Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-p9bg8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T02:16:32.542Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Locked-in or Locked-out: Can a Public Services Market Really Change?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 November 2019

MARK CONSIDINE
Affiliation:
Chancellery, Raymond Priestly Building, University of Melbourne, Parkville 3010, Australia. email: [email protected]
SIOBHAN O’SULLIVAN
Affiliation:
School of Social Sciences, Morven Brown Building C20, University of New South Wales, NSW 2052, Australia, email: [email protected]
MICHAEL MCGANN
Affiliation:
School of Social and Political Sciences, University of Melbourne, Parkville 3010, Australia, email: [email protected]
PHUC NGUYEN
Affiliation:
La Trobe Business School, La Trobe University Shepparton Campus, 210 Fryers Street, Shepparton 3630, Australia, email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Australia’s welfare-to-work system has been subject to ongoing political contestation and policy reform since the 1990s. In this paper we take a big picture look at the Australian system over time, re-visiting our earlier analysis of the impact of marketisation on flexibility at the frontline over the first ten years of the Australian market in employment services. That analysis demonstrated that marketisation had failed to deliver the service flexibility intended through contracting-out, and had instead produced market herding around a common set of standardised frontline practices. In the interim, there have been two further major redesigns of the Australian system at considerable expense to taxpayers. Re-introducing greater flexibility and service tailoring into the market has been a key aim of these reforms. Calling on evidence from an original, longitudinal survey of frontline employment service staff run in 2008, 2012 and 2016, this paper considers how the Australian market has evolved over its second decade. We find remarkable consistency over time and, indeed, evidence of deepening organisational convergence. We conclude that, once in motion, isomorphic pressures towards standardisation quickly get locked into quasi-market regimes; at least when these pressures occur in low-trust contracting environments.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2019

Introduction

Since the 1990s, there has been a radical change in the institutions delivering public employment services in many OECD countries. Nowhere has this been more apparent than in Australia which, in ten years, went from a publicly delivered employment services regime, to a system of shared delivery between the public and private sectors, to an entirely privatised system of market delivery. These institutional changes have involved a fundamental shift in the role of the government from a provider to a purchaser of services, driven by a set of principal-agent assumptions about the ability of contracts to mitigate information asymmetry problems in public service supply chains, and the conviction that marketisation can produce a system that is not only more efficient but also ‘more tailored, more personalised, and more flexible’ (Considine et al., Reference Considine, Lewis, O’Sullivan and Sol2015: 46). This was the underlying logic behind the introduction of Australia’s Job Network (JN), an ‘internationally important social policy experiment’ (Ramia and Carney, Reference Ramia and Carney2000: 60) in competitive tendering that operated from 1998 until 2009.

Successive Australian governments have shown no loss of appetite for continued service market experimentation. Along with periodic contracting rounds, there have been two major system re-structures: Job Services Australia (2009) and Jobactive (2015), each designed to address identified shortcomings of their predecessors. Frequently these related to the inability of successive market models to produce services that were flexibly tailored to the long-term unemployed; criticisms frequently levelled against JN (Bredgaard and Larsen, Reference Bredgaard and Larsen2008; Finn, Reference Finn2011; McDonald and Marston, Reference McDonald and Marston2008; Ramia and Carney, Reference Ramia and Carney2010). In a study drawing on comparative survey research with frontline employment services staff in the late 1990s and 2008, Considine et al. (Reference Considine, Lewis and O’Sullivan2011) concluded that JN had evolved into a highly standardised system, as providers adopted increasingly conservative and converging practices over time.

In this paper, we examine this second decade of Australian quasi-market reform and the changes that have unfolded since JN. Drawing on two further waves of data collection from frontline staff in 2012 and 2016 and comparing these to the earlier study of frontline service delivery under JN, we consider whether more recent restructures have been able to arrest the previously documented trends towards service standardisation and provider herding that appeared to have set in by the end of JN. Or have such features become indelibly ‘locked-in’ to the Australian welfare market?

In developing this analysis, we draw on the concept of institutional isomorphism from organisational theory (DiMaggio and Powell, Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983; Beckert, Reference Beckert2010), as well as insights from quasi-markets and transaction cost theory concerning the effects of different transaction modes on competition and quality (for example Greer et al., Reference Greer, Breidahl, Knuth and Larsen2017; Bennett, Reference Bennett2017; Bartlett, Reference Bartlett1991), to examine the dynamics of change within employment services fields and the extent to which such public services markets can be expected to evolve into more varied systems or consolidate around a set of ‘dominant organisational models’ (DiMaggio and Powell, Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983: 148). Theorists predict that public service organisations are particularly susceptible to isomorphism, or convergence towards similar organisational structures and processes, due to their resource dependency and accountability relationships to government (Frumkin and Galaskiewicz, Reference Frumkin and Galaskiewicz2004); features that, we argue, apply equally to non-government organisations in publicly-funded welfare markets. Indeed, aspects of how the transactional arrangements between purchasers and providers are organised in welfare markets can further strengthen and intersect with these isomorphic pressures to reinforce tendencies towards standardisation in employment services fields. These include the structure of the pricing mechanism, the level of prescription in contracts, the high barriers to entry facing new entrants and uncertainty over the relationship between provider inputs and client outcomes; conditions that incentiviseorganisations to replicate what others already do – but to try to do so more efficiently – while shielding established providers from new competitors with alternative organisational processes.

In what follows, we introduce the concept of institutional isomorphism and how it relates to understanding patterns of development and change within public services markets. We then review the key design features and evolution of Australia’s JN, and subsequent attempts to reform Australia’s marketised system towards greater flexibility, before introducing the present study and our findings.

Isomorphism in organisational fields

New theories of public management posit that the creation of quasi-markets will enhance diversity in service delivery as agencies strive to innovate to gain competitive adavantage. They view the competitive drive for efficiency as the catalyst of institutional change, as in the example of Payment-by-Results contracts which rely on the performance signals in payment models to motivate agencies to ‘develop new practices to identify and tackle individual employment barriers’ (Finn, Reference Finn2012: 24). For organisational theorists in sociology, however, it is the demand for legitimacy rather than efficiency that is ‘the major driving force of organisational change’ (Knill and Balint, Reference Knill and Balint2008: 679), and which drives organisations within shared fields of action to become ‘more similar without necessarily making them more efficient’ (DiMaggio and Powell, Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983: 147). Over time, organisations exposed to similar conditions converge on ‘similar norms, structures and systems’ (Kitchener, Reference Kitchener1998: 75) as they adapt ‘to conform to the expectations of the key stakeholders in their environment’ (Ashworth et al., Reference Ashworth, Boyne and Delbridge2007: 165).

DiMaggio and Powell (Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983) identify distinct coercive, mimetic, and normative isomorphic mechanisms. For example, organisations may adapt because they are pushed into doing so by organisations they depend upon, such as governments. Governments can coerce organisations to adjust their structures through their ‘power to regulate’ (Frumkin and Galaskiewicz, Reference Frumkin and Galaskiewicz2004: 284) but also through their control over funding (Ashworth et al., Reference Ashworth, Boyne and Delbridge2007). In such cases of coercive isomorphism, diffusion occurs through defensive reactions to systems of administrative accountability, as organisations comply with institutional pressures to adopt ‘those routines and structures that are defined by law or government agencies as legitimate’ (Frumkin and Galaskiewicz, Reference Frumkin and Galaskiewicz2004: 286). Eligibility requirements for government contracts, for example, may push organisations within a given field to adopt similar financial reporting and governance processes. Kitchener’s (Reference Kitchener1998) study of quasi-market transformation among UK hospitals showed how representative bodies informally exerted pressures on hospital managers to adopt a clinical directorates organisational structure, which then became the archetypal UK hospital model despite never being mandated as policy. In the context of the Australian welfare market, previous studies have highlighted the pressures exerted on not-for-profits to professionalise and reform their boards in order to maintain exchange relationships with government (Considine et al., Reference Considine, O’Sullivan and Nguyen2014b).

In public services markets characterised by a purchaser-provider split, governments may also exert coercive isomorphic pressures on organisations through how they structure the transactions within those markets (Greer et al., Reference Greer, Breidahl, Knuth and Larsen2017). For example, the purchaser may specify fixed processes, such as the frequency of appointments or minimum requirements in clients’ activity agreements, that providers must adhere to in order to receive payment. Alternatively, the purchaser may leave it to providers to determine what services clients receive, and when, but arrange the payment model so that providers are predominantly paid based on specified outcomes. However, strengthening the performance signals in payment models may generate standardising tendencies of their own by intensifying providers’ aversion to risk. This is because they transfer the costs of under-performance onto providers, making experimentation with unproven approaches riskier for organisations.

Importantly, coercive isomorphic pressures are predicted to intensify the more organisations are dependent on another organisation. Greater inter-dependence generates greater similarity ‘in structure, climate, and behavioural focus’ (DiMaggio and Powell, Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983: 154). Again, the modes of transaction in welfare markets, and how they are organised by the purchaser, are likely to have important implications for the degree of organisational inter-dependence in employment services fields. In quasi-markets where users are ‘empowered’ to purchase services directly through the grant of vouchers, organisations are less financially dependent on the purchasing power of governments than in quasi-markets where governments procure services and ‘simply direct the user to the provision it has bought’ (Wiggan, Reference Wiggan2015: 117). In practice, employment services markets are rarely organised around user-choice. Rather, as in the Australian market, governments often act as the sole purchaser. This would suggest that providers in Australia may be particularly vulnerable to coercive isomorphic pressures because they are competing in a field in which the flow of resources is controlled by a ‘monopsony’ purchaser. Established providers that have organised their businesses around delivering contracts may be especially vulnerable to coercive isomorphic pressures if they have become ‘“tied into” the field’ (Taylor et al., Reference Taylor, Rees and Damm2016: 265) through resource dependency.

While regulatory and government funding arrangements are ‘core drivers’ (Frumkin and Galaskiewicz, Reference Frumkin and Galaskiewicz2004: 286) of isomorphism, organisations can also be pulled towards convergence by normative and mimetic processes. Normative isomorphic forces result from processes of professionalisation, which DiMaggio and Powell identify in terms of the rise of professional communities and industry associations that serve ‘to promulgate normative rules about organisational and professional behaviour’ (Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983: 152). These ‘epistemic communities’ (Knill and Balint, Reference Knill and Balint2008: 681) help to diffuse common understandings of policy problems and their solutions within fields. In mimetic isomorphism, organisations model themselves on counterparts that are perceived to be more legitimate or more successful, or they import practices by osmosis through employee transfer. DiMaggio and Powell (Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983) predict that mimetic isomorphism will be more prevalent in fields where there is uncertainty over the relationship between means and ends; an inherent feature of the ‘complex and multi-dimensional’ transactions that occur in welfare markets insofar as they involve ‘the provision of sophisticated service activities rather than the relatively basic provision of material commodities with which traditional markets deal’ (Bartlett, Reference Bartlett1991: 53).

Organisations delivering social services do so under conditions of bounded rationality. The causal effects of particular service inputs on client outcomes are not particularly well understood. Amidst these conditions, the mimetic copying of established processes reduces ‘the decision load’ (Beckert, Reference Beckert2010: 155) of determining which configuration of practices is likely to fulfil objectives. Organisations strive to ensure their legitimacy by emulation. Not because of any clear evidence that the copied practices will optimise performance but because some options appear to have an established legitimacy (Ashworth et al., Reference Ashworth, Boyne and Delbridge2007). For organisations entering the field, emulation may be a way of more easily fitting the ‘administrative categories that define eligibility for public and private grants and contracts’ (DiMaggio and Powell, Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983: 153). In this context, the grant of government contracts may structure isomorphic processes by giving key firms recognition and legitimacy, motivating competitors ‘to copy aspects of their structure or operating procedures in the hope of obtaining similar rewards’ (DiMaggio and Powell, Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983: 153).

Institutional change at the Australian frontline

Australia was one of the first OECD countries to fully competitively tender its public employment services, which it did under Job Network in May 1998. It was described by the Australian government as ‘the most significant reorganisation of labour market assistance arrangements’ (quoted in O’Flynn, Reference O’Flynn2007: 4) since the 1940s and, by the OECD, as ‘without parallel’ internationally (Finn, Reference Finn2011: 5). According to O’Flynn, ‘it was clear that a new era in employment services had begun’ (Reference O’Flynn2007: 1). Although Struyven (Reference Struyven2014) argues that the transformation of Australia’s system in fact unfolded through a more gradual process of institutional layering, displacement and conversion. Indeed, prior to JN, several hundred for-profit and non-profit agencies were licensed to deliver case management to the long-term unemployed under Labor’s Working Nation (1994). This reform created a dual system in which the Commonwealth Employment Service continued to deliver services to a proportion of jobseekers, while a new market was created for case management of the long-term unemployed. In this way, market-based administrative principles were ‘layered’ onto the existing public system setting in motion new institutional logics that would eventually displace the public foundations of the system under the Howard Coalition government.

