Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-gb8f7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T06:04:57.037Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The aftermath of ballot box success and failure: evidence from land preservation referendums

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 July 2023

Carrie Gill
Affiliation:
Rhode Island Office of Energy Resources, USA
Corey Lang
Affiliation:
Environmental and Natural Resource Economics, University of Rhode Island, USA
Shanna Pearson-Merkowitz*
Affiliation:
School of Public Policy, University of Maryland, College Park, USA
*
Corresponding author: Shanna Pearson-Merkowitz; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

State and local governments put hundreds of referendums on the ballot each year. Often, they pass but sometimes they fail. What happens after a successful or failed attempt at the ballot box? Do advocates go back to voters with another request? And if they do, do they tend to succeed? We employ a regression discontinuity empirical framework to causally estimate referendum dynamics in the arena of land conservation. Our results suggest municipalities where a referendum just barely fails hold about 0.5 more referendums and pass about 0.28 more referendums than municipalities that just barely pass, meaning initial defeat is often reversed. We also investigate whether strategic changes are made in election approaches for those that try again. We find no evidence of systematic patterns in strategic revisions for municipalities that fail their first referendum. However, when revisions are made, our evidence suggests that voters appear to respond positively.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press

Introduction

Local governments in the USA are often constitutionally bound to ask voters for approval before issuing government debt or raising taxes. These additional resources pay for critical infrastructure for schools, land conservation, watershed cleanup, roads, and even municipal waste treatment. However, voters may not always approve of the projects or funding priorities their elected or appointed leaders have deemed worthy enough to place on the ballot. For example, in 2018, alone state governments placed bond projects on statewide ballots worth $21.1 billion, but voters only approved $12.25 billion in bonds to be purchased. In 2022, voters in 37 states voted on 132 statewide ballot measures that included both bond projects, taxes, and other ballot questions: voters approved 90 and rejected 42.

What happens after a referendum fails? Do those who advocated for the project or policy simply give up, or do they return to the voters and ask for approval again? Likewise, what happens after a successful referendum? Do advocates and legislators take the success as a cue that they can return to the voters for more? Particularly in the area of referendums for funding (bonds and dedicated taxes), are advocates revenue maximizers who will continue to return to voters for as much as they are willing to approve and ask them again in the face of defeat? While a literature exists looking at the import of the wording of referendum titles and descriptions, and the length and ordering of questions on a ballot (e.g. Augenblick and Nicholson Reference Augenblick and Nicholson2016; Brunner et al. Reference Brunner, Robbins and Simonsen2021; Matsusaka Reference Matsusaka2018), investigating the real-world consequences of failed referendums (Kogan et al. Reference Kogan, Lavertu and Peskowitz2017), as well as a large literature on ballot referendums writ large (Matsusaka Reference Matsusaka2008; Smith and Tolbert Reference Smith and Tolbert2009; Dyck and Lascher Reference Dyck and Lascher2019), no quantitative causal studies have investigated the actions of advocates and policy makers after a referendum failure or passage and the outcomes of these second attempts.

We employ a regression discontinuity (RD) empirical framework to estimate causal effects of referendum outcomes. We use a comprehensive dataset of US municipal-level land preservation referendums from 1988 to 2012, which allows us to perform a large-N analysis that captures the presence of multiple proposals in a single venue. We find that municipalities that fail an initial referendum tend to put the issue back on the ballot soon after, and that second attempts are successful about half the time. We also explore revisions to referendum characteristics for the subset of municipalities that hold multiple referendums and test the efficacy of these revisions. While we find no statistical evidence of systematic strategic revisions to subsequent referendums for municipalities that fail at their first attempt, when revisions are made, voters appear to respond positively.

Policy entrepreneurs, the local ballot box, and voter response

Political science and public policy literatures refer to advocates for policy change who make strategic decisions about how to pursue their policy goals as “policy entrepreneurs” (PEs). While there is a rich literature on PE decisions about venue choice (e.g. the courts, the legislature, or the ballot box) and level of government they pursue (e.g. Congress, the state, or a locale) (Roberts and King Reference Roberts and King1991; Weissert Reference Weissert1991; Mintrom and Norman Reference Mintrom and Norman2009; Ley and Weber Reference Ley and Weber2015; Ley Reference Ley2016; Petridou and Mintrom Reference Petridou and Mintrom2021), little work investigates how PEs react to succeeding or failing in their quests at the ballot box. Understanding these dynamics provides politically relevant insight about how to proceed after a successful or defeated attempt at policy change.

Kingdon (Reference Kingdon1994) notes that PEs can be “in or out of government, in elected or appointed positions, in interest groups or research organizations. But their defining characteristic… is their willingness to invest their resources—time, energy, reputation, and sometimes money—in the hope of a future return” (p. 122). PEs may take the form of groups of people or of individuals either inside or outside a community (Mintrom and Norman Reference Mintrom and Norman2009).

PEs also choose a venue in which to seek their proposed policy change, a process that involves weighing the benefits and drawbacks of different venue options (Baumgartner and Jones Reference Baumgartner and Jones2010), including which venue gives the greatest likelihood of success and associated costs of pursuing policy change. PEs may also seek to make changes in multiple venues at a time (Burns Reference Burns1994; Gray and Lowery Reference Gray and Lowery2000) or use public access venues (like the courts or the voter initiative) when legislatures fail to act on issues entrepreneurs desire (Bowler and Donovan Reference Bowler and Donovan2004; Gerber et al. Reference Gerber, Bowler, Donovan and Tolbert1998).

In this paper, we investigate PE behavior using referendums because referendums only appear on the ballot as a result of efforts made by actors who wish the local government to use financial resources to preserve or change the status quo.Footnote 1 As a result, the policy actors involved in getting referendums onto the ballot and working to gain enough community support to gain passage are precisely the type of PEs that Kingdon and Mintrom and Norman describe. In order for a referendum to be placed on the ballot, a community member, elected or appointed official, or group must successfully push the local legislature to place it on the ballot.

As a form of direct democracy, local referendums present an important way in which residents can inform policy and signal their opinions about the importance of an issue, opinions that may differ from local developers or planners on policies that are close to home (Bowler and Donovan Reference Bowler and Donovan2004). Seeking policy change at the local level also has some advantages for PEs as there may be a more manageable number of hurdles and actors involved in the process. Even in terms of voter support, there are fewer people in a smaller geographic area than if the policy change were made at the state level. Changes at the local government level, if successful in several locales, can also increase the rate at which a state is likely to adopt a policy through a “trickle up” or “vertical diffusion” process (Karch and Rosenthal Reference Karch and Rosenthal2016). However, local governments also have important constraints: they may not have the authority to regulate all policy areas and they have very few options and considerable limitations on their ability to fund new programs.

Do policy entrepreneurs reintroduce referendums on future ballots after a ballot success or failure?

In any given venue, PEs can decide to try again either when they have succeeded or when they have failed. For example, bills in legislatures rarely pass the first year they are introduced. Bills are regularly reintroduced until a policy window opens (e.g. Kathlene et al. Reference Kathlene, Clarke and Fox1991). Furthermore, PEs may change their proposals over time, so they better fit into a particular policy window or problem definition (Kingdon Reference Kingdon1994).

Banaszak (Reference Banaszak1996) documents the process of the Swiss and USA fights for women’s suffrage and finds that even after a failure at the ballot box, PEs worked to get the issue back on the ballot in an attempt to gain eventual passage of full women’s suffrage. Further, PEs in Sweden made tactical decisions about when to hold a second referendum and were strategic regarding the wording of the second referendum following an initial failure at the ballot box (Banaszak Reference Banaszak1996). Recent research has found that communities that reject referendums often vote on them again, and this dynamic must be accounted for when assessing the impacts of public spending on housing prices and other outcomes (Cellini et al. Reference Cellini, Ferreira and Rothstein2010, Kogan et al. Reference Kogan, Lavertu and Peskowitz2017, Lang Reference Lang2018). Following this logic, we hypothesize that PEs will continue their agenda of policy change following either an initial defeat or success in the same venue.

Indeed, referendum elections are quite different than candidate elections or a normal process of budgeting where trade-offs must be made. In referendums, voters are asked simply to “up or down” a single spending item. As a result, they cannot weigh trade-offs or compare two different scenarios (or candidates) and hold out for their preferred distribution of goods and taxes (e.g. Romer and Rosenthal Reference Romer and Rosenthal1978). Advocates are likely “revenue-maximizers” for their cause—they wish to have the maximum resources that voters and legislators will devote to their preferred spending area. PEs with access to the ballot box should push to have the referendum appear again following a failure or following an overwhelming success. Thus, the likelihood of a subsequent referendum could be a continuous function of the vote margin (the proportion of yes votes at the ballot box minus the proportion required for passage), meaning the outcome of the referendum does not have an effect on holding subsequent referendums (null hypothesis). Alternatively, proponents of referendums that just barely failed may be discouraged from holding subsequent referendums in the face of failure and either move venues or discontinue their efforts. However, the reverse could also be true; proponents that just barely failed may be more likely to try again. PEs may choose to continue within a chosen venue either because it is the only venue that is able to make their desired change, other venues are not available for political or financial reasons, or because they have already invested resources in the chosen venue and continuing on is less costly than changing venues (Buffardi et al. Reference Buffardi, Pekkanen and Rathgeb Smith2015). Thus, we hypothesize that proponents will continue their agenda of policy change following an initial defeat by holding a second referendum soon after their focal election when the election is close.

However, when focal referendums either succeed or fail by large margins, the logic changes. When a focal referendum fails by a large margin, it is unlikely that a subsequent referendum would be held in the near future because proponents will likely perceive their cause as lost or decide a different venue may be more fruitful. Similarly, those that pass by a large margin may be very likely to hold a subsequent referendum, as proponents see there is widespread support for the issue.

Voter response to repeated referendums

How do voters respond to the presence of a referendum topic reappearing on a future ballot? One the one hand, voter knowledge is quite low in general, and local elections have low salience and low voter turnout in general. Voters may not understand what they are voting on, particularly when it comes to referendums with costs associated. Recent evidence suggests that voters have little understanding of the relationship between tax increases presented on the ballot and their actual tax bills (Cozza et al. Reference Cozza, Elkins and Hudson2021; Lang et al. Reference Lang, Wichman, Weir and Pearson-Merkowitz2022) and that aggregate bond costs have very little impact on voter support (Bechard et al. Reference Bechard, Lang and Pearson-MerkowitzForthcoming). Furthermore, several studies have documented status quo bias in referendum voting (Donovan and Bowler Reference Donovan and Bowler1998; Bowler and Donovan Reference Bowler and Donovan2000; Morisi Reference Morisi2018) and valence voting (e.g. a gut “yes”) (Dyck and Pearson-Merkowitz Reference Dyck and Pearson-Merkowitz2019; Cozza et al. Reference Cozza, Elkins and Hudson2021). While previous literature has found that the information environment is critical to referendum passage (Lupia Reference Lupia1994; Bowler and Donovan Reference Bowler and Donovan2000), most of these studies focus on state-level ballot questions in which there may be considerable press coverage. Given the low level of information and salience of local referendums, a failed referendum could be taken as a sign of low voter knowledge or a function of who turned out that day, possibly driven by something else on the ballot or other random or non-random factors. Returning to the ballot may allow advocates to engage in community outreach and build support for the project. Thus, we hypothesize that, on average, voter support will increase in each subsequent election compared to the focal referendum.

Do PEs modify referendums after a focal election?

We also perform three exploratory analyses to investigate potential ways PEs may change the content of a referendum: the dollar amount proposed, the funding structure, and the election date. Each of these is exploratory, and we do not have directional hypotheses that drive expectations.

First, proponents who just barely fail in their focal referendums could reduce proposed funding in a second election, as a smaller price tag may be thought to be more acceptable to voters. On the other hand, those who experience success in a focal referendum may increase the proposed amount of a subsequent referendum depending on how much surplus voter support existed in the first referendum.Footnote 2 Of course, in many cases, costs are fixed. For example, in the area of land preservation, the cost of purchasing a farm to conserve cannot be adjusted—the jurisdiction must either purchase it at the cost the owners are willing to sell, or not purchase it. As a result, we are agnostic about the likelihood that PEs will (or can) go this route.

Second, PEs may seek to alter the date of the referendum to either get more voters by moving the referendum to the date of a well-attended major election or increase the proportion of special interest voters and advocates by moving the referendum to the date of a less attended special election (e.g. Berry and Gersen Reference Berry and Gersen2010; Anzia Reference Anzia2011; but see Kogan et al. Reference Kogan, Lavertu and Peskowitz2018). Meredith (Reference Meredith2009) finds that agenda-setters with power over the timing of a referendum will schedule referendums when other races on the ballot will attract voters that will support the measure. However, given that different election cycles exist in different locales, and that if an off-cycle or on-cycle election is beneficial to the PEs’ cause is likely context- and issue-specific, we are hesitant to expect uniform results. Some issues may benefit from a larger population voting, whereas others may benefit from a smaller population voting depending on the nature of the ideology of the area, and the ideological distance between the PEs, the active opponents, and the median voter (e.g. Dynes et al. Reference Dynes, Hartney and Hayes2021).

Third, advocates could attempt an alternative financing mechanism that is more favorable to voters after a failure. In particular, given the unpopularity of tax increases, one might expect proposals that initially asked for a tax but failed to be more likely to change to proposing a bond in order to increase support. But for those that have an initial success with a bond referendum, they may be motivated to attempt to secure a permanent fund through the passage of a tax. However, again, this strategic change may not be possible in all instances. If the PE is seeking the purchase of a large farm, bond financing is more appropriate than tax funding as a large sum is needed at one point in time, but no money is needed thereafter. As a result, we do not have preconceived hypotheses regarding systemic changes in this regard.

How do voters respond to changes to the referendum?

Lastly, we explore what effect these changes, when they do appear, have on voter support. We propose PEs generally understand how voters respond to referendum characteristics in their area and leverage their experience to modify subsequent referendums accordingly. Also, we suspect issues that appear on the ballot in repeat elections have a natural upward slope of support as voters get used to voting yes. Thus, we expect any changes to positively affect the election outcome and the vote margin.

Data and methods

In order to test our hypotheses, we use data from municipal referendums for open space preservation following a large literature on open space preservation proposals on state and local ballots (Altonji et al. Reference Altonji, Lang and Puggioni2016; Banzhaf et al. Reference Banzhaf, Oates and Sanchirico2010; Heintzelman et al. Reference Heintzelman, Walsh and Grzeskowiak2013, Kotchen and Powers Reference Kotchen and Powers2006; Sundberg Reference Sundberg2006; Nelson et al. Reference Nelson, Uwasu and Polasky2007, 2013; Lowry and Scott Krummenacher Reference Lowry and Scott Krummenacher2017; Lang et al. Reference Lang, Prendergast and Pearson-Merkowitz2018; Lowry Reference Lowry2018; Prendergast et al. Reference Prendergast, Pearson-Merkowitz and Lang2019; Pearson-Merkowitz and Lang Reference Pearson-Merkowitz and Lang2020; Lang and Pearson-Merkowitz Reference Lang and Pearson-Merkowitz2022). We use data from the Trust for Public Land’s LandVote database (TPL). The database is a comprehensive listing of state, county, special district, and municipal-level referendums to acquire and/or preserve land since 1988. For each referendum, TPL reports a description of the referendum, jurisdiction, total proposed funding of the ballot measure, total approved funding, proposed conservation-specific funding for land acquisition and protection, approved conservation funding, financing mechanism, election date, vote proportions for and against, as well as descriptive notes. This dataset has two major benefits. First, it is the only comprehensive dataset of bond referendums currently in existence. Second, a large literature exists on the determinants of voting outcomes for open space preservation proposals on state and local ballots that help inform our control variables and expectations (e.g. Heintzelman et al. Reference Heintzelman, Walsh and Grzeskowiak2013; Altonji et al. Reference Altonji, Lang and Puggioni2016; Prendergast et al. Reference Prendergast, Pearson-Merkowitz and Lang2019; Pearson-Merkowitz and Lang Reference Pearson-Merkowitz and Lang2020; Banzhaf et al. Reference Banzhaf, Oates and Sanchirico2010; Kotchen and Powers Reference Kotchen and Powers2006). In the coterminous USA, from 1988 to 2012, 1,031 municipalities held 1,640 referendums to acquire and preserve open spaces. Of the municipalities in our dataset, 351 held more than one referendum. See Tables A1 and A2 for a breakdown of sample referendums by year and by state.

We test our first hypotheses using a RD design, which allows for causal inference (Imbens and Lemieux Reference Imbens and Lemieux2008). Generally, treatment effects are estimated by comparing outcomes for treated units to control units. The problem with this simplistic method is that there are unobserved determinants of outcomes that can bias estimated treatment effects. RD improves inference by effectively comparing observations in a range close to the treatment threshold, that is, observations that are just barely treated or just barely not treated. By comparing observations that are close to the threshold, treatment status can be assumed as good as random. RD exploits this quasi-random treatment assignment to identify the casual effect.

In our application, we compare municipalities that have barely passed versus barely failed a referendum and test for differences in future referendum behavior. We model the number of subsequent referendums following a first referendum as a function the first referendum’s vote margin, which is the running variable. We test for a discontinuity in number of subsequent referendums around a threshold of a zero-vote margin,Footnote 3 representing a referendum that just barely passes or fails.

The first critical assumption of RD is that the potential outcomes of observations within this neighborhood are continuous. Therefore, any discontinuity in outcome across the threshold can be attributed directly to the outcome of the first referendum, instead of other confounding factors that may exist over the entire range of vote margins as would be the case if we employed OLS. We cannot test the assumption of continuous potential outcomes directly because we only observe one voting outcome for each referendum, but we can indirectly assess the assumption by comparing observable characteristics for municipalities that pass or fail. If there is balance between these groups, then our assumption is plausible. We matched municipalities to socioeconomic data in the 2000 USA. Decennial Census and present summary statistics for all municipalities in our dataset (Table 1, Column 1), municipalities that pass at least one referendum (Column 2) and that fail at least one referendum (Column 3), and municipalities that pass and fail with a vote margin within five percent (Columns 5 and 6, respectively), as well as t-statistics for the difference of means (Columns 4 and 7). Municipalities in our dataset have similar socioeconomic characteristics regardless of success or failure at the ballot box, especially those that have vote margins within five percent of passing. These similarities support the use of our RD framework; municipalities that hold referendums with vote margins near the cutoff point are statistically similar in observable characteristics and are likely to be similar in unobserved characteristics as well. In addition, we compare socioeconomic and referendum characteristics using an RD framework, both graphically and using regression (see Figure A1 and Table A4 in the Online Appendix). These analyses showed that socioeconomic and referendum characteristics are generally continuous in vote margin, supporting our assumption that any discontinuity in number of future referendums at the threshold is due to success or failure of a first referendum rather than another factor.

Table 1. Socioeconomic and demographic descriptive statistics

Notes: Socioeconomic and demographic data are from the 2000 U.S. Decennial Census for municipalities that held at least one open space referendum in the coterminous United States 1988-2012 according to the Trust for Public Land’s LandVote database. High school and college are educational attainment variables representing the percent of population that completed those degrees. Income is median household income. Recent construction represents the percent of houses constructed 1990-2000. Standard deviations are shown in parentheses

The second critical assumption of RD designs is that there is no manipulation of the running variable. The fact that many thousands of people vote on each of these referendums suggests that manipulation of the outcome is quite difficult. That being said, we still investigate this possibility rigorously. Figure A2 in the Online Appendix presents a density plot of every sample municipality’s first referendum, which forms the running variable. The data are noisy but do not indicate a clear discontinuity at the threshold. As a second and more formal test, we employ the Cattaneo et al. (Reference Cattaneo, Jansson and Ma2018) test of smoothness of the running variable’s density around the threshold. The p-value for the hypothesis of no discontinuity at the threshold is 0.571, indicating no statistical difference. Thus, this evidence suggests that there is no manipulation of the running variable.

Using a RD framework, Cellini et al. (Reference Cellini, Ferreira and Rothstein2010) find that districts that fail an initial school bond measure are more likely to pass a subsequent measure. If we were to simply model the number of subsequent referendums as a function of success or failure, then our estimates would compare municipalities that fail by a large margin to those that pass with a large margin, which are arguably very different in both observable and unobservable characteristics (likely introducing selection bias). The benefit of RD is that we control for vote margin and estimate only the local differential effect for ostensibly similar municipalities that barely fail or barely pass referendums. In fact, our empirical analysis compares our RD approach to a more traditional cross-sectional approach and finds results differ by an order of magnitude.

We illustrate our null and alternative hypotheses in the context of an RD framework in Figure 1, which shows patterns that may be observed in the data under the various hypotheses. Figure 1 plots the number of future referendums held as a function of vote margin in the first referendum, with the threshold for passage being a vote margin of zero. Our null hypothesis is represented by the graph on the left. We have given the relationship between vote margin and future referendums an intuitive positive slope (though this is not necessary for our research design), which would suggest that voters self-select into municipalities that match their preferences for open space and future referendums reflect these preferences but are not impacted by the outcome of the first referendum. The middle graph represents H1, where municipalities that just barely fail a first referendum are less likely to hold a future referendum relative to those that pass the first referendum. The discontinuous jump in likelihood of holding a subsequent referendum is apparent at the threshold. The right graph represents H2, where municipalities that just barely fail a first referendum are more likely to try again by holding future referendums, while those that pass are less likely to hold future referendums.Footnote 4

Figure 1. Intuition behind regression discontinuity design.

Notes: Each graph hypothesizes the number of future referendums held (vertical axis) as a function of vote margin for an initial referendum (horizontal axis). Points to the left of the vertical dashed line represent a failed initial referendum, while those to the right represent a passed first referendum. The left graph represents a scenario with no discontinuity around a zero-vote margin and the upward slope could be interpreted as preference-based sorting. The middle graph represents a scenario where municipalities that pass a referendum are encouraged to hold more in the future, while those that fail a referendum are discouraged from holding future referendums. The right graph represents a scenario where municipalities that just barely fail a referendum are more likely to hold future referendums to try again, while those that just barely pass a referendum are satiated and less likely to hold future referendums.

We generate two dependent variables for estimating temporal dynamics, the number of future referendums held and the number of future referendums passed in each municipality in our dataset. The number of future referendums held following a first referendum i by municipality m within $\tau $ years of a first referendum is defined by:

(1) $$held_{im}^\tau = \left\{ {\matrix{ {\mathop \sum \nolimits_t^{t + \tau } referendum\_hel{d_{mt}}} \cr {missing\;if\;i\;occured\;within\;\tau \;of\;the\;end\;of\;the\;dataset} \cr } } \right.$$

where $referendum\_hel{d_{mt}}$ equals one for each referendum held in municipality m between t and $t + \tau $ . If the entire time frame $\tau $ does not fall within the span of the dataset, we treat $held_{im}^\tau $ as missing. Because our analysis relies on a count of referendums, we discard observations where the first referendum occurs too close to the end of our dataset to have complete data for the number of future referendums. We likewise generate a dependent variable counting the number of referendums that pass within a time frame of the first referendum, $passed_{im}^\tau $ .

We create these variables for time frames $\tau $ of 1, 3, and 5 years. We include these time frames to account for collective local memory of past referendums assuming recent referendums are the more salient than older referendums. Additionally, each time frame may capture towns with different constraints. While some towns may be able to schedule a repeat election within 1 year, others may be financially or constitutionally constrained to the next normal election.Footnote 5

For illustration purposes, consider the example of Park Ridge Borough, NJ. Park Ridge held referendums in 2003, 2009, 2010 and 2012. We consider each of these referendums as the first referendum, in turn, and calculate the number of subsequent referendums held. When the 2003 referendum is considered the first referendum, the number of referendums held within 1, 3, and 5 years are all zero since the next referendum held was in 2009, 6 years past the date of the first observed referendum. When 2009 is considered the first referendum, the number of referendums held within 1 year equals 1 because of the 2010 referendum ( $hel_{2009,\;Park\;Ridge}^1 = 1$ ), the number of referendums held within 3 years equals 2 because of the 2010 and 2012 referendums ( $held_{2009,\;Park\;Ridge}^3 = 2$ ), and the number of referendums held within 5 years is not included in the model because the time frame extends past the end of our dataset ( $held_{2009,Park\;Ridge}^5 = missing$ ). In our regression model, each referendum is considered a first referendum and represents one observation.

Using our RD framework, we define the treatment variable to be failing a first referendum and model the number of referendums held (or passed) within $\tau $ years as a function of treatment and control flexibly for vote margin of first referendum i at time t:

(2) $$\eqalign{ & held_{imt}^\tau = {\beta ^\tau } \cdot fai{l_{imt}} + \gamma _1^\tau \cdot fai{l_{imt}} \cdot votemargi{n_{imt}} + \gamma _2^\tau \cdot fai{l_{imt}} \cdot votemargi{n_{imt}}^2 + \cr & \gamma _3^\tau \cdot fai{l_{imt}} \cdot votemargi{n_{imt}}^3 + \gamma _4^\tau \cdot votemargi{n_{imt}} + \gamma _5^\tau \cdot votemargi{n_{imt}}^2 \cr & + \gamma _6^\tau \cdot votemargi{n_{imt}}^3 + {{\boldsymbol{\delta ^\tau }}} \cdot {{\boldsymbol{X_{mt}}}} + \varepsilon _{imt}^\tau \cr}$$

where $held_{im}^\tau $ is defined by equation (1), $fai{l_{im}}$ is a binary variable equal to 1 if the first referendum i in municipality m failed, and ${\beta ^\tau }$ is our variable of interest. We interpret ${\beta ^\tau }$ as the differential number of referendums held within time frame $\tau $ following a fail outcome, ceteris paribus. A negative significant value of ${\beta ^\tau }$ suggests that a municipality that fails a first referendum is likely to hold fewer referendums in the future than a municipality that passes a first referendum. A positive significant value of ${\beta ^\tau }$ suggests that a municipality that fails a first referendum is likely to hold more votes in the future than a municipality that passes. An insignificant value of ${\beta ^\tau }$ indicates that the binary voting outcome has no discernible effect on the number of future referendums. In our preferred model (described in equation 2), we control for the vote margin of the first referendum using a cubic polynomial applied to either side of the threshold for passage. We also report the results from using a quadratic functional form and a local linear specification. We include a vector ${{\boldsymbol{X}}_m}$ of municipality socioeconomic characteristics, state fixed effects, and year fixed effects.Footnote 6 Last, $\varepsilon _{imt}^\tau $ is the error term. We use ordinary least squares estimation with robust standard errors clustered at the municipality level. Equally important, we also estimate Equation (2) using $passed_{imt}^\tau $ as the dependent variable.

Revisions

Our second analysis focuses on exploring revisions made to referendum characteristics and their effectiveness. We examine changes made to referendums in municipalities that hold more than one referendum. Our exploration begins with estimating how referendum characteristics change as a function of voting outcomes. Specifically, we look at revisionsFootnote 7 between a first referendum and the next subsequent referendum in total proposed funding (logged subsequent total proposed funding per capita minus logged first referendum total proposed funding per capita), percentage point change in proportion of conservation funding to total funding, whether the measure uses a bond as the financing mechanism, and whether the referendum was held in November of a presidential election year (e.g. Guber Reference Guber2003):

(3) $$revision_{im}^\tau = characteristi{c_{i + 1,m}} - characteristi{c_{im}}$$

As with our dependent variables in the referendum dynamics analysis, we use a time frame of 5 years following the first observed referendum. In addition to our reasoning in the temporal dynamics framework, we include this time frame to account for collective local memory and political relevance of past referendums. Only pairs of first and subsequent referendums are included in our sample for this analysis. One argument against this method is that selection bias is likely to exist for those municipalities that decide to hold a subsequent referendum. While this is true, we argue that because we restrict our sample to include only municipalities that held more than one referendum, selection bias is present across all municipalities in this sample, and our coefficient of interest will still have a valuable interpretation with internal validity for municipalities that hold multiple referendums. We use OLS to estimate the model:

(4) $$revision_{imt}^\tau = {\beta ^\tau } \cdot fai{l_{imt}} + {{\boldsymbol{\delta ^\tau }}} \cdot {{\boldsymbol{Z_{mt}}}} + \varepsilon _{imt}^\tau $$

where $revision_{im}^\tau $ is defined in equation (3) and ${{\boldsymbol{Z_{mt}}}}$ is a vector including socioeconomic variables, a binary variable equal to 1 if the municipality is in Massachusetts or New Jersey,Footnote 8 and a binary variable equal to 1 if the subsequent referendum was held during the recession 2008–2012.Footnote 9 Here, ${\beta ^\tau }$ is again our variable of interest. A significant ${\beta ^\tau }$ indicates a significant difference in each revised characteristic between municipalities that fail versus pass their first referendum, which would suggest that municipalities strategically revise referendums.

Finally, we test whether these revisions are correlated with voter support of subsequent referendums to see if these changes are correlated with a larger vote margin. We model change in vote margin, $votemarginchange_{im}^\tau $ , of the subsequent referendum (within a 5-year time frame) as a function of revisions to referendum characteristics interacted with vote outcome of a first referendum:

(5) $$\eqalign{ votemarginchange_{imt}^5 & = {\alpha ^5} \cdot fai{l_{imt}} + {{\boldsymbol{\gamma ^5}}} \cdot {\boldsymbol{revisions_{imt}^5}} \cr & + \;{{\boldsymbol{\beta ^5}}} \cdot fai{l_{imt}} \cdot {\boldsymbol{revisions_{imt}^5}} + {{\boldsymbol{\delta ^5}}} \cdot {{\boldsymbol{Z_{mt}}}} + \varepsilon _{imt}^5 \cr}$$

Here, ${\boldsymbol{revisions_{imt}^5}}$ is a vector of all four possible revisions as defined above. The interaction of the revisions with $fai{l_{imt}}$ provides information about how the revisions differ by initial referendum outcome. ${{\boldsymbol{Z_{mt}}}}$ is defined as in equation (4).Footnote 10

In both Equations (4) and (5), we have moved away from the RD framework. The equations also simplify the set of control variables. These are necessary steps given the substantial reduction in sample size caused by focusing on municipalities that hold more than one referendum. However, changing from RD to standard OLS limits the causal interpretation of these results, and instead we encourage a more descriptive interpretation. In addition to estimating both models with the full sample, we also estimate them with a reduced sample of initial referendums within 10 percentage points of the passing threshold to incorporate the RD logic and improve the counterfactual.

Results

Referendum dynamics

We begin with Figure 2, which shows the number of future referendums held (top row) and passed (bottom row) within 1 year (left column), 3 years (middle column), and 5 years (right column) versus the vote margin of a first referendum, similar to the setup of Figure 1. The data are binned at two-percent intervals in vote margin, and data are fitted flexibly using a locally weighted (lowess) regression to illustrate the magnitude of the discontinuity around a vote margin of zero. The plots in the top row are most similar to the right-most plot in Figure 1, providing suggestive support for the alternative hypothesis that municipalities that fail a referendum try again while those that pass a referendum do not. Intuitively, the magnitude of the effect grows as the time frame increases; a longer time frame allows more opportunity to hold additional referendums. The bottom row of plots shows that municipalities that just barely fail a first referendum are also more likely to pass more future referendums than those that just barely pass. This observation lends additional support for the “try again” hypothesis.Footnote 11

Figure 2. Number of future referendums held and passed following an initial referendum.

Notes: Each graph displays the number of future referendums held (top row) and passed (bottom row) 1 year (left column), 3 years (middle column), and 5 years (right column) following an initial referendum. The vertical axis is number of referendums (note that y-axes vary in scale) and the horizontal axis is vote margin; points to the left of the dashed line represent a failed first referendum and points to the right of the dashed line represent a passed first referendum. Referendum vote margins are binned in 2% intervals and only vote margins between [-14, 34] are displayed, representing 95% of the dataset. Data are fitted flexibly using a locally weighted regression to illustrate the magnitude of the discontinuity around a vote margin of zero. Data are for municipality-level referendums in the coterminous USA 1988–2012 from the Trust for Public Land’s LandVote database.

Table 2 shows the results of the model described in equation (2) where panel (A) uses the number of referendums held within 5 years of an initial referendum as the dependent variable and panel (B) uses the number of referendums passed.Footnote 12 Column 1 uses a cubic polynomial to control for vote margin on either side of the threshold. Column 2 instead uses a quadratic polynomial. Columns 1 and 2 also include municipality-level socioeconomic demographics and state and year fixed effects. Column 3 uses a local linear functional form, applying the Calonico et al. (Reference Calonico, Cattaneo and Titiunik2014) optimal bandwidth. The model in Column 1 is our preferred model, and the coefficient of interest is interpreted as a change in the number of referendums. Specifically, for panel (A), a failed outcome on a first referendum leads to that municipality holding 0.472 more referendums within 5 years compared to a municipality that was successful in their first referendum, all else equal.Footnote 13

Table 2. The effect of a marginal vote for an initial referendum on referendums within 5 years

Notes: The dependent variable is number of referendums held (Panel A) and number of referendums passed (Panel B) within 5 years of a first referendum. The coefficient of interest is on Fail, a binary variable equal to 1 if the first referendum failed and 0 otherwise. Column 1 controls for vote margin on either side of the threshold for passage using a cubic polynomial. Column 2 instead uses a quadratic polynomial. Columns 1–2 include socioeconomic variables and state and year fixed effects. Column 3 applies the “rdrobust” local linear estimator developed by Calonico et al. (Reference Calonico, Cattaneo and Titiunik2014). The number of observations reported in Column 3 are the effective number of observations used after the optimal bandwidth is estimated. The effective number of observations is 567 in Panel A and 547 in Panel B. The implied bandwidth for Panel A is 9.105 and 8.783 for Panel B. Data are for municipality-level referendums held in the coterminous USA 1988–2012 from the Trust for Public Land’s LandVote database. Robust standard errors are in parentheses and clustered at the municipality level.

*, **, ***Significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.

Table 3 compares the effect of vote outcome on number of referendums held within a time frame ranging from 1 to 5 years following the initial referendum: column n corresponds to the number of referendums held (Panel A) and passed (panel B) within n years. The estimated effect on number of referendums held remains highly significant through all time frames and grows in magnitude from 0.3 more referendums held within 1 year to 0.5 more referendums held within 5 years following a failed first referendum.

Table 3. The effect of a marginal vote for an initial referendum on future referendums

Notes: The dependent variable is number of referendums held (Panel A) and number of referendums passed (Panel B) within y years of a first referendum. The coefficient of interest is on Fail, a binary variable equal to 1 if the first referendum failed and 0 otherwise. Each column represents a longer time frame of subsequent referendums, from within 1 subsequent year (Column 1) to 5 years (Column 5). The cubic polynomial in vote margin controls for vote margin on either side of the threshold for passage. Data are for municipality-level referendums held in the coterminous USA 1988–2012 from the Trust for Public Land’s LandVote database. Robust standard errors are in parentheses and clustered at the municipality level.

*, **, ***Significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.

Repeating this analysis using the number of referendums passed within a time frame as the dependent variable (panel B of Tables 2 and 3) shows a similar pattern with a smaller effect size. In Table 2, panel (B), a municipality that fails a first referendum passes 0.284 more referendums within the next 5 years than a municipality with a successful first referendum. Table 3 shows that the magnitude of the effect ranges from 0.1 to 0.3 referendums passed over the various time frames.Footnote 14

The magnitude of these results warrants discussion. In our opinion, they are large in the sense that because they imply that nearly half of municipalities try again after failure and over 25% of those that fail actually succeed in passing a subsequent referendum. Some intuition may suggest that communities would just give up after defeat by popular vote. That being said, it is important to note that, on average, funding for land conservation for communities that initially fail never reaches parity with communities that initially pass. This result follows from the 25% future passage rate and, as we will show in the next section, proposed funding declines for subsequent referendums.

Strategic behavior

Do PEs strategically revise characteristics such as proposed funding and financing mechanism in subsequent referendums? Our analysis here restricts our sample to include only those municipalities that hold more than one referendum. We present means for municipalities by initial outcome and difference in means along with results from our estimation of equation (4) in Table 4. Our models suggest that there is a significant relationship between the first outcome and the future proposed funding amount. Specifically, municipalities that fail a first referendum tend to decrease total proposed funding per capita by about 40% relative to those that pass.Footnote 15 The magnitude and significance of the relationship between the first outcome and revised funding degrade when only municipalities with marginal first outcomes are included, suggesting this strategic revision is driven by municipalities with a strong preference for open space rather than by municipalities attempting to garner additional support through strategic revisions following a marginal outcome.Footnote 16 We find no evidence of revising the proportion of conservation-specific funding.

Table 4. Revisions to subsequent referendum characteristics

Notes: Table presents changes to referendum characteristics within a 5-year time frame by first referendum outcome. Change in total proposed funding per capita is the difference between log(subsequent total proposed funding per capita) and log(first referendum total proposed funding per capita). Conservation proportion is a ratio of conservation-specific funding to total proposed funding, and change in conservation proportion is the subsequent proportion minus the first referendum proportion. Bond financing equals 1 if the municipality switched from a different financing mechanism to a bond, −1 if vice versa, and 0 if there is no change. Similarly, November of election year is equal to 1 if the municipality switched the subsequent ballot to coincide with a presidential election, −1 if vice versa, and 0 if there is no change. Column 5 controls for socioeconomic characteristics, whether the municipality is in MA or NJ, and whether the referendum occurred during the recession (2008–2012), with standard errors clustered at the municipality level.

*, **, ***Significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

There are no significant revisions to financing mechanism or the date of referendum. The majority of municipalities considered in the 5-year time frame do not revise the financing mechanism (86%), and of those municipalities that fail a first referendum, an equal number switch to taxes or to bonds (N = 5). The majority of our sample does not revise when they hold the subsequent referendum (68%). Nearly a fifth of municipalities move their subsequent referendums to November of an election year (18.9% of those who pass a first referendum and 20.0% of those who fail), while a relatively small proportion of municipalities that fail an initial referendum move the subsequent referendum to a date other than November of an election year (9.6% versus 14.3%).

Table 5 presents results of a regression of change in vote margin between subsequent referendums on the outcome of a first referendum and interactions with revisions to proposed total funding per capita and proportion of conservation-specific funding, finance mechanism, and date of the election. We control for socioeconomic characteristics, whether the municipality is in Massachusetts or New Jersey, and whether the subsequent referendum was held during the recession. Column 1 shows results for the entire sample, and Column 2 restricts the dataset to all first referendums within 10% of the cutoff point. Both columns present results for the 5-year time frame. First consider the model with all observations. Prior vote outcome is highly significant and positive, indicating that a failed referendum is likely to garner greater support in the subsequent election (an additional 11.3%) and a passed referendum is likely to garner less support (a decrease of 2.9%). We cannot conclusively infer the mechanism for this effect, but we offer two possible explanations. First, simple mean reversion: there is an average preference for open space and vote margin oscillates about this mean. A simple regression of change in vote margin on initial vote margin shows that this oscillation occurs around the 10% vote margin mark, consistent with mean voter support. However, a second explanation is that repeated exposure to referendums of a single topic increases the likelihood of voter support, until reaching a ceiling of support around 10% vote margin. Further research is necessary to confirm if either of these mechanisms is at play. For the sample restricted to marginal first outcomes, simply holding a subsequent referendum garners more support for all referendums. Municipalities that fail a first referendum by less than 10% increase voter support by 10.7% in the subsequent referendum. Municipalities that only marginally pass their first referendum are likely to garner an additional 4.4% on the subsequent referendum.

Table 5. Effects of revisions on vote margin of subsequent referendums

Notes: The dependent variable is change in vote margin (subsequent vote margin minus first vote margin) for a time frame of 5 years between referendums. Column 1 uses all observations, and Column 2 restricts the sample to only observations with the first referendum vote margin within 10% of the cutoff. Change in total proposed funding per capita is the difference between log(subsequent total proposed funding per capita) and log(first referendum total proposed funding per capita). Conservation proportion is a ratio of conservation-specific funding to total proposed funding, and change in conservation proportion is the subsequent proportion minus the first referendum proportion. Change in bond financing equals 1 if the municipality switched from a different financing mechanism to a bond, −1 if vice versa, and 0 if there is no change. Similarly, Change November election year ballot is equal to 1 if the municipality switched the subsequent ballot to coincide with a presidential election, −1 if vice versa, and 0 if there is no change. All columns include socioeconomic variables, a binary variable equal to 1 if the municipality is in Massachusetts or New Jersey, and a binary variable equal to 1 if the referendum is held during the recession 2008–2012. Data are for municipality-level referendums held in the coterminous USA 1988–2012 from the Trust for Public Land’s LandVote database. Robust standard errors are in parentheses and clustered at the municipality level.

*, **, ***Significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.

There is no significant effect of changes in proposed funding per capita for municipalities that pass an initial referendum, but this insignificance is suggestive of greater voter acceptance, given that these municipalities tend to increase funding amounts. For municipalities that marginally fail a first referendum, we find no correlation with a change in total funding per capita, but, for those whose referendums contain multiple topics (e.g. affordable housing and historic preservation as well), we do find a significant increase in voter support for increasing the proportion of funding specific to conservation. A one-tenth percentage point change in proportion of conservation funding to total funding is positively correlated with a 2.2 percent change in vote margin.

In the full sample (Column 1), switching from tax financing to bond financing significantly increases voter support for municipalities that pass their first referendum. This effect appears to be driven by a few municipalities that passed their first referendums using bond financing with vote margins greater than 25% (N = 44). Of this subsample, 35 municipalities proposed bond financing in the subsequent referendum, one switched from tax financing to bond financing, and eight switched from bond financing to tax financing. The average change in vote margin for those eight municipalities was −25.2%, but only three of these municipalities sacrificed enough support to fail the subsequent referendum. The coefficient on the interaction with fail is insignificant, indicating no difference in slope between outcomes. However, we cannot glean much insight because there are so few observations for municipalities that fail an initial referendum and then revised the financing mechanism (N = 10) and all of these municipalities passed their subsequent referendums with margins ranging from 4% to 26%, regardless of whether they revise to tax or bond financing.

