Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T04:51:46.480Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

What Curbs Social Investment? The Effect of Foreign Electoral Outcomes on Childcare Expenditure Levels

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 January 2022

SIMONE TONELLI*
Affiliation:
SOCIUM Research Centre on Inequality and Social Policy, University of Bremen, Bremen, Germany Mary-Somerville-Straße 9 28359, Bremen email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This study aims to deepen our understanding of social investment expansion proposing a political learning mechanism to link existing institutional and political explanations. When resources are limited, increased spending in social investment often comes at the expense of politically costly retrenchment of established social insurance policies. Previous studies suggest that this trade-off results in existing entitlements crowding out new policies, and that party ideology plays less of a role in determining social policy expansion. I argue that this is because parties face an electoral dilemma, as individual preferences for social investment and social insurance have been shown to differ between groups that partly overlap in their voting behaviour. Applying a policy diffusion framework to the analysis of childcare expenditure, this study proposes that policymakers learn from the political consequences of past decisions made by their foreign counterparts and update their policy choice accordingly. The econometric analysis of OECD data on childcare expenditure shows that governments tend to make spending decisions that follow those of ideologically similar cabinets abroad and that left-wing governments with a divided electorate tend to reduce childcare expenditure if a previous expansionary decision of a foreign incumbent is followed by an electoral defeat. The findings have implications for the study of the politics of social policy development.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

Introduction

The transformations associated with the shift to a post-industrial society gave rise to a set of new social risks (NSRs) more heterogeneous than those generated in industrial economies, and hence more difficult to compensate for via social insurance (Bonoli, Reference Bonoli2005; Esping-Andersen, Reference Esping-Andersen2002; Armingeon and Bonoli, Reference Armingeon and Bonoli2007). Instead, NSRs are tackled by a measure of social investment, such as active labour market policies and childcare services (Morel and Palier, Reference Morel and Palier2011). Social investment policies are thus considered important instruments to confront the risks generated by post-industrial societies, and the slow development of these services is puzzling (Bouget et al., Reference Bouget, Frazer, Marlier, Sabato and Vanhercke2015).

This research adopts a policy diffusion perspective and proposes a political learning mechanism through which the consequences of the politics of social investment can both facilitate and hamper the development of these policies. In this framework, policymakers are assumed to be Bayesian learners whose beliefs about the consequences of a policy adoption are updated when new information is gathered (Braun and Gilardi, Reference Braun and Gilardi2006; Tversky and Kahneman, Reference Tversky and Kahneman1974). It is argued that information about the political success or failure of a policy decision in other jurisdictions is expected to affect policymakers’ judgments about the political feasibility of a given policy proposal altering their policy choice (May, Reference May1992).

The central argument is developed around the electorally uncertain character of the politics of social investment expansion. Social investment policies are not supported equally by all individuals in a polity. NSR groups are more likely to prefer an emphasis on expenditures that allow them to participate in the labour market, while already integrated individuals, such as production workers with specific skills, are more likely to prefer compensation for ‘old risks’ (Häusermann, Reference Häusermann2010; Häusermann et al., Reference Häusermann, Kurer and Schwander2014; Häusermann et al., Reference Häusermann, Pinggera, Ares and Enggist2019). Overall, people are more likely to oppose the expansion of benefits from which they do not directly benefit (Busemeyer et al., Reference Busemeyer, Garritzmann and Neimanns2015; Busemeyer and Neimanns, Reference Busemeyer and Neimanns2017; Busemeyer and Garritzmann, Reference Busemeyer and Garritzmann2017; Chung and Meuleman, Reference Chung and Meuleman2017).

Even though individuals belonging to different social groups have, on average, different preferences for social policy, their party preferences are not always as different (Häusermann and Kriesi, Reference Häusermann and Kriesi2015). In this study, it is argued that incumbents whose electorate is divided on which policy to prioritise face a political dilemma. Indeed, in times of austerity, part of the electorate of governing parties may perceive the expansion of social investment as a shift of resources from the protection for old risks and translate this into a loss of support. Thus, uncertain of the political outcome of their policy choice, the decisions of parties in government may be informed by the past experience of their foreign counterparts in an attempt to learn from their electoral consequences and reduce political risks.

To test this argument, I estimate the association between the domestic and foreign levels of childcare expenditure, where the past foreign policy decisions are weighted by their closest electoral outcomes. The policy change under study is the level of expenditure in childcare services, as family policy is a key element of the social investment approach, which emphasises investments in children’s social and cognitive skills (Esping-Andersen, Reference Esping-Andersen2002) and removes a major obstacle to mothers’ labour market integration (Lewis et al., Reference Lewis, Knijn, Martin and Ostner2008; Hook, Reference Hook2015; Esping-Andersen, Reference Esping-Andersen2009).

The electoral relevance of childcare services and other work-friendly family policies has been growing together with the declining importance of the core constituencies of mainstream parties, generally more in favour of male-breadwinner social insurance policies, such as industrial workers for the parties of the Left and religious voters for centre parties (Schwander et al., 2018). Promoting social investment, these parties attempt to attract new voters, such as women and young highly educated professionals (Morgan, Reference Morgan2013; Karreth et al., Reference Karreth, Polk and Allen2013; Häusermann, Reference Häusermann2018; Schwander and Häusermann, Reference Schwander and Häusermann2013). Under different circumstances, these electoral strategies have proven able to produce both electoral rewards and sanctions (Abou-Chadi and Wagner, Reference Abou-Chadi and Wagner2019; Nelson and Giger, Reference Nelson and Giger2019; Neimanns, Reference Neimanns2021).

The organisation of the paper will start with a section outlining the theoretical mechanism through which political learning is expected to influence an incumbent policy choice. This is followed by a section on the politics of social investment that contains an illustration of the electoral dilemma faced by governments with a divided electorate and formalises testable hypotheses on the effect of political learning. The subsequent sections describe the research design and empirical strategy, present and discuss the findings, and the final section concludes.

Learning from Foreign Electoral Consequences: A Mechanism of Policy Diffusion

Policy diffusion occurs when government policy decisions in one country are systematically conditioned by prior policy choices made in other countries (Simmons et al., Reference Simmons, Dobbin and Garrett2006). There is a widespread consensus on three broad classes of diffusion mechanisms: learning, emulation, and competition (Braun and Gilardi, Reference Braun and Gilardi2006; Simmons et al., Reference Simmons, Dobbin and Garrett2006; Shipan and Volden, Reference Shipan and Volden2008; Graham et al., Reference Graham, Shipan and Volden2013; Gilardi, Reference Gilardi2012). In this study, learning from the consequences of other units is proposed as a mechanism to explain the slow development of social investment.

