-1024-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gurley, John G. 1971. “The State of Political Economics.” The American Economic Review 61 (2): 5362.Google Scholar
Harcourt, Geoffrey 1969. “Some Cambridge Controversies in the Theory of Capital.” Journal of Economic Literature 7 (2): 369405.Google Scholar
Harris, Seymour E., ed. 1947. The New Economics: Keynes’ Influence on Theory and Policy. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Klamer, Arjo 1990. “Textbook as Economic Discourse.” In Samuels, Warren J., ed., Economics as Discourse. Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 129154.10.1007/978-94-017-1377-1_5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knopf, Kenyon A., and Strauss, James H. 1960. The Teaching of Elementary Economics. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.Google Scholar
Levy, David M., and Peart, Sandra J. 2011. “Soviet Growth and American Textbooks: An Endogenous Past.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 78 (1–2): 110125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindbeck, Assar 1971. The Political Economy of the New Left: An Outsider’s View. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Linder, Marc, with the help of Sensat, Julius Jr. 1977. The Anti-Samuelson. Two volumes. New York: Urizen Books.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 1963. An Introduction to Positive Economics. London, UK: Weidenfield & Nicolson.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 1997. Macroeconomic Theory and Policy: The Selected Essays of Richard G. Lipsey. Volume 2. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G., and Steiner, Peter O. 1966. Economics. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Mata, Tiago 2004. “Constructing Identity: The Post Keynesians and the Capital Controversies.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 26 (2): 241259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mata, Tiago. 2009a. “Migrations and Boundary Work: Harvard, Radical Economists, and the Committee on Political Discrimination.” Science in Context 22 (1): 115143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mata, Tiago. 2009b. “Death of the Audience.” Blog entry. https://historyofeconomics.wordpress.com/2009/07/06/worrying-about-the-audience. Accessed October 28, 2018.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre 1985. The Rhetoric of Economics. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
McConnell, Campbell R. 1960. Economics: Principles, Problems, and Policies. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
McConnell, Campbell R. 1972. Economics. Fifth edition. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 2014. “How Textbooks Create Knowledge and Meaning: The Case of the Coase Theorem in Intermediate Microeconomics.” Working paper. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2479732. Accessed October 28, 2018.Google Scholar
Merton, Robert C., ed. 1972. The Collected Papers of Paul A. Samuelson. Volume 3. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Morgan, Mary S., and Rutherford, Malcolm, eds. 1998. “From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism.” Annual supplement to History of Political Economy 40.Google Scholar
Nelson, Robert H. 2001. Economics as Religion: From Samuelson to Chicago and Beyond. University Park, PA: The Pennsylvania State University Press.Google Scholar
Pearce, Kerry A., and Hoover, Kevin D. 1995. “After the Revolution: Paul Samuelson and the Textbook Keynesian Model.” In “New Perspectives on Keynes,” ed. Cottrell, Allin F., annual supplement to History of Political Economy 27: 183216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peterson, Wallace C., Sherman, Howard J., and McCloskey, Deirdre. 1973. “A Trio of Opinions on the Ninth Edition of Paul Samuelson’s Economics.” Challenge 16 (4): 6166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reinhold, Robert 1970. “Leader of Economic Mainstream: Paul Anthony Samuelson.” New York Times, October 27, 1970, p. 8.Google Scholar
Reynolds, Lloyd G. 1966. Economics: A General Introduction. Second edition. Homewood: R.D. Irwin.Google Scholar
Rocke, Alan J. 2010. Images and Reality: Kekulé, Kopp and the Scientific Imagination. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rowen, Hobart 1969. “Bankers Cheer Defender of Dissident Youth.” The Washington Post, November 18, 1969, p. A4.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1948. Economics: An Introductory Analysis. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1967. Economics. Seventh edition. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1970. Economics. Eighth edition. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1973. Economics. Ninth edition. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1997. “Credo of a Lucky Textbook Author.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11: 153160.10.1257/jep.11.2.153CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A., and Temin, Peter 1976. Economics. Tenth edition. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Saunders, Phillip, and Bach, George Leland 1970. “The Lasting Effects of an Introductory Economics Course: An Exploratory Study.” The Journal of Economic Education 1 (2): 143149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skousen, Mark 1997. “The Perseverance of Paul Samuelson’s Economics.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (2): 137152.10.1257/jep.11.2.137CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solow, Robert M., Heilbroner, Robert L., and Riecken, Henry W.. 1971. “Discussion.” The American Economic Review 61 (2): 6368.Google Scholar
Tobin, James 1974. The New Economics One Decade Older. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Vicedo, Marga 2012. “Introduction: The Secret Lives of Textbooks.” Isis 103 (1): 8387.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed