Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T06:02:23.976Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Economics, Social Policy and Social Administration: The Interplay between Topics and Disciplines*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 January 2009

Abstract

The article uses a distinction between topic and discipline to argue that social administration, like economics, is characterized by both, but that social administration has the special advantage, in treating the topic of social policy, of being multi-disciplinary. An account is presented of why economics is underrepresented among the disciplines of social administration, and three important contributory roles are outlined for economics to play in the development of social administration.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1981

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Williams, Alan, ‘One economist's view of social medicine’, Epidemiology and Community Health, 33 (1979), 37.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed

2 Cahnman, W. J. and Schmitt, C. M., ‘The concept of social policy (Sozialpolitik)’, Journal of Social Policy, 8 (1979), 4759.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 Titmuss, R. M., Social Policy: an Introduction, Allen and Unwin, London, 1974.Google Scholar

4 Ibid. pp. 30–1.

5 Titmuss, R. M., The Gift Relationship: From Human Blood to Social Policy, Allen and Unwin, London, 1970.Google Scholar

6 See Edgeworth, F. Y., Mathematical Psychics, C. Kegan Paul, London, 1881.Google Scholar

7 See Dickinson, F. G., Philanthropy and Public Policy, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1962Google Scholar; Phelps, E. S. (ed.), Altruism, Morality and Economic Theory, Russell Sage Foundation, New York, 1975Google Scholar; Collard, D., Altruism and Economics, Martin Robertson, London, 1978.Google Scholar

8 In emphasizing the idea of caring as an integrating concept of social science I am not, of course, implying it is not substantiively important in the analysis of actual policies.

9 Lafitte, F., Social Policy in a Free Society, Birmingham University Press, Birmingham, 1962.Google Scholar

10 Marshall, T. H., Social Policy, Hutchinson, London, 1967.Google Scholar

11 See the introduction in Jones, K. (ed.), Yearbook of Social Policy in Britain 1973, Routledge and Kegan Paul, London, 1973.Google Scholar

12 Donnison, D., ‘Social policy since Titmuss’, Journal of Social Policy, 8 (1979), 145–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

13 The reason, for this may lie on the ‘supply side’: the vast expansion in sociology teaching in universities since the war and the limited employment prospects for the better graduates may have led them to offer themselves relatively more frequently than others – including social administration graduates, who came later, were fewer in number, and had considerable employment potential elsewhere. (I am grateful to Brian Abel-Smith for this point).

14 Economists, sociologists, etc. are identified by their discipline. The discipline is identified by its theory. Hence theoreticians are ‘disciplinarians’ – in quotation marks to avoid confusion with the more usual meaning of the word. A social administrator may be a ‘disciplinarian’ in this sense or a ‘multi-disciplinarian’.

15 See Culyer, A. J., The Political Economy of Social Policy, Martin Robertson, Oxford, 1980.Google Scholar

16 Pinker, R., The Idea of Welfare, Heinemann, London, 1979.Google Scholar

17 A superb review for those unfamiliar with this territory is Mueller, D. C., Public Choice, Cambridge University Press, London, 1979.Google Scholar

18 Warham, J., ‘Social administration and sociology’, Journal of Social Policy, 2 (1973), 193207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

19 Smith, J. H., ‘The human factor in social administration’, Journal of Social Policy, 8 (1979). 433–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

20 Titmuss, R. M., Commitment to Welfare, Allen and Unwin, London, 1968, p. 22.Google Scholar

21 In a paper for the Social Administration Association's meeting in Leeds 1981.

22 Godfrey, L. G., Theoretical and Empirical Aspects of the Effects of Taxation on the Supply of Labour, OECD, Paris, 1975Google Scholar; Atkinson, A. B. and Flemming, J. S., ‘Unemployment, social security and incentives’, Midland Bank Review, Autumn (1978), 616Google Scholar; Feldstein, M. S., ‘The welfare loss of excess health insurance’, Journal of Political Economy, 81 (1973), 251–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lindsay, C. M., ‘Demand with zero-priced care’, in C. M. Lindsay, National Health Issues: the British Experience, Roche, New Jersey, 1980Google Scholar; Evans, R. G. and Walker, H. D., ‘Information theory and the analysis of hospital cost structure’, Canadian Journal of Economics, 5 (1972), 398418CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Culyer, A. J., Wiseman, J., Drummond, M. F. and West, P. A., ‘What accounts for the higher costs of teaching hospitals?Social and Economic Administration, 12 (1978), 20–9CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Layard, P. R. G. and Verry, D. W., ‘Cost functions for university teaching and research’, Economic Journal, 85 (1975), 5574Google Scholar; Jones-Lee, M., The Value of Life: an Economic Analysis, Martin Robertson, London, 1976Google Scholar; Le Grand, J., ‘The distribution of public expenditure: the case of health care’, Economica, 45 (1978), 125–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Boskin, M. J. and Hurd, M. D., ‘The effect of social security on early retirement’, Journal of Public Economics, 10 (1978), 361–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Mincer, J., ‘Unemployment effects of minimum wages’, Journal of Political Economy, 84 (1976), S87-S104CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Needleman, L., ‘The comparative economics of improvement and new building’, Urban Studies, 6 (1969), 196209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

23 Barry, B. M., Political Argument, Routledge and Kegan Paul, London, 1965.Google Scholar

24 Culyer, A. J., Lavers, R. J. and Williams, Alan, ‘Social Indicators: healthSocial Trends, 2 (1971), 3142.Google Scholar

25 Bradshaw, J., ‘A taxonomy of social need’ in Mc, G.Lachlan (ed.), Problems and Progress in Medical Care, 7, Oxford University Press, London, 1972.Google Scholar

26 See Bebbington, A. C. and Davies, B. P., ‘Territorial need indicators: a new approach’ Parts I and II, Journal of Social Policy, 9 (1980), 145–68 and 433–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

27 Williams, Alan, ‘Need – an economic exegesis’, in Culyer, A. J. and Wright, K. G. (eds), Economic Aspects of Health Services, Martin Robertson, Oxford, 1978.Google ScholarPubMed

28 Weale, A., Equality and Social Policy, Routledge and Kegan Paul, London, 1978.Google Scholar

29 Culyer, A. J., ‘Need, values and health status measurement’ in Culyer, A. J. and Wright, K. G. (eds), Economic Aspects of Health Services, Martin Robertson, Oxford, 1978.Google Scholar

30 Sen, A. K., ‘Planners' preferences: optimality, distribution and social welfare’ in Margolis, J. and Guitton, H. (eds), Public Economics, Macmillan, London, 1969Google Scholar. This is set out in a simplified version in Culyer, A. J., The Political Economy of Social PolicyGoogle Scholar, op. cit. chapter 4.

31 Rawls, J., A Theory of Justice, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1972.Google Scholar

32 Nozick, R., Anarchy, State and Utopia, Blackwell, Oxford, 1974.Google Scholar