Learning can be defined as the process of acquisition of new relevant information that permits the updating of beliefs about the effects of a new policy (Meseguer, Reference Meseguer2004; Meseguer, Reference Meseguer2005; Meseguer, Reference Meseguer2003; Braun and Gilardi, Reference Braun and Gilardi2006). The learning process is best described in terms of Bayesian updating. Individuals update their beliefs by looking at the experiences of others, either rationally or relying on ‘cognitive shortcuts’ such as representativeness, availability and anchoring (Tversky and Kahneman, Reference Tversky and Kahneman1974; McDermott, Reference McDermott2001; Weyland, Reference Weyland2012; Weyland, Reference Weyland2009).

The acquisition of new relevant information can lead to two forms of learning. Policy learning occurs when the information acquired concerns the effectiveness of a policy, i.e. when it achieves what it is designed to do (Meseguer, Reference Meseguer2003). Political learning occurs when the information acquired concerns the payoffs associated with policies, i.e. their electoral rewards and their closeness to the policymaker ideal point (Braun and Gilardi, Reference Braun and Gilardi2006, p. 301).

The focus of this paper is on political learning, i.e. ‘judgments about the political feasibility of policy proposals and understandings of the policy process within a given policy domain’ (May, Reference May1992, p. 339). Examples of political learning are political actors adapting their political strategies to advance their political agendas without suffering severe electoral costs (Pierson, Reference Pierson1994), e.g. proposing fewer radical reforms and negotiating with interest groups to achieve reforms (Natali, Reference Natali2002).

The scholarship on policy diffusion is regarded as the field of study that has done the most to link theoretical models of learning to empirical analyses (Dunlop and Radaelli, Reference Dunlop and Radaelli2013, p. 600), developing models that included both mechanisms of policy and political learning (Braun and Gilardi, Reference Braun and Gilardi2006; Gilardi and Wasserfallen, Reference Gilardi and Wasserfallen2019). Empirically, this research showed the importance of political learning as a mechanism influencing many policy developments. Policy diffusion is often conditional on ideological ground, as political/ideological proximity between units facilitates diffusion (Volden, Reference Volden2006; Butler et al., Reference Butler, Volden, Dynes and Shor2017), and public opinion support (Pacheco, Reference Pacheco2012; Pacheco and Maltby, Reference Pacheco and Maltby2017; Abel, Reference Abel2019). Governments also react to the electoral consequences of the prior policy choices of other countries (Gilardi, Reference Gilardi2010) and tend to reframe diffusing laws in more electorally acceptable forms (Mallinson and Hannah, Reference Mallinson and Hannah2020).

Research in party politics has shown that political learning also occurs between parties, which strategically adjust their ideological orientations according to the shifts of their counterparts that have recently governed (Williams, Reference Williams2015; Williams and Whitten, Reference Williams and Whitten2015). Parties also adjust their positions according to shifts in public opinion when the direction of change is clearly disadvantageous for the party (Adams et al., Reference Adams, Clark, Ezrow and Glasgow2004). A growing amount of research in the intersection between party politics and policy diffusion is collecting evidence that this phenomenon takes place also cross-nationally (Böhmelt et al., Reference Böhmelt, Ezrow, Lehrer, Schleiter and Ward2017; Böhmelt et al., Reference Böhmelt, Ezrow, Lehrer and Ward2016; Schleiter et al., Reference Schleiter, Böhmelt, Ezrow and Lehrer2021; Adam and Ftergioti, Reference Adam and Ftergioti2019). Ideological shifts, however, do not come without a cost. Voters update their party support accordingly and hold governing parties accountable for their policy outputs (Adams et al., Reference Adams, Bernardi and Wlezien2020; Bernardi and Adams, Reference Bernardi and Adams2019; Adams et al., Reference Adams, Clark, Ezrow and Glasgow2006).

Figure 1 contains a stylised model of political learning via foreign electoral consequences. Let i be a country in which the government must decide how to allocate the yearly budget for social expenditure, let j be a country that recently had a national election, and let the government of the two countries have similar constituencies. The way government in country i will allocate social expenditure will depend on a number of domestic factors, such as its ideological orientation, the existence of a specific problem pressure, and the availability of sufficient resources. There will also be, however, non-domestic factors affecting the government decisions via policy or political learning. One form of political learning occurs when the government in country i observes the outcome of the election in country j (dashed line) and updates its perception of adequacy of a given policy choice accordingly. In this way, the expenditure decision in country i is affected by the electoral outcome of country j (dashed arrow). More specifically, if the incumbent in country j wins the election, the government in country i will be more likely to make similar policy decisions; if the government in country j loses the election the government in country i will be less likely to make similar policy decisions.

FIGURE 1. Model of political learning via electoral consequences

The model of political learning in figure 1 relies on the assumption that the learning government is uncertain of the optimal course of action to undertake. This is not, however, always the case. The next section elaborates on the reasons why social investment expansion may be considered a source of uncertainty and the conditions under which such uncertainty may occur.

The Uncertain Politics of Social Investment

Unconstrained public opinion support for social investment is broad (Garritzmann et al., Reference Garritzmann, Busemeyer and Neimanns2018) but is significantly reduced when its expansion has to be financed through cuts in existing entitlements (Busemeyer et al., Reference Busemeyer, Garritzmann and Neimanns2015; Busemeyer and Garritzmann, Reference Busemeyer and Garritzmann2017). In times of austerity, the expansion of some programs tends to occur at the expense of others (Häusermann, Reference Häusermann2010), and social insurance programs compete with needs-based benefits (Palier, Reference Palier2010; Palier and Thelen, Reference Palier and Thelen2010; Emmenegger et al., Reference Emmenegger, Häusermann, Palier and Seeleib-Kaiser2012; Kim and Choi, Reference Kim and Choi2020).

As a consequence, the political conflict in advanced political economies is characterised by friction between individual preferences for policies that distribute benefits on the basis of contributions and those that do so on the basis of need (Beramendi et al., Reference Beramendi, Häusermann, Kitschelt and Kriesi2015), and preferences between expenditure that generates immediate consumption for the insured and expenditure whose returns are diffused and delayed, such as active labour market policies, investments in human capital and child and elderly care services (Häusermann and Kriesi, Reference Häusermann and Kriesi2015; Rueda, Reference Rueda2005; Schwander and Häusermann, Reference Schwander and Häusermann2013; Van Lancker, Reference Van Lancker2013).

Individuals with different preferences for social policy, however, do not necessarily vote for different parties (Häusermann and Kriesi, Reference Häusermann and Kriesi2015). On the one hand, part of the electorate of the Left opposes increasing spending on social investment if it perceives it as a threat to existing entitlements (Abou-Chadi and Wagner, Reference Abou-Chadi and Wagner2019). On the other hand, the same parties are rewarded for the expansion of certain social investment policies, i.e. childcare (Nelson and Giger, Reference Nelson and Giger2019), but only from individuals further up the income distribution, i.e. those more likely to make use of them (Neimanns, Reference Neimanns2021).

I argue that a divided electorate and the unpredictability of electoral returns of a social investment expansion generate uncertainty in the decision-making process of policymakers lacking complete information about what is the optimal course of action to undertake. To overcome information deficits, governments may look at the experiences of others and learn from their consequences (Braun and Gilardi, Reference Braun and Gilardi2006; Meseguer, Reference Meseguer2004).

Therefore, when cabinets allocate more resources to childcare expenditure and are rewarded in subsequent elections, the other countries’ expenditure levels should increase (H1). Similarly, when cabinets allocate more resources to childcare expenditure and are sanctioned in subsequent elections, the other countries’ expenditure levels should decrease (H2).

Political learning, however, should occur only in situations of uncertainty. To be valid, the hypotheses above should fulfil two conditions: first, there must be a divided electorate, i.e. groups of individuals prioritising, on average, different social expenditures, and voting, on average, for the same party; second, the divided electorate should be the electorate of the governing parties.

Thus, as a first scope condition (SC1), the effect should be significant only in countries in which the size of groups more in favour of social insurance is declining in favour of groups with a preference for social investment (Schwander et al., 2018). Low-skilled workers with specific skills are especially likely to oppose investment-oriented policies (Häusermann, Reference Häusermann2010; Häusermann et al., Reference Häusermann, Kurer and Schwander2014) while high-skilled and female labour market outsiders strongly favour social investment policies (Häusermann et al., Reference Häusermann, Kurer and Schwander2014). The welfare priority of these groups is even stronger when the relative importance of social insurance or social investment is included in the picture: Production workers prioritise social insurance and social consumption more than every other category, while high skilled socio-cultural professionals are the most positive towards social investment (Häusermann et al., Reference Häusermann, Pinggera, Ares and Enggist2019). Therefore, the effect of the foreign political consequences should be stronger in countries where the ratio between socio-cultural professionals and production workers is skewed in favour of socio-cultural professionals and weaker where the ratio is skewed in favour of production workers (SC1).

A second scope condition is that the governing party or coalition should have a divided electorate. The majority of social democratic parties balance their programmatic offer between social investment and protection for old risks (Häusermann et al., Reference Häusermann, Pinggera, Ares and Enggist2019), arguably reflecting the evidence that socio-cultural professionals and production workers do not significantly differ in their probability of voting parties on the Left (Häusermann and Kriesi, Reference Häusermann and Kriesi2015). Indeed, an expansion of childcare services increases the electoral support for the Left only in the part of its electorate with higher income, generally socio-cultural professionals (Neimanns, Reference Neimanns2021). This implies that the electorate of the parties of the Left is the most divided on these policy preferences. Conversely, the electorate of Christian democratic and Centre-right parties is also changing as the religious voters are losing importance, and these parties may compete for centrist voters embracing more progressive views on childcare, especially when a radical-right competitor is missing (Schwander et al., 2018; Fleckenstein, Reference Fleckenstein2011). In contrast, far-right parties are not expected to shift their positions on childcare to follow public opinion shifts, as they are generally sanctioned by a more resilient electorate (Adams et al., Reference Adams, Clark, Ezrow and Glasgow2006). Therefore, while all parties on the ideological spectrum but the far-right may be to an extent susceptible to the foreign electoral consequences of childcare expansion, the effect should be stronger for the parties on the Left (SC2).

Data and Methods

To test the hypotheses stated in the previous section, I model the diffusion effects with the inclusion of spatial lags in the model specification, relying on a longitudinal dataset with observations for 23 OECD countriesFootnote 1 from 1999 to 2013. The dependent variable is the total public and mandatory private social expenditure for childcare and early education services as a percentage of GDP (OECD, 2018b). The restriction of the sample size to 23 countries is due to data availability of the same countries in the European Social Survey Cumulative File (ESS, 2018), and the time frame is given by data availability for all 23 countries at the time of analysis.

Data on election dates, election outcomes and cabinet composition for the definition of the weighting matrices are taken from Döring and Manow (Reference Döring and Manow2019). Government positions on the ideological dimension are measured on a left-right scale from 1 to 10. It is calculated by averaging the position of the cabinet parties, weighted by the number of seats occupied, using expert survey data (Döring and Manow, Reference Döring and Manow2019). I use ESS (2018) waves 1-8 to measure the size of production workers (PW) and socio-cultural professionals (SCP) according to Oesch’s (2006) class schema. Each individual is assigned to one category according to their ISCO-code and then categories are aggregated by country and wave. Since the waves are published every two years and the survey is conducted in the years in between, the values of a wave done at year t are imputed to the years t-1, t-2… t-n if values are missing. For example, the values of the first wave that took place in 2002 are assumed as valid also for 1999, 2000 and 2001. The ratio between socio-cultural professionals and production workers (SCP-to-PW ratio) is calculated dividing the share of socio-cultural professionals by the share of production workers.

The model includes several variables that are expected to influence the outcome of interest (see Table A1 for an overview of the variables included in the model).

Theoretically, the level of childcare expenditure in a year is likely to depend on the level of the previous year, thus I include the lagged value of the dependent variable. Methodologically, whether the lagged dependent variable (LDV) should be included or not in the model specification, even when part of the data generating process, is an open debate. While LDV models are known to produce biases in the estimation of coefficients (Achen, Reference Achen2000; Plümper et al., Reference Plümper, Troeger and Manow2005), it has been argued that there is nothing pernicious in using it when the time dimension is large enough $\left( {T \ge 15} \right)$ (Beck and Katz, Reference Beck and Katz2011). Furthermore, the omission of LDV would itself produce severe omitted variable bias (Wilkins, Reference Wilkins2018), especially in the spatial specification where the LDV controls for important common trends between cross-sections that may lead to spatial patterns (Plümper and Neumayer, Reference Plümper and Neumayer2010).