Under the first JN contract, a mix of over 300 private, community and government-owned providers won contracts to deliver a range of job-matching, job-search training, and intensive assistance services with the non-public providers winning two-thirds of the market (O’Flynn, Reference O’Flynn2007). Agencies received a combination of service fees and outcome payments that varied depending on the duration that clients were placed into employment or training and which were differentiated according to jobseekers’ assessed level of disadvantage. The second JN contract (2001–2003) extended price competition to intensive service provision, and private providers won almost 90 per cent of contracts as the new market competition logic became the system’s ‘major driving force’ (Ramia and Carney, Reference Ramia and Carney2000: 66).

The first two JN contracts operated mostly as ‘black box’ systems in that providers were afforded much leeway to determine the assistance they provided. However, this changed from 2003, when greater specification concerning the content and frequency of services was introduced along with minimum service guarantees. While partly about guaranteeing service quality, this measure was also designed to ensure that jobseekers’ mutual obligations were consistently enforced under a new Active Participation model (Considine et al., Reference Considine, Lewis, O’Sullivan and Sol2015: 39). Providers were required to document how clients were meeting their conditionality requirements via a new central IT platform. This information could be viewed by agency managers and departmental officials, who exhibited an increased inclination towards recovering payments from providers who were found to have misused their discretion. This heavier regulation was driven by growing evidence that agencies were gaming the system through practices of ‘creaming’ and ‘parking’ clients (Considine, Reference Considine2001), and even ‘creating phantom jobs’ to collect payments (O’Flynn, Reference O’Flynn2007: 4).

Another important change was the abandonment of price-competition during tenders. In the face of evidence that agencies’ contract bids were ‘at a level that was insufficient to ensure proper employment assistance for the most disadvantaged’ (Thomas, Reference Thomas2007: 8), the government instituted fixed prices and a quarantined pool of funds (the Employment Fund) for purchasing assistance for clients that providers were unable to retain as profit. With price-competition abandoned, past performance became the basis for allocating contracts and market share as determined by a new ‘Star Ratings’ performance measurement system. This system, which was introduced in 2001 and remains in operation, uses a confidential regression to award each site a performance rating – initially every six months, but now quarterly – that then feeds into providers’ overall rating at a region level. It was originally intended as a kind of ‘Michelin Guide’ (Considine et al., Reference Considine, Lewis, O’Sullivan and Sol2015: 38) for signalling providers’ relative performance to clients, although it quickly became the key mechanism for awarding contracts and periodically (re)allocating shares of jobseekers within contract regions from low to high-performing providers. Sixty per cent of the agencies awarded contracts in 2003 automatically had their contracts extended based on their Star Ratings. It was at this point in the system’s evolution that the government-owned provider collapsed, seemingly unable to compete with the other private agencies that made up the rest of JN. In 2006, less than 10 per cent of contracts were competitvely tendered as JN became consolidated around one hundred ‘core providers’ (Finn, Reference Finn2011), all for-profits or not-for-profits.

The marketisation of Australia’s employment services was driven by the belief that competition would not only increase efficiency but also promote innovation and tailoring. While the average cost of employment outcomes did decline (Thomas, Reference Thomas2007), JN did not produce the levels of flexibility predicted. Studies suggest that it instead resulted in a quasi-market of agencies focused on survival, and for whom the risk involved in not sticking to beaten paths was ‘simply too high’ (Bredgaard and Larsen, Reference Bredgaard and Larsen2008: 345). Part of the problem related to the purchaser’s increasingly prescriptive approach to regulating transactions within the market. Increasing contractual specification and the detailed oversight of providers via the application of IT-based information systems, critics contended, had given rise to an ‘inflexible’ pattern of outsourced services’ (Finn, Reference Finn2011: 13) where ‘“personalised service” [was] the exception, rather than the norm’ (Marston and McDonald Reference Marston and McDonald2008: 265). Considine et al.’s comparative research showed a ‘marked increase in the level of routinisation and standardisation at the frontline’ (Reference Considine, Lewis and O’Sullivan2011: 811) as agencies responded to the intensification of administrative accountability by embracing standardisation ‘as a way to minimise risks’ (Reference Considine, Lewis and O’Sullivan2011: 826). This in turn led to a loss of differentiation between for-profit and not-for-profit providers.

Since JN, there have been by two major re-structures of the Australian system: Job Services Australia (JSA) (2009–15) and Jobactive (2015–2022). JSA was introduced by Labor in 2009, following a review of JN. Major emphases of the reform were to make the system less punitive and to replace JN’s ‘“one size fits all” approach… with greater flexibility for employment services providers to tailor services’ (Gillard, Reference Gillard2008). Jobseekers were to become more involved in designing their employment plans, with the new system placing a greater emphasis on ‘increasing flexibility… and on providing more integrated and holistic “wrap-around” support’ (SSC, 2009: 31). This was accompanied by a partial softening of the compliance framework, as agencies were given more discretion over the tailoring of clients’ Job Plans (Ramia and Carney, Reference Ramia and Carney2010). The funding model was also adjusted to increase the incentives for agencies to focus on assisting harder-to-help clients, and the performance framework partially revised to move ‘away from the “command and control” relationship’ that had characterised the later years of JN (Finn, Reference Finn2011: 20).

The restructure came at considerable transition cost. Approximately 320,000 jobseekers were required to change provider, while agencies who retained a similar market share incured millions in transaction costs associated with the change (Finn, Reference Finn2011: 17). This points ‘to a dilemma in the tendering model’ (McDonald and Marston, Reference McDonald and Marston2008: 106). To maintain a competitive market, the purchaser needs to continuously generate new tendering processes that, in turn, generate high transaction costs associated with the preparation of tendering documents, assessment of bids and negotiation of contacts. Whereas established providers can deploy the informational advantages and surpluses gained from previous contracts to bid for repeat contracts, new entrants ‘must expend resources on market participation and business acquisition costs without any guarantee that contracts can be secured’ (Bennett, Reference Bennett2017: 143). There are also the ex-post transaction costs that arise for both the purchaser and providers associated with monitoring the market to mitigate risks of gaming behaviours.