Childcare expenditure levels are expected to depend on the amount of resources available in a country; to control for economic performances I include the log of the GDP per capita (World Bank, 2019b) and real GDP growth (OECD, 2018a). To control for the sociodemographic demand of childcare, the models include the total fertility rate (World Bank, 2019c) and the female labour force participation rate (World Bank, 2019a). A larger share of women in the legislative chamber (Armingeon et al., Reference Armingeon, Wenger, Wiedemeier, Isler, Knöpfel, Weisstanner and Engler2019) may also be associated with higher levels of expenditure, as female MPs are assumed to be more responsive to working women interests (Bonoli and Reber, Reference Bonoli and Reber2010). I include the level of government expenditure in social security transfers as a percentage of GDP (OECD, 2018b) as it may negatively affect childcare expenditure due to the crowding out effect (Bonoli and Reber, Reference Bonoli and Reber2010; Kim and Choi, Reference Kim and Choi2020). I control for the government’s ideology as parties on the Left are expected to be associated with higher levels of expenditure that promotes the participation of women in the labour market (Korpi, Reference Korpi2000). I include a spatial lag of geographic proximity as neighbouring countries represented in national media are known to affect family policy development (Linos, Reference Linos2013) and to control for other exogenous shocks and common trends (Plümper and Neumayer, Reference Plümper and Neumayer2010). Finally, I include country dummies to control for all the country-specific time-invariant unobserved heterogeneity that may be associated with changing expenditure.

Model specification

I estimate a series of dynamic spatial autoregressive models (Franzese and Hays, Reference Franzese and Hays2007, Reference Franzese and Hays2008), which allow for dependence between observations due to strategic interaction as a consequence of political learning. In this analysis, the level of expenditure of one country at time t is modelled as a function of the average level of expenditure on other countries at $t - 1$ , weighed by different attributes discussed in the following section.

In equation 1, a weighting matrix specifies the set of countries and the relevant linkages between the countries. Accordingly, the spatial lag model is defined as:

(1) $${y_t} = \varphi {y_{t - 1}} + \;\beta {X_{t - 1}} + \rho W{y_{t - 1}} + \varepsilon $$

Where ${y_t}$ is the dependent variable (childcare expenditure at time t), ${y_{t - 1}}$ signifies the temporally lagged dependent variable (childcare expenditure at time $t - 1$ ), ${X_{t - 1}}$ is a matrix of temporally lagged explanatory variables. $W{y_{t - 1}}$ stands for the product of the connectivity matrix W and the lagged value of the dependent variable ${y_{t - 1}}$ , i.e. $W{y_{t - 1}}$ is the spatial lag and $\rho $ is the corresponding spatial autoregressive coefficient.

In panel analysis, the connectivity matrix W, is given by a $NT \times NT$ matrix with $T\;\left( {N \times N} \right)$ sub-matrices along the block-diagonal, with an element ${w_{ij}}$ capturing the relative connectivity of unit (country) j to unit (country) i and with the diagonal elements ${w_{ii}} = 0$ . A common way to define the spatial lag is to use the temporally lagged values of the dependent variable (Gleditsch and Ward, Reference Gleditsch and Ward2008).

A common estimator is the ordinary least square (OLS) regression (Böhmelt et al., Reference Böhmelt, Ezrow, Lehrer and Ward2016; Williams, Reference Williams2015; Williams and Whitten, Reference Williams and Whitten2015). However, the spatial lag in OLS introduces endogeneity in the specification, and maximum likelihood (ML) and two-stage least square (2SLS) have been shown to provide superior estimates and more accurate standard errors (Franzese and Hays, Reference Franzese and Hays2007; Plümper and Neumayer, Reference Plümper and Neumayer2010). As suggested by Anselin et al. (Reference Anselin, Le Gallo and Jayet2008), ML may also be a way to deal with the endogeneity induced by the LDV (Elhorst, Reference Elhorst2014).

Operationalisation of country linkages

For the operationalisation of country interdependencies, I rely on four distinct weighting matrices. Matrix ${W_{won}}$ captures the interdependencies between the government in country i and the incumbent in country j, and the strength of the relationship is given by the share of parties in the incumbent coalition who were also part of the newly appointed cabinet after the elections. Thus, the government in country i gives more weight to the decisions of its successful counterparts. ${W_{lost}}$ captures the interdependency between the government in country i and the incumbent in country j and the strength of the relationship is given by the share of parties of the incumbent coalition that were not part of the newly-appointed cabinet after the elections. Thus, the government in country i gives more weight to the decisions of its unsuccessful counterparts. ${W_{ideo}}\;$ captures the ideological distance between the government in country i and the government in country j – that is to say, the government in country i gives more weight to decisions made by more ideologically similar counterparts. Finally, ${W_{geo}}\;$ captures the geographical distance between country i and j, so the government in country i weights more decisions made by governments in proximate countries.

Each element ${w_{ij}}$ of the underlying connectivity matrix ${W_{won}}$ receives a value $0 \le {w_{ij}} \le 1$ , equal to the share of parties of an incumbent cabinet coalition in country j that were part of the cabinet coalition that followed the elections. Each element ${w_{ij}}$ of ${W_{lost}}$ receive a value $0 \le {w_{ij}} \le 1$ , equal to the share of parties of the incumbent cabinet coalitions that were not part of the cabinet coalition that followed the elections. Each element ${w_{ij}}$ of ${W_{ideo}}$ receives a value $1 \le {w_{ij}} \le 10$ , equal to the absolute difference between the values of the left-right positions of the governments in country i and j. Finally, each element ${w_{ij}}$ of ${W_{geo}}$ takes a value equal to the inverse distance between the capitals of country i and j.

It is common practice to row standardize the proximity matrices to facilitate the interpretation of results, removing dependence on the scale factor and avoiding singularity, so that each row sums up to 1. Row-standardization generates spatial lags that are a weighted average of the values of the dependent variable with weights dependent on the existence and strength of a postulated network tie between a pair of cases. The spatial lags $W{y_{won}},\;W{y_{lost}}\;,\;W{y_{ideo}}$ and $W{y_{geo}}\;$ are calculated by multiplying the relative weighting matrices with a vector containing the time-lagged value of childcare expenditure, the resulting vector represents the average value of childcare expenditure of the countries in the sample, corrected by the weights specified in the weighting matrices.

Findings

Table 1 contains the estimated parameters. Unsurprisingly, a large part of childcare expenditure depends on the level of expenditure in previous years across all models. Besides that, the strongest predictor in model 1 is the total fertility rate: a one unit increase in the TFR is associated with a rise in expenditure by 0.09 percent of the GDP. The log of GDP per capita has a very small association with the level of childcare expenditure, such that it becomes indistinguishable from zero when further controls are included in the model specification. The level of expenditure for social security transfer as a share of GDP has a consistent significant negative effect on the level of childcare expenditure, in line with the crowding out hypothesis, indicating that resources tend to be either allocated to social insurance or social investment. In most models, the effect of government ideology is not associated significantly with the outcome levels, in line with previous research that found an inconsistent effect of ideology in the development of post-industrial social policy (Bonoli, Reference Bonoli2013; Bonoli and Reber, Reference Bonoli and Reber2010). The coefficient for ideology, however, becomes a significant predictor of childcare expenditure levels when the effect of geographical diffusion of childcare expenditure is controlled for: For a unit increase in the Left-Right dimension, the expenditure for childcare is reduced by 0.004 percent of GDP.

TABLE 1. Spatiotemporal autoregressive models (Maximum likelihood estimates).

Standard errors in parentheses

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

For what concerns the effect of the size of occupational groups: the larger the share of socio-cultural professionals, the higher the demand for childcare services. A significant portion of socio-cultural professionals are women and younger and highly educated individuals, who generally prefer social investment over social consumption. Each unit percentage increase in the share of socio-cultural professionals is associated with a rise in spending on childcare services by 0.007 percent of GDP. In contrast, the share of production workers does not significantly predict the level of childcare expenditure. Model 2 includes the ratio between SCP and PW instead of their overall shares, and the effect is positive and strong. Each unit increase in the SCP-to-PW ratio increases the expenditure for childcare services by 0.08 percent of GDP.

Model 3 includes the spatial lag for government ideological proximity, i.e. the average level of spending of every other country in the sample, weighted by the ideological distance between governments. The larger the ideological distance between the two governments, the larger the importance given to its value. The coefficient is negative, suggesting that policy decision in one country is followed by a similar decision in a country with an ideologically proximate government. The coefficient in model 3 is not significant, but it becomes significant once the control for geographic proximity is introduced in the specification, suggesting that policy diffusion takes place between countries with ideologically similar cabinets only as far as these countries are also geographically close. An increase of one percentage point in the average expenditure of ideological proximate governments is associated with a rise in expenditure by about 0.12 percent of GDP, indicating a strong diffusion between like-minded governments.

Models 4 and 5 include the indicators for political learning, i.e. the average expenditure levels in countries that recently experienced elections, weighted for the success and failure of incumbent coalitions. The larger the share of parties of the previous coalition that (do not) belong to the newly appointed cabinet, the larger the importance given to their expenditure choices. The coefficient of $W{y_{won}}$ is positive but not significant while the coefficient for $W{y_{lost}}$ is negative and significant. This suggests that success stories are not valued as much as failure stories. Such an effect is in line with research on cognitive biases that has consistently shown that negative and positive information is weighted differently, with higher value given to negative information (Kahneman and Tversky, Reference Kahneman and Tversky1979; Ito and Cacioppo, Reference Ito and Cacioppo2005; Rozin and Royzman, Reference Rozin and Royzman2001), as well as with the findings in party politics research showing that political parties adjust their policy orientations according to shifts in public opinion only as long as such shifts are clearly disadvantageous for the party (Adams et al., Reference Adams, Clark, Ezrow and Glasgow2004). Thus, H2 is supported but and H1 is rejected. The main effect on an increase of one percentage point in average spending level of governments that subsequently lost an election is associated with a reduction of spending by 0.04 percent of GDP. The estimated effect does not change once geographical proximity is controlled for.

Model 6 tests the scope conditions under which political learning should occur. Since it is not possible to infer meaningful conditional effects simply by looking at the significance of the interaction term (Brambor et al., Reference Brambor, Clark and Golder2006), in Figure 2 the conditional effects of political learning are plotted.

FIGURE 2. Marginal effects of Wy Lost for different SCP-to-PW ratios and for differentgovernment ideologies, with 95% CINote: Left = 2.5 on the left-right scale; Centre = 5.5 on the left-right scale; Right = 8.5 on the left right scale

Figure 2 contains the average marginal effect of political learning for countries with different ratios between socio-cultural professionals and production workers, and different government orientations. For governments of right-wing and centrist ideologies, the slope of the marginal effects of $W{y_{lost}}$ is not significantly different from zero. Instead, for governments made by parties of the Left, the effect of political learning on the level of spending is strong and statistically significant: The effect of $W{y_{lost}}$ is close to zero when the size of production workers is much larger than socio-cultural professionals (values close to zero on the x-axis) and becomes increasingly negative for larger shares of socio-cultural professionals, signalling an increasingly divided electorate.

To sum up, childcare expenditure levels were found to be positively associated with higher fertility rates, larger shares of socio-cultural professionals, the ratio between socio-cultural professionals and production workers, and negatively to the size of the expenditure for social security transfers. Left-wing governments were found to be associated with a higher childcare development when the influences of geographically proximate governments are controlled for. One of these influences is the behaviour of governments that is also ideologically proximate, as it appears that governments of similar ideology tend to make similar decisions with regards to childcare expenditure decisions. The analysis showed that these governments also learn from the negative political consequences of their foreign counterparts that have recently governed: In particular, governments of the Left with a divided electorate tend to reduce their expenditure levels whenever a foreign incumbent that previously did so loses the elections.

Conclusions

Political explanations of social policy development are central in the comparative politics literature on the welfare state, especially with regards to the expansion and retrenchment of benefits. Early theories posited that a large working-class with homogenous preferences for state intervention represented by left-wing parties in government was central to welfare state development. More recently, evidence has shown that the role of politics in welfare state development has changed. Post-industrial societies brought about new social risks and new strategies to cope with them, i.e. social investment policies. These new strategies imply an expansion of instruments that compete with existing entitlements, creating new conflicts, and fragmenting the historical constituencies of political parties.

I have argued in this paper that this situation generates a political dilemma for the parties whose historical core constituencies are losing importance and must attract new voters. In doing so, these parties may have an interest in the expansion of social investment but lack complete information on the political consequences of such a course of action. I hypothesized that as a consequence of such lack of information, governments learn from their foreign counterparts’ decisions and their electoral consequences.

To test the political learning mechanism, I modelled childcare expenditure levels in 23 welfare states using a set of dynamic spatial autoregressive models that allow for interdependencies between units to be included in the regression. I hypothesised that incumbent cabinet coalitions which increased levels of expenditure and were rewarded or sanctioned in a subsequent election should be respectively associated with higher or lower levels of spending in other units. The results of the analysis do not support the hypothesis that higher levels of expenditure of successful cabinets are positively associated with expenditure levels in other units but support the hypothesis of governments learning from the electoral failures of foreign counterparts.

As predicted, political learning significantly affects childcare expenditure only when a relevant political dilemma has the conditions to emerge, i.e. when the importance of groups preferring social consumption – production workers – is declining and that of groups with a preference for social investment – socio-cultural professionals – is growing. The effect is significant only for the parties on the left of the political spectrum, whose electorate is particularly divided between these two groups.

Adopting a policy diffusion framework, this study contributed to the literature on the determinants of the development of social investment investigating it from a novel angle and proposing a link between institutional and political explanations of policy development. Despite being widely advocated at the supranational level and in academia as a productive instrument to protect individuals and families in post-industrial societies from new social risks, social investment policies are developing slowly in Europe. The findings of this study show that such a weak diffusion may be due partly to the uncertainty that parties in the government coalitions have regarding the political consequences implied by a trade-off between new policies and existing entitlements. More broadly, the implications of these findings indicate that political actors may moderate the feedback effect of existing institutions via the perception that they have of possible political consequences, suggesting a channel through which institutional feedback influences the development of new policies. This general conclusion is, however, a plausible claim made on the findings of this study but it was not empirically tested and contains an element of speculation. Future research should explore more carefully the role of political moderation and use more accurate measures of the perception that political actors have of the environment in which they operate.

Supplementary material information: the dataset and scripts for the replication of the analysis will be made available upon request of the editor, the reviewers, or for publication.

Acknowledgements

Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the ESPAnet 2019 in Stockholm and at the 11th Nordwel Summer School in Bremen. I am grateful for the participants’ constructive input. Moreover, I wish to thank Tobias Böger, Julian Garritzmann, Eloisa Harris, Johannes Huinink, Carina Schmitt and two anonymous reviewers for their valuable feedback, and Hanne Gaukel for her helpful assistance. Funded by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG) Projektnummer 374666841 – SFB 1342.

Competing interests

The author declares none.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/S0047279421000908

Footnotes

1 The countries included in the analysis are Austria, Belgium, Switzerland, Czech Republic, Germany, Denmark, Spain, Estonia, Finland, France, United Kingdom, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Iceland, Italy, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, and Sweden.

References

Abel, D. (2019), ‘The diffusion of climate policies among German municipalities’, Journal of public policy. 126.Google Scholar
Abou-Chadi, T. and Wagner, M. (2019), ‘The electoral appeal of party strategies in postindustrial societies: when can the mainstream left succeed?’, The Journal of Politics 81(4): 14051419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Achen, C. (2000), ‘Why Lagged Dependent Variable Can Suppress the Explanatory Power of the Independent Variable’. Political Methodology Section of the American Political Science Association Annual Meeting. UCLA.Google Scholar
Adam, A. and Ftergioti, S. (2019), ‘Neighbors and friends: How do European political parties respond to globalization?’, European Journal of Political Economy 59: 369384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adams, J., Bernardi, L. and Wlezien, C. (2020), ‘Social welfare policy outputs and governing parties’ left-right images: Do voters respond?’, The Journal of Politics 82(3): 11611165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adams, J., Clark, M., Ezrow, L. and Glasgow, G. (2004), ‘Understanding change and stability in party ideologies: do parties respond to public opinion or to past election results?’, British Journal of Political Science 34(4): 589610.10.1017/S0007123404000201CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adams, J., Clark, M., Ezrow, L. and Glasgow, G. (2006), ‘Are niche parties fundamentally different from mainstream parties? The causes and the electoral consequences of Western European parties’ policy shifts, 1976–1998’, American journal of political science 50(3): 513529.10.1111/j.1540-5907.2006.00199.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anselin, L., Le Gallo, J. and Jayet, H. (2008), ‘Spatial panel econometrics’, The econometrics of panel data. Heidelberg: Springer, pp.625660.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armingeon, K. and Bonoli, G. (2007), The politics of post-industrial welfare states: adapting post-war social policies to new social risks: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armingeon, K., Wenger, V., Wiedemeier, F., Isler, C., Knöpfel, L., Weisstanner, D. and Engler, S. (2019), Comparative Political Data Set 1960–2017. Bern: Institute of Political Science, University of Berne.Google Scholar
Beck, N. and Katz, J.N. (2011), ‘Modeling dynamics in time-series–cross-section political economy data’, Annual Review of Political Science 14: 331352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beramendi, P. Häusermann, S. Kitschelt, H. and Kriesi, H. (eds.) (2015), The politics of advanced capitalism. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernardi, L. and Adams, J. (2019), ‘Does government support respond to governments’ social welfare rhetoric or their spending? An analysis of government support in Britain, Spain and the United States’, British Journal of Political Science 49(4): 14071429.10.1017/S0007123417000199CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Böhmelt, T., Ezrow, L., Lehrer, R., Schleiter, P. and Ward, H. (2017), ‘Why dominant governing parties are cross-nationally influential’, International Studies Quarterly 61(4): 749759.10.1093/isq/sqx067CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Böhmelt, T., Ezrow, L., Lehrer, R. and Ward, H. (2016), ‘Party policy diffusion’, American Political Science Review 110(2): 397410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonoli, G. (2005), ‘The politics of the new social policies: providing coverage against new social risks in mature welfare states’, Policy & politics 33(3): 431449.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonoli, G. (2013), The origins of active social policy: Labour market and childcare policies in a comparative perspective: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonoli, G. and Reber, F. (2010), ‘The political economy of childcare in OECD countries: Explaining cross-national variation in spending and coverage rates’, European Journal of Political Research 49(1): 97118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouget, D., Frazer, H., Marlier, E., Sabato, S and Vanhercke, B. (2015), Social Investment in Europe. A study of national policies. Brussels: European Commission.Google Scholar
Brambor, T., Clark, W.R. and Golder, M. (2006), ‘Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses’, Political analysis, 6382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braun, D. and Gilardi, F. (2006), ‘Taking ‘Galton’s problem’ seriously: Towards a theory of policy diffusion’, Journal of theoretical politics, 18(3): 298322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, M.R. and Garritzmann, J.L. (2017), ‘Public opinion on policy and budgetary trade-offs in European welfare states: evidence from a new comparative survey’, Journal of European Public Policy 24(6): 871889.10.1080/13501763.2017.1298658CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, M.R., Garritzmann, J.L. and Neimanns, E. (2015), Public opinion towards policy trade-offs: Investigating attitudes on social investment and compensatory welfare policies with a new comparative survey. Workshop citizens in changing welfare states: Pressures, frames, and feedback, University of Gothenburg, Gothenburg.Google Scholar
Busemeyer, M.R. and Neimanns, E. (2017), ‘Conflictive preferences towards social investments and transfers in mature welfare states: The cases of unemployment benefits and childcare provision’, Journal of European Social Policy 27(3): 229246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Butler, D. M., Volden, C., Dynes, A. M. and Shor, B. (2017), ‘Ideology, learning, and policy diffusion: Experimental evidence’, American journal of political science 61(1): 3749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chung, H. and Meuleman, B. (2017), ‘European parents’ attitudes towards public childcare provision: The role of current provisions, interests and ideologies’, European Societies 19(1): 4968.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Döring, H. and Manow, P. (2019), ‘Parliament and government composition database (ParlGov)’, An infrastructure for empirical information on parties, elections and governments in modern democracies. Version 12(10).Google Scholar
Dunlop, C.A. and Radaelli, C.M. (2013), ‘Systematising policy learning: From monolith to dimensions’, Political studies 61(3): 599619.10.1111/j.1467-9248.2012.00982.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elhorst, J.P. (2014), Spatial econometrics: from cross-sectional data to spatial panels: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Emmenegger, P., Häusermann, S., Palier, B. and Seeleib-Kaiser, M. (2012), ‘How rich countries cope with deindustrialization’, The Age of Dualization: The Changing Face of Inequality in Deindustrializing Societies. 304-320.Google Scholar
Esping-Andersen, G. (2002), ‘A child-centred social investment strategy’, Why we need a new welfare state. 26–67.Google Scholar
Esping-Andersen, G. (2009), Incomplete revolution: Adapting welfare states to women’s new roles: Polity.Google Scholar
ESS (2018), European Social Survey Cumulative File, ESS 1-8 (2018). Data file edition 1.0. NSD Norwegian Centre for Research Data, Norway - Data Archive and distributor of ESS data for ESS ERIC.Google Scholar
Fleckenstein, T. (2011), ‘The politics of ideas in welfare state transformation: Christian democracy and the reform of family policy in Germany’, Social Politics 18(4): 543571.10.1093/sp/jxr022CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Franzese, R.J. and Hays, J.C. (2007), ‘Spatial econometric models of cross-sectional interdependence in political science panel and time-series-cross-section data’, Political analysis 15(2): 140164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franzese, R.J. Jr and Hays, J.C. (2008), ‘Interdependence in comparative politics: Substance, theory, empirics, substance’. Comparative Political Studies, 41(4-5): 742780.10.1177/0010414007313122CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garritzmann, J.L., Busemeyer, M.R. and Neimanns, E. (2018), ‘Public demand for social investment: new supporting coalitions for welfare state reform in Western Europe?’, Journal of European Public Policy 25(6): 844861.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilardi, F. (2010), ‘Who learns from what in policy diffusion processes?’, American journal of political science 54(3): 650666.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilardi, F. (2012), ‘Transnational diffusion: Norms, ideas, and policies’, Handbook of international relations 2: 453477.Google Scholar
Gilardi, F. and Wasserfallen, F. (2019), ‘The politics of policy diffusion’, European Journal of Political Research 58(4): 12451256.10.1111/1475-6765.12326CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gleditsch, K. and Ward, M.D. (2008), Spatial regression models: Sage Publications Inc.Google Scholar
Graham, E.R., Shipan, C.R. and Volden, C. (2013), ‘The diffusion of policy diffusion research in political science’, British Journal of Political Science. 673701.10.1017/S0007123412000415CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Häusermann, S. (2010), The politics of welfare state reform in continental Europe: Modernization in hard times: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Häusermann, S. (2018), ‘Institutional Legacies and Party Competition’, Welfare Democracies and Party Politics: Explaining Electoral Dynamics in Times of Changing Welfare Capitalism. 150.Google Scholar
Häusermann, S. and Kriesi, H. (2015), ‘What do voters want? Dimensions and configurations in individual-level preferences and party choice’, The politics of advanced capitalism. 202–230.Google Scholar
Häusermann, S., Kurer, T. and Schwander, H. (2014), ‘High-skilled outsiders? Labor market vulnerability, education and welfare state preferences’, Socio-Economic Review 13(2): 235258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Häusermann, S., Pinggera, M., Ares, M. and Enggist, M. (2019), ‘The Limits of Solidarity. Changing welfare coalitions in a transforming European party system. ’, Paper prepared for the International Conference of Europeanists (CES), June 20-22 in Madrid. Google Scholar