These transaction costs ‘are an inescapable by-product of contracting out’ (Bredgaard and Larsen, Reference Bredgaard and Larsen2008: 345). However, institutional economists argue that they are likely to be especially high in social services markets: where ‘a contractor knows the quality of its service is difficult to observe, where a large degree of information asymmetry exists…and where the assessment of a provider’s true additionality is confounded by external factors such as the business cycle or simply demand for labour’ (Hill, Reference Hill2013: 198). To manage these risks, purchasers try to steer agents’ behaviours via detailed contractual specification of processes, penalty clauses, and mechanisms for post-contract oversight. But beside the difficulties involved in fully specifying contracts and determining the appropriate balance between price and quality in payment models (Bartlett, Reference Bartlett1991; Bredgaard and Larsen, Reference Bredgaard and Larsen2008; Bennett, Reference Bennett2017), such a contracting regime is very costly to administer. By the end of JSA, the annual cost of administrating the system was estimated at A$259.3 m, or 21 per cent of total programme costs (ANAO, 2017).

The high-costs of administering the system, and associated impact on levels of service flexibility, have been a persistent challenge for governments in Australia. In mid-2015, the new Coalition government introduced what it argued was another ‘fundamental reform of employment services’ (DoE, 2016: 11). It criticised JSA as heavily ‘constrained by administrative requirements’ (DoE, 2016: 9), attributing this to the system’s ‘limited scope for provider-initiated service design’ (DoE, 2016: 9). Accordingly, and like preceeding reforms, a key objective of the reform was to ‘reduce service prescription’ (DoE, 2015: 1). Providers were permitted to bid on the basis of different service models, in the hope that this would free them ‘to deliver flexible solutions tailored to an individual jobseeker’s circumstances’ (ANAO, 2017: 34). At a more ideological level, the reform also sought to intensify jobseeker activation through strengthening conditionality. Other key changes included the lengthening of contracts to five years and increase in the size of the geographic areas that agencies were awarded contracts for; changes that resembled elements of the UK’s Work Programme commissioning model and which were designed to minimise the purchaser’s transaction costs through reducing the number of exchange relationships it would need to enter into and monitor (Bennett, Reference Bennett2017). Another parallel with the Work Programme was the restructuring of the pricing mechanism towards Payment-by-Results. The proportion of total provider funding represented by outcome payments increased to more than 50 per cent compared with a third previously (ANAO, 2017: 15).

These changes to how providers were contracted and paid by the purchaser were designed to stimulate greater flexibility. However, by increasing the level of financial risk that providers needed to assume to deliver contracts, they also threatened to reduce diversity by making it harder for smaller, not-for-profit organisations with fewer capital reserves to remain-in or enter the market. Just 44 agencies won contracts. For-profit agencies won more of the maket than before, prompting concerns about ‘the ongoing dilution of the not-for-profit difference in the system’ (Jobs Australia, 2015a: 3).

The study

While JSA and Jobactive diverged in their approaches to jobseeker compliance, both reforms constituted attempts to reverse the standardised pattern of service delivery that had developed under JN. This problem of standardisation related to both the administrative, rule-bound approach to case management as well as the loss of differentiation between providers. To consider whether these subsequent reforms have produced substantial change towards a more varied and flexible employment services market or exhibited patterns of institutional closure and inertia, we return to Considine et al.’s (Reference Considine, Lewis and O’Sullivan2011) analysis of the impact of ten years of reform on service flexibility at the Australian frontline. That study drew on two waves of survey data collection with frontline staff, firstly between 1996 and 1999, and repeated in 2008, using largely the same instrument. This instrument comprised over 100 questions, principally about: how frontline staff carry-out basic service delivery tasks; the extent to which they use standardised assessment tools and scripted IT-driven processes when working with clients; and the degree to which they incorporate client-preferences in servicing. That approach, and ability to compare responses between workers in public, for-profit and not-for-profit agencies, enabled a comparison between Australia’s partially contracted-out system in the late 1990s and fully privatised system by 2008, with a dual focus on whether increased marketisation had delivered more flexible services, on the one hand, as well as greater diversity of assistance, on the other. We update that analysis, using data from two further surveys in 2012 and 2016 and benchmarking these against the 2008 findings.

As in 2008, these subsequent surveys were conducted online. In 2012, more than 1200 frontline staff from 26 agencies were surveyed while 1233 respondents from 32 agencies participated in 2016 (Table 1). The data were analysed using SPSS software. Chi-squared and Kruskal-Wallis tests were used to detect differences between survey years when responses were categorical, ordinal or rank order. In cases of numeric responses or continuous variables, ANOVA was used.

Table 1. Respondents

Findings from 2012 have previously been reported, suggesting large continuities in frontline practice between JN and JSA (Considine et al., Reference Considine, O’Sullivan and Nguyen2014a). With an additional wave of data collection tracking frontline practice under Jobactive, a longer-term assessment of patterns of continuity and change in the degree of ‘flexibility’ within the Australian quasi-market is now possible. We assess this from multiple perspectives: the level of frontline decision-making (discretion), the level of responsiveness to individual jobseekers (tailoring), and the degree of difference between providers (market diversity). These dimensions are interrelated insofar as a system that encourages tailoring requires that frontline staff have some capacity to act independently and to adjust their approach to the individual. It doesn’t automatically follow that frontline autonomy will promote tailoring, since discretion can also be exercised to make work more manageable and in ways that benefit ‘the worker rather than the client’ (Fletcher, Reference Fletcher2011: 447). Nonetheless, a degree of autonomy is a precondition for the possibility of ‘contextualised’ (Sainsbury, Reference Sainsbury, van Berkel, Caswell, Kupka and Larsen2017: 64) decision-making that is responsive to the interests of clients. Accordingly, a ‘flexible’ quasi-market implies high levels of professional discretion, directed toward service tailoring which, in turn, should produce greater variation between providers.

Relying on frontline workers’ self-reported understandings of their working conditions as indicators of actual levels of flexibility within the Australian welfare market is not without problems. There is a risk that the data could be subject to recall bias or skewed by respondents’ overly optimistic assessment of their own agency as workers. Nevertheless, we expect any such effects to be generalised across the sample, both within and between survey years, and therefore unlikely to undermine the value of the comparative analysis over time.

Findings

Table 2 reports several measures used to track changes in frontline discretion over time. In contrast to the intent behind the JSA and Jobactive reforms, these data suggest a moderate reduction in levels of frontline autonomy since JN. Frontline staff remain under high supervisory oversight, and there is evidence of increased reliance on IT systems and standardised protocols to guide their decision-making. This is reflected in the decline in the proportion of participants who agree or strongly agree that they are free to decide for themselves what to do with clients. This has fallen from just under 63 per cent in 2008 to below 50 per cent in 2016. This change is statistically significant and is mirrored in participants’ responses concerning the extent to which their decision-making is mediated by computers. In 2008, 47 per cent of respondents indicated that their computer system told them what steps to take with jobseekers and when to take them. Despite the considerable criticisms directed at the transformation of case management into a form of ‘screen-level bureaucracy’ under JN (Marston and McDonald, Reference Marston and McDonald2008), this proportion increased to above 50 per cent following the JSA reforms. This change is statistically significant. Although there has been a marginal decline in the proportion reporting such a reliance on computer-based decisions since, this latter decrease is not statistically significant. The data also show no statistically significant easing in the level of supervisory oversight of frontline staff by agency managers. Between surveys, there have been few significant changes in participants’ responses concerning either the extent to which their supervisor knows a lot about the work they do from day-to-day, or their tendency to defer decisions to their supervisor in cases not covered by procedural guidelines. Although the proportions agreeing or strongly agreeing that (a) they defer to their supervisors when faced with issues not covered by the procedural guide, or that (b) their supervisor knows a lot about their daily work, have declined from 91 per cent and 82 per cent respectively in 2008 to 86 per cent and 78 per cent respectively in 2016, these changes are not statistically significant. This indicates the continuation of a procedural approach to decision-making based on following scripts and escalating more complex cases to line managers (Considine and Lewis, Reference Considine and Lewis1999).

Table 2. Flexibility and discretion

Note: Significance tests have been conducted on mean rank scores, which also show the direction of change.

This pattern is also observed in the data in Table 3, which track a range of measures concerning whether client servicing is driven by standardised routines or is responsive to individual choice. Again, we find no evidence of a discernible reversal in the pattern of routinised frontline work observable under JN. Indeed, the proportion who report that the IT system they use dictates how they do their jobs ‘to a large extent’, and that their own judgement is ‘not at all’ influential in determining what activities are recommended, have both increased since 2008. It must be noted, however, that these changes involve relatively marginal increases, and are not statistically significant. What is statistically significant is the increase in the proportion who indicate that the decisions they make about clients are determined ‘to a great deal’ by standard programme rules, which has steadily risen from 18 per cent in 2008 to 27 per cent in 2012 to 31 per cent in 2016. Although there has been a somewhat surprising decrease in the proportion indicating that answers to standardised assessment questions are influential in determining the decisions they make about jobseekers. This suggests that standardisation has primarily manifested in the adoption of a more rule-bound approach to decision-making rather than via decisions being aided by the utilisation of systematic assessments of client needs.

Table 3. Flexibility and tailoring

On the question of tailoring, the data are more ambiguous. On one interpretation, tailoring implies that clients receive dissimilar menus of services according to their circumstances (Considine et al., Reference Considine, O’Sullivan and Nguyen2018). Although differentiation could also be construed as inequitable treatment and evidence of jobseeker creaming and parking (Sainsbury, Reference Sainsbury, van Berkel, Caswell, Kupka and Larsen2017). In 2008, almost 79 per cent of participants reported that all their clients received a similar service and our data show no significant pattern of change since. However, there is some evidence that client choice is becoming marginally more influential in determining what services jobseekers receive; or more accurately, what activities they undertake. In 2016, 13 per cent of respondents indicated that the agency they worked for placed ‘a great deal’ of emphasis on client choice compared with 10 per cent in 2008. However, this change was not statistically significant and was offset by a similar increase in the proportion who said that their agency placed no emphasis whatsoever on user-choice. At the individual level, staff did indicate that jobseekers’ preferences were becoming more influential in determining what activities they recommended, with the proportion indicating that jobseeker preferences are ‘very influential’ in this regard increasing from just 12 per cent in 2008 to 19 per cent in subsequent surveys.

Overall, what emerges is a picture in which frontline workers’ own professional discretion has narrowed while, simultaneously, jobseekers’ preferences have paradoxically gained in influence. This may suggest that the application of programme rules has become a more focal task of frontline work and is consistent with the ideological elements of the Jobactive reforms on ‘introducing stronger mutual obligation requirements’ (DoE, 2016: 9). But within this process of ensuring that jobseekers are meeting requirements, clients are being given some choice over how to comply (or which programmed activities to undertake). This might be characterised as a form of shallow tailoring: client choice influences what activities are undertaken but the menu jobseekers can select from, and the time when activities must be undertaken, is bounded by programme rules (compare Sainsbury, Reference Sainsbury, van Berkel, Caswell, Kupka and Larsen2017: 64).

What is perhaps most remarkable about these data on frontline discretion and tailoring is the absence of significant patterns of change in the levels of flexibility since JN. To consider this issue in more detail, we further analysed the data using an inter-sectorial comparative approach. Consistent with previous data analysis methods used to consider levels of convergence within the sector, we compared the responses of staff employed by for-profit and not-for-profit providers on 113 different variables (Table 4). Already, in 2008, our data had suggested isomorphic pressures in the Australian quasi-market insofar as the JN experiment did not lead to an industry of service innovators but a ‘herd’ of profit maximisers…who embrace standardisation of services as a way to minimise risks’ (Considine et al., Reference Considine, Lewis and O’Sullivan2011: 826). However, repeating this test on the 113 items used across all waves of data collection since 2008 shows a dramatic intensification in the level of organisational convergence since JN. Whereas 24 statistically significant differences were observed between the for-profit and not-for-profit sectors in 2008, this reduced to 8 under JSA and 11 under Jobactive. That is, on almost 90 per cent of items, we found no statistically significant difference between the responses of for-profit and not-for-profit agency staff. Of the differences that remained, several related to workers’ level of contact with external agencies and stakeholders. But on items related to agencies’ use of sanctions, time spent on various job tasks (e.g. documenting compliance, in contact with jobseekers), and level of frontline discretion, the number of statistically significant differences between the responses of for-profit and not-for-profit agency staff substantially reduced post-JN.

Table 4. Statistically significant differences in response between respondents from for-profit and not-for-profit agencies

Note: Only items where significant differences were found are shown. X denotes a statistically significant difference.

By 2016, any lingering differences between for-profit and not-for-profit agency workers in terms of their perceptions of jobseekers and willingness to apply a standardised ‘work first’ model of activation had entirely disappeared. Similarly, the value-orientations of for-profit and not-for-profit staff, and their beliefs about the key objectives of their jobs, had become almost indistinguishable. Whereas the responses of frontline staff working in different sectors significantly differed along five variables related to their goal orientation and work priorities in 2008, this narrowed to just one remaining difference by 2016. This, along with the homogenisation in frontline workers’ beliefs about jobseekers, points to strong consolidation in the Australian system over the past decade. This consolidation is particularly striking insofar as the ‘core’ of organisational cultures and value systems is thought to be less susceptible to influences from the institutional environment than the ‘periphery’ of organisational processes (Ashworth et al., Reference Ashworth, Boyne and Delbridge2007: 171).

Discussion and Conclusion

We have assessed whether the Australian quasi-market has evolved into a more flexible system across three dimensions: frontline discretion, tailoring, and market diversity. We find no significant pattern of change between JN, JSA, and Jobactive in levels of standardisation or supervisory oversight at the frontline and, if anything, further erosion of frontline discretion and the intensification of prescriptive approaches to decision-making. This is despite repeated governments explicitly stating that one of their key reform priorities was increasing service diversity and enabling better-tailored services. The diffusion of case management practices and value-orientations across organisations has also rapidly accelerated, with the surviving for-profit and not-for-profit providers much more alike than under JN. What is notable about this consolidation is its direction, with providers converging on a standardised model of frontline practice rather than the enhanced flexibility anticipated by the reforms. This consolidation might be described as a form of non-compliant convergence (Ashworth et al., Reference Ashworth, Boyne and Delbridge2007) insofar as providers have resisted conforming to norms of flexibility promoted by the purchaser.

What are the mechanisms driving this heavy consolidation within the Australian employment services field? Our data do not allow us to establish these conclusively since we only track reported changes in frontline practice and organisation models over many years of complex institutional changes, not the causal mechanisms propelling these changes. Moreover, we cannot discount the role of activation policy reforms, such as the strengthening of mandatory job search and other conditionality (e.g. Work-for-the-Dole) requirements under later iterations of the system in ‘crowding out’ possibilities for service flexibility through limiting opportunities for providers to deviate from implementing standardised ‘work first’ models. That is, the increasing standardisation of the Australian employment services field may have been driven, at least in part, ‘from the top down’ through policy effects on frontline practice and reduced possibilities for referring clients to alternative employability programmes and flanking social services (see, in relation to similar patterns in the UK, Fuertes and Lindsay, Reference Fuertes and Lindsay2016: 540).

Nevertheless, several additional factors may plausibly have contributed to the deepening institutional inertia in additional to these policy dynamics. Some of these relate to the mimetic and normative isomorphic pressures that take hold within organisational fields over time, such that ‘the more mature an organisational field, the more likely it is to be heavily “structurated” by institutional norms and rules’ (Ashworth et al., Reference Ashworth, Boyne and Delbridge2007: 167). As institutional theorists observe, information flows and interactions between organisations increase as organisational fields become more developed, along with socialisation processes via the establishment of professional communities (DiMaggio and Powell, Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983: 148). Employee transfer may also become more prevalent, further perpetuating ‘adherence to legitimised organisational forms’ (Kitchener, Reference Kitchener1998: 75). Here previously reported survey data show an upward trend in the proportion of staff with over 5 years’ experience working in the field, from 31 per cent in 2008 (Considine et al., Reference Considine, Lewis, O’Sullivan and Sol2015) to 48 per cent in 2016 (Lewis et al., Reference Lewis, Considine, O’Sullivan and Nguyen2016). Yet the proportion who have been with their employer for over 5 years has only marginally increased, from 17 to 19 per cent.

Other explanatory factors are more specific to the modes (and terms) of transaction within the Australian welfare market, and how these have been continuously adjusted by the purchaser to deal with some of the implementation challenges that arise when trying to achieve public policy objectives via the NPM instruments of competitive tendering and contract regulation. As Breedgaard and Larsen argue, striking the right balance ‘between the logic of the market and social goals’ remains a constant challenge for governments when contracting social services from market providers (Reference Bredgaard and Larsen2007: 292). Authorities try ‘to let the market work on its own premises’ to enhance efficiency but information asymmetry problems and the high dergee of uncertainty over the relationship between inputs and outputs makes the risks of gaming behaviours and other unintended consequences especially high. As we have seen in Australia, ‘constant adjustments and changes to the tendering system’ (Bredgaard and Larsen, Reference Bredgaard and Larsen2007: 293) are needed to cope with the inherent tensions between equity and efficiency in welfare markets. Reviewing these reform dynamics, we can see how features of the structuring of quasi-market transactions by the public purchaser intersect with other isomorphic pressures to amplify tendencies towards inertia within the Australian welfare market.

The first of these is the displacement of ‘black box’ approaches with forms of ‘hard contracting’ (van Berkel, Reference van Berkel2014: 192) underpinned by stronger forms of administrative accountability. These include the specification of detailed procedural guidelines by the purchaser, regular caseload and compliance audits, and the introduction of mandatory IT-based case management systems. Under JSA, for example, more than 3,000 pages of departmental guidelines applied to providers (ANAO, 2017) who faced the threat of payment recovery penalties, the imposition of additional reporting requirements, and potential exclusion from future business if they were found to be in breach of contractual clauses or guidelines. While the Jobactive contract gave providers more leeway to develop their own models, these had to cohere with prescribed universal service guarantees. Additionally, frontline work continued to be guided by over 30 different guideline documents covering issues such as the circumstances under which jobseekers may be suspended, what activities to include in Job Plans, and allowable employment fund expenditure (ANAO, 2017). These guidelines and formalised service guarantees powerfully signal the institutional legitimacy of various organisational practices, while the intensive monitoring of providers for breaches of contractual compliance exerts coercive isomorphic pressures on organisations to follow prescribed processes.