Hook, J.L. (2015), ‘Incorporating ‘class’ into work–family arrangements: Insights from and for Three Worlds’, Journal of European Social Policy 25(1): 1431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ito, T. and Cacioppo, J. (2005), ‘Variations on a human universal: Individual differences in positivity offset and negativity bias’, Cognition & Emotion 19(1): 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1979), ‘Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk’, Econometrica 47(2): 263292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karreth, J., Polk, J.T. and Allen, C.S. (2013), ‘Catchall or catch and release? The electoral consequences of social democratic parties’ march to the middle in Western Europe’, Comparative Political Studies 46(7): 791822.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, Y.Y. and Choi, Y.J. (2020), ‘Does social protection crowd out social investment?’, Policy and Society 39(2): 208225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Korpi, W. (2000), ‘Faces of inequality: Gender, class, and patterns of inequalities in different types of welfare states’, Social Politics: international studies in gender, state & society 7(2): 127191.10.1093/sp/7.2.127CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, J., Knijn, J. T., Martin, J. and Ostner, J. T. (2008), Patterns of Development in Work/Family Reconciliation Policies for Parents in France, Germany, the Netherlands, and the UK in the 2000s. Social Politics: International Studies in Gender, State and Society, 15, 261286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linos, K. (2013), The democratic foundations of policy diffusion: How health, family, and employment laws spread across countries: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mallinson, D.J. and Hannah, A.L. (2020), ‘Policy and Political Learning: The Development of Medical Marijuana Policies in the States’, Publius: The Journal of Federalism.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
May, P.J. (1992), ‘Policy learning and failure’, Journal of public policy 12(4): 331354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDermott, R. (2001), ‘The psychological ideas of Amos Tversky and their relevance for political science’, Journal of theoretical politics 13(1): 533.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meseguer, C. (2003), ‘Learning and economic policy choices: a Bayesian approach’.Google Scholar
Meseguer, C. (2004), ‘What role for learning? The diffusion of privatisation in OECD and Latin American countries’, Journal of public policy. 299325.10.1017/S0143814X04000182CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meseguer, C. (2005), ‘Policy learning, policy diffusion, and the making of a new order’, The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 598(1): 6782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morel, N. and Palier, B. (2011), Towards a social investment welfare state?: Ideas, policies and challenges: Policy Press.Google Scholar
Morgan, K.J. (2013), ‘Path shifting of the welfare state: Electoral competition and the expansion of work-family policies in Western Europe’, World politics 65(1): 73115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Natali, D. (2002), ‘La ridefinizione del welfare state contemporaneo: la riforma delle pensioni in Francia e in Italia’.Google Scholar
Neimanns, E. (2021), ‘Preferences, vote choice, and the politics of social investment: Addressing the puzzle of unequal benefits of childcare provision’, Journal of Social Policy. 1–20.Google Scholar
Nelson, M. and Giger, N. (2019), ‘Social investment by popular demand? The electoral politics of employment-centered family policy’, Comparative European Politics 17(3): 426446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2018a), OECD Economic Outlook No. 103. OECD Economic Outlook: Statistics and Projections Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
OECD (2018b), Social Expenditure: Aggregated data. OECD Social Expenditure Statistics Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
Oesch, D. (2006), ‘Coming to grips with a changing class structure: An analysis of employment stratification in Britain, Germany, Sweden and Switzerland’, International Sociology 21(2): 263288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pacheco, J. (2012), ‘The social contagion model: Exploring the role of public opinion on the diffusion of antismoking legislation across the American states’, The Journal of Politics 74(1): 187202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pacheco, J. and Maltby, E. (2017), ‘The role of public opinion—does it influence the diffusion of ACA decisions?’, Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law 42(2): 309340.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Palier, B. (2010), A long goodbye to Bismarck? The politics of welfare reform in continental Europe: Amsterdam Univ. Press.Google Scholar
Palier, B. and Thelen, K. (2010), ‘Institutionalizing dualism: Complementarities and change in France and Germany’, Politics & Society 38(1): 119148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, P. (1994), Dismantling the welfare state?: Reagan, Thatcher and the politics of retrenchment: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plümper, T. and Neumayer, E. (2010), ‘Model specification in the analysis of spatial dependence’, European Journal of Political Research 49(3): 418442.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plümper, T., Troeger, V.E. and Manow, P. (2005), ‘Panel data analysis in comparative politics: Linking method to theory’, European Journal of Political Research 44(2): 327354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rozin, P. and Royzman, E.B. (2001), ‘Negativity bias, negativity dominance, and contagion’, Personality and social psychology review 5(4): 296320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rueda, D. (2005), ‘Insider–outsider politics in industrialized democracies: The challenge to social democratic parties’, American Political Science Review 99(1): 6174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schleiter, P., Böhmelt, T., Ezrow, L. and Lehrer, R. (2021), ‘Social Democratic Party Exceptionalism and Transnational Policy Linkages’, World politics. 133.Google Scholar
Schwander, H. (2018), ‘Electoral demand, party competition and family policy: The politics of a new policy field’. In Manow, P., Palier, B. and Schwander, H. (eds.), Welfare democracies and party politics: Explaining electoral dynamics in times of changing welfare capitalism, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp.197224.Google Scholar
Schwander, H. and Häusermann, S. (2013), ‘Who is in and who is out? A risk-based conceptualization of insiders and outsiders’, Journal of European Social Policy 23(3): 248269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shipan, C.R. and Volden, C. (2008), ‘The mechanisms of policy diffusion’, American journal of political science 52(4): 840857.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmons, B.A., Dobbin, F. and Garrett, G. (2006), ‘Introduction: The international diffusion of liberalism’, International organization. 781810.Google Scholar
Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1974), ‘Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases’, science 185(4157): 11241131.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Van Lancker, W. (2013), ‘Putting the child-centred investment strategy to the test: Evidence for the EU27’, European Journal of Social Security 15(1): 427.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volden, C. (2006), ‘States as policy laboratories: Emulating success in the children’s health insurance program’, American journal of political science 50(2): 294312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weyland, K. (2009), Bounded rationality and policy diffusion: Social sector reform in Latin America: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weyland, K. (2012), ‘The Arab Spring: Why the surprising similarities with the revolutionary wave of 1848?’, Perspectives on Politics 10(4): 917934.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilkins, A.S. (2018), ‘To lag or not to lag?: Re-evaluating the use of lagged dependent variables in regression analysis’, Political Science Research and Methods 6(2): 393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, L.K. (2015), ‘It’s all relative: Spatial positioning of parties and ideological shifts’, European Journal of Political Research 54(1): 141159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, L.K. and Whitten, G.D. (2015), ‘Don’t stand so close to me: Spatial contagion effects and party competition’, American Journal of Political Science 59(2): 309325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank (2019a), Female Labour Force Participation (Share of Total Labour Force). World Development Indicators database. New York: World Bank.Google Scholar
World Bank (2019b), GDP per capita, PPP (constant 2017 international $). World Development Indicators database. New York: World Bank.Google Scholar
World Bank (2019c), Total Fertility Rate (Number of Births per Woman). World Development Indicators database. New York: World Bank.Google Scholar
Figure 0

FIGURE 1. Model of political learning via electoral consequences

Figure 1

TABLE 1. Spatiotemporal autoregressive models (Maximum likelihood estimates).

Figure 2

FIGURE 2. Marginal effects of Wy Lost for different SCP-to-PW ratios and for differentgovernment ideologies, with 95% CINote: Left = 2.5 on the left-right scale; Centre = 5.5 on the left-right scale; Right = 8.5 on the left right scale

Supplementary material: File

Tonelli supplementary material

Tonelli supplementary material 1

Download Tonelli supplementary material(File)
File 21.4 KB
Supplementary material: File

Tonelli supplementary material

Tonelli supplementary material 2

Download Tonelli supplementary material(File)
File 21.3 KB
Supplementary material: File

Tonelli supplementary material

Tonelli supplementary material 3

Download Tonelli supplementary material(File)
File 134.7 KB