The reluctance of the purchaser to abandon this micro-management of providers is understandable given the political risks associated with contract gaming. But, in addition to increasing the transaction costs of managing the market, the evidence suggests that it locks-in ‘a focus on transactions’ (Jobs Australia, 2018: 9) and narrow approach to client-servicing based around reducing providers’ exposure to audit risk. This was illustrated by Senate Inquiry testimony about a reluctance across the sector to spend Employment Fund resources on anything beyond a narrow range of items, which agency managers attributed to consultants’ fear of putting themselves and their organisation ‘at risk of recovery funds and compliance action’ (SEERC, 2019: 81).

Elements of the performance framework applied by the purchaser further reinforce this risk-aversion among providers; most notably, the Star Ratings system which is used to periodically re-allocate market share, in terms of the proportion of jobseekers within a contract area, from low to high-performing providers. With providers’ short-term survival dependent on achieving 3-stars or above, the incentive is ‘to focus on quantum rather than quality of outcomes’ (NESA, 2018: 17) and to compete ‘to out-do each other’ (Jobs Australia, 2018: 26) at delivering the same services rather than experimenting with innovations that may put them ‘at risk in the next business allocation’ (Jobs Australia, 2015b: 3). This short-term orientation is further reinforced by the pricing signals in the payment model, which have been reconfigured towards Payment-by-Results. This has shifted more financial risk onto providers, whose viability has become increasingly dependent on maximising the number of employment outcomes they can achieve at minimal cost. In other jurisdictions, providers have responded to these downward cost pressures by increasing caseload sizes and employing ‘fewer and less qualified staff’ (Greer et al., Reference Greer, Breidahl, Knuth and Larsen2017: 165). But increasing the outcomes incentives in the payment model also risks further contributing to standardisation through the exclusion of smaller, not-for-profits, with fewer capital resources. This stems from how results-based payment models require agencies to finance the establishment of human and capital infrastructure on the basis of estimated, but uncertain, outcome payments. When the payment model incorporates only limited administration fees, as under Jobactive, the available fixed funding may be ‘insufficient to cover the administrative cost of managing the Deed’ (NESA, 2018: 14) or the capital investment required to establish service infrastructure. It is a problem that is compounded by the trend towards larger, longer contracts negotiated with fewer agencies given how these increase the size of the geographic areas across which agencies must deliver services.

As these examples show, how transactions are configured by the purchaser in terms of the pricing signals in payment models, the size of the contract areas, and the level of administrative requirements written into contract deeds, can reinforce broader isomorphic pressures within employment services fields through, among other things: increasing entry barriers, intensifying providers’ risk-aversion, and incentivising a focus on low-cost service delivery models. These organisational field and transaction dynamics intersect to make quasi-markets in employment services vulnerable to consolidation around a group of ‘insider firms’ (Bennett, Reference Bennett2017: 144). Whether Australia has reached such a tipping point is unclear, although the degree of organisational convergence since JN suggests it may not be far off. The degree to which the Australian experience can be generalised to other countries also requires further work. It may be that some of the influences driving institutional inertia in the Australian market can be mitigated through alternative organisations of the transactions in welfare markets, such as replacing the monopsony purchasing of competitive tendering with direct purchasing of services by voucher-holding clients.

Acknowledgments

This work was funded by an Australian Research Council Linkage Grant (LP150100277), supported by our industry partners Jobs Australia, the National Employment Services Association, and Westgate Community Initiatives Group. The authors thank the ARC and our industry partners for their support, in addition to all the employment services providers and many frontline staff who took time out of their busy day to participate in this research.

References

Ashworth, R., Boyne, G. and Delbridge, R. (2007), ‘Escape from the iron cage? Organisational change and isomorphic pressures in the public sector’, Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 19, 1, 165–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Australian National Audit Office (ANAO) (2017), Jobactive: Design and monitoring. Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia.Google Scholar
Bartlett, W. (1991), ‘Quasi-markets and contracts: A markets and hierarchies perspective on NHS reform’, Public Money and Management, 11, 3, 5361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beckert, J. (2010), ‘Institutional isomorphism revisited: Convergence and divergence in institutional change’, Sociological Theory, 28, 2, 150–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bennett, H. (2017), ‘Re-examing british welfare-to-work contracting using a transaction cost perspective’, Journal of Social Policy, 46, 1, 129–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bredgaard, T. and Larsen, F. (2007), ‘Implementing public employmnet policy: What happens when non-public agencies take over?’, International Journal of Sociology and Social Policy, 27, 7/8, 287300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bredgaard, T. and Larsen, F. (2008), ‘Quasi-markets in employment policy: Do they deliver on promises?’, Social Policy and Society, 7, 3, 341–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Considine, M. (2001), Enterprising states: The public management of welfare-to-work, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Considine, M. and Lewis, J.M. (1999), ‘Governance at ground level: The frontline bureaucrat in the age of markets and networks’, Public Administration Review, 59, 6, 467480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Considine, M., Lewis, J.M. and O’Sullivan, S. (2011), ‘Quasi-markets and service delivery flexibility following a decade of employment assistance reform in Australia’, Journal of Social Policy, 40, 4, 811–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Considine, M., Lewis, J.M., O’Sullivan, S. and Sol, E. (2015), Getting welfare to work: Street-level governance in Australia, the UK, and the Netherlands. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Considine, M., O’Sullivan, S. and Nguyen, P. (2014a), ‘New public management and welfare-to-work in Australia: comparing the reform agendas of the ALP and Coalition’, Australian Journal of Political Science, 49, 3, 469–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Considine, M., O’Sullivan, S. and Nguyen, P. (2014b), ‘Governance, boards of directors and the impact of contracting on not-for-profits organisations: an Australian study’, Social Policy and Administration, 48, 2, 169187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Considine, M., O’Sullivan, S. and Nguyen, P. (2018), ‘The policymaker’s dilemma: the risks and benefits of a 'black box’ approach to commissioning active labour market programmes’, Social Policy and Administration, 52, 1,. 229–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Department of Employment (DoE) (2015), Evaluation strategy for jobactive. Canberra: Australian Government. URL: https://docs.employment.gov.au/system/files/doc/other/evaluation_strategy_for_jobactive.pdf Accessed 15/1/2019.Google Scholar
Department of Employment (2016), Employment services 2015 regulation impact statement. Canberra: Australian Government. URL: https://ris.dpmc.gov.au/2016/02/23/employment-services-2015/ Accessed 2/3/16.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, P.J. and Powell, W.W. (1983), ‘The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organisational fields’, American Sociological Review, 48, 2, 147–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finn, D. (2011), Job Services Australia: Design and implementation lessons for the British context. London: Department for Work and Pensions.Google Scholar
Finn, D. (2012), Subcontracting in public employment services: The design and delivery of 'outcome based’ and 'black box’ contracts. Brussels: European Commission.Google Scholar
Fletcher, D.R. (2011), ‘Welfare reform, jobcentre plus and the street-level bureaucracy: Towards inconsistent and discriminatory welfare for severely disadvantaged groups’, Social Policy and Society, 10, 4, 445–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frumkin, P. and Galaskiewicz, J. (2004), ‘Institutional isomorphism and public sector organisations,’ Jounral of Public Administration Research and Theory, 14, 3, 283307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fuertes, V. and Lindsay, C. (2016), ‘Personalisation and street-level practice in activation: The case of the UK’s work programme’, Public Administration, 94, 2, 526–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gillard, The Hon. Julia. (2008), More flexible, better targetted employment services. Canberra: Australian Government. URL: https://ministers.jobs.gov.au/gillard/more-flexible-better-targeted-employment-services Accessed 14/1/2019.Google Scholar
Greer, I., Breidahl, K.N., Knuth, M. and Larsen, F. (2017), The marketisation of employment services: The dilemmas of Europe’s work-first welfare states: Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hill, J.C. (2013), ‘The marketisation of employment services and the British work programme’, Competition and Change, 17, 2, 197207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jobs Australia (2015a), State of play: Jobactive employment services 2015–2020 tender results. URL: https://www.ja.com.au/sites/default/files/final_sop_-_es_2015-2020_tender_results.pdf Accessed 9/5/2016.Google Scholar
Jobs Australia (2015b), Submission on the competition policy review final report. Melbourne: Jobs Australia.Google Scholar
Jobs Australia (2018), Submmision to senate inquiry into the appropriateness and effectiveness of the objectives, design, implementation and evaluation of jobactive. Melbourne: Jobs Australia.Google Scholar
Kitchener, M. (1998), Quasi-market transformation: An institutionalist approach to change in uk hospitals. Public Administration, 76:Spring, 7395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knill, C. and Balint, T. (2008), ‘Explaining variation in organisational change: The reform of human resource management in the European Commission and the OECD’, Journal of European Public Policy, 15, 5, 669–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, J.M., Considine, M., O’Sullivan, S., Nguyen, P. and M. (2016), From entitlement to experiment: the new governance of welfare to work ‐ Australian report back to industry partners. Melbourne: University of Melbourne. URL: https://arts.unimelb.edu.au/__data/assets/pdf_file/0010/2165878/2016-Australian-Industry-Report.pdf Accessed 18/7/2018.Google Scholar
Marston, G. and McDonald, C. (2008), ‘Feeling motivated yet? Long-term unemployed people’s perspectives on the implementation of workfare in Australia’, Australian Journal of Social Issues, 43, 2, 255–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDonald, C. and Marston, G. (2008), ‘Re-visiting the quasi-market in employment services: Australia’s Job Network’, Asia Pacific Journal of Public Administration, 30, 2, 101–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
NESA (2018), Nesa’s response to the senate inquiry into the appropriateness and effectivesnnes of the objectives, design, implementation and evaluation of jobactive. Melbourne: National Employment Services Association.Google Scholar
O’Flynn, J. (2007), Measuring performance in Australia’s Job Network: Part A. Melbourne: the Australia and New Zealand School of Government. URL: https://www.anzsog.edu.au/preview-documents/case-study-level-1/185-measuring-performance-in-australia-s-job-network-a-2007-37-1/file Accessed 2/4/19.Google Scholar
Ramia, G. and Carney, T. (2000), ‘Contractualism, managerialism and welfare: The Australian experiment with a marketised employment services network’, Policy and Politics, 29, 1, 5983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ramia, G. and Carney, T. (2010), ‘The Rudd government’s employment services agenda: Is it post-NPM and why is that important?’, Australian Journal of Public Administration, 69, 3, 263–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sainsbury, R. (2017), ‘Activation in the UK: The frontline and the “black box” of employment service provision’, van Berkel, R., Caswell, D., Kupka, P. and Larsen, F. [Eds] Frontline delivery of welfare-to-work policies in europe: Activating the unemployed. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Senate Education and Employment References Committee ( SEERC) (2019), Jobactive: Failing those it is intended to service. Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia.Google Scholar
Senate Standing Committee (SSC). (2009), DEEWR tender process to award employment services contracts. Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia.Google Scholar
Struyven, L. (2014), ‘Varieties of market competition in public employment services: a comparision of the emergence and evolution of the new system in Australia, the Netherlands and Belgium’, Social Policy and Administration, 48, 2, 149–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, R., Rees, J. and Damm, C. (2016), ‘UK employment services: Understanding provider strategies in a dynamic strategic action field,Policy and Politics, 44, 2, 253–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, M. (2007), A review of developments in the Job Network. Canberra: Parliament of Australia. URL: https://www.aph.gov.au/About_Parliament/Parliamentary_Departments/Parliamentary_Library/pubs/rp/RP0708/08rp15 Accessed 16/3/16Google Scholar
van Berkel, R. (2014), ‘Quasi-markets and the delivery of activation: A frontline perspective’, Social Policy and Administration, 48, 2, 188203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiggan, J. (2015), ‘Varieties of marketisation in the UK: Examining divergence in activation markets between Great Britain and Northern Ireland 2008–2014’, Policy Studies, 36, 2, 115–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Respondents

Figure 1

Table 2. Flexibility and discretion

Figure 2

Table 3. Flexibility and tailoring

Figure 3

Table 4. Statistically significant differences in response between respondents from for-profit and not-for-profit agencies