Lastly, we find a significant correlation between election timing and change in vote margin. In the full sample (Column 1), moving the referendum to coincide with a presidential election correlates with an increase in vote margin for the set of municipalities that fail their first referendum. In the restricted sample, all municipalities with a marginal first outcome increase their vote margin when revising the timing of the subsequent referendum to November of an election year (or vice versa). Off-year elections such as midterms typically have reduced participation, which may allow advocates or special interest groups, who are more likely to participate, to hold more influence in referendum outcomes (e.g. Meredith Reference Meredith2009). Moving the subsequent referendum to coincide with a main election such as a presidential election with higher participation tends to increase voter support. This effect suggests that the general public, including those who do not necessarily identify as open space advocates, does indeed show a preference for open space, and when the public is less likely to vote (as in a month that does not coincide with a presidential election), there is less support for open space referendums.Footnote 17

Discussion

We research what happens following a failed or successful referendum, using referendums to preserve open space in US municipalities as our case study. Our results suggest that municipalities that fail a first referendum tend to hold another referendum in the near future, and that holding a repeat referendum increases the vote return enough that a second referendum is likely to pass. This suggests that advocates for policy changes benefit from a “try and try again” approach at the ballot box. Our evidence also suggests that places that have successful referendums tend to be smart about garnering that support for additional projects; towns that pass a first referendum and hold a subsequent referendum tend to ask for more money, and although it may decrease their vote share, the referendums still pass.

From these findings, we infer several important implications for political scientists, policy analysts, land planning scholars, and land economists. First, advocates do not seem to be put off by an initial failure if they come close to success. We find significant evidence that there is a “try and try again” approach and that it pays off. Second, these findings also indicate that policies can benefit from appearing on the ballot multiple times; vote margins increase in successive elections. Defeat is not the end of the road for a ballot proposition and reintroduction can gain support.Footnote 18

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/S0143814X23000119

Funding statement

This work was supported by the USDA National Institute of Food and Agriculture, Agricultural and Food Research Initiative Competitive Program, Agriculture Economics and Rural Communities, grant number: 2015-67024-22937.

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Footnotes

1 There are two means by which local referenda appear on the ballot: legislative referral and citizen ballot collection. Which one is employed is largely determined by the rules of the local jurisdiction. In addition, for many locales, the jurisdiction is required to have a vote if they wish to take on debt or raise taxes, in which case, even if the legislature is unanimous in its support, it must go to the electorate for ratification. We do not have data on the local jurisdictions’ rules regarding ballot access and mandatory votes. However, all of these would require a policy entrepreneur advocating for the policy change. In the case of legislative referenda, members of the legislature may be the policy entrepreneurs or they may be the intermediary between the entrepreneurs and the ballot, whereas when citizens gather signatures to place the issue on the ballot, a local citizen or group of citizens are the policy entrepreneurs.

2 For any given referendum, there is roughly a 75 percent chance of passage given how rarely referendums fail in the USA. PEs may be aware of the statistical chance of passage and propose subsequent referendums until they succeed. On the other hand, PEs may attribute success or failure to referendum characteristics and revise accordingly.

3 We define vote margin as the proportion of votes in favor of the referendum minus the proportion of votes needed for passage. Some referendums require a larger than 50% vote in favor to pass (e.g. 2/3rds support or 60% support). In our data, we treat these cutoffs as the votes needed for passage. So, each observation has its own cutoff for passage, but the vote margin is the difference between what is needed for passage and the actual vote.

4 It is important to note that one limitation of our modeling strategy is that we can only distinguish differences between municipalities that just barely fail or pass a referendum; we cannot know whether this discontinuity is caused by one group holding more referendums or by the other group holding fewer, we only know the relative difference in number of subsequent referendums held.

5 Results using timeframes of 2, 4, and 6 years are similar. Sample size decreases with longer time frames.

6 We include state and year fixed effects to account for statewide policies related to open space, governmental and public prioritization of open space needs among other macroeconomic factors, state-level differences in ease of policy-making using ballot measures (e.g. Bowler and Donovan Reference Bowler and Donovan2004), and yearly government budget changes. For example, Massachusetts and New Jersey enacted notable policies facilitating ballot measures and provision of open space at the municipal level (see Heintzelman et al. Reference Heintzelman, Walsh and Grzeskowiak2013 for an overview of New Jersey’s Green Acres Program and Kotchen and Powers Reference Kotchen and Powers2006 for an overview of Massachusetts’s Community Preservation Act).

7 Twenty-one municipalities voted on more than one ballot measure on the same day (N=55). Results of one measure cannot affect the appearance of a measure or strategically impact the characteristics of a measure that appears simultaneously. Therefore, we aggregated these measures using the sums of total proposed funding, proposed conservation funding, total approved funding, and approved conservation funding. Of municipalities that held multiple referendums on the same day, eight municipalities had measures that proposed different financing mechanisms and two municipalities passed one measure but failed the other.

8 We control for Massachusetts and New Jersey because both states have unique legislation that encourages local governments to adopt land preservation policies, as discussed in footnote 6. These two states have had the most referendums by a fair margin; see Table A2 in the Online Appendix.

9 We use binary control variables rather than fixed effects and omit the RD framework to free up degrees of freedom given the smaller sample size of municipalities that held at least two referendums.

10 One question, of course is if the municipality is holding a second referendum on the exact same land conservation question or if the future election regards a different plot of land or project. Unfortunately, our data does not allow us to tell if it is the exact same land conservation request (e.g. same land) or there is a different project put forward to voters. A good example here is Glasbury, Connecticut’s recent (2022) bond which asked voters for $3 million for land preservation. The Landvote database simply lists this bond’s subject as “Bond for the preservation of open space and purchase of development rights” and the actual wording of the ballot was no more specific. As a result, what we can tell is if they return to the electorate for a second attempt at the general purpose of land conservation, but not for the same project. We could infer from the change in amount requested which towns change plots, but given land prices change, we cannot be sure this inference would be correct. Land could get less or more expensive in the interim year.

11 Table A3 in the Online Appendix is a transition matrix detailing the vote margin of each focal referendum and the results of the next subsequent referendum and provides additional evidence for this hypothesis.

12 Table A5 in the Online Appendix presents results building up to the model described by equation (2), including a simple OLS estimate without controlling for vote margin. Table A6 in the Online Appendix presents coefficients on socioeconomic variables for 1-year and 5-year timeframes.

13 Because we are comparing municipalities that initially fail to those that initially pass, it is just as valid to interpret the results as communities that barely pass a referendum hold on average 0.472 fewer referendums in the future than communities that barely fail a referendum.

14 The RD results are robust to a falsification test that moves the passing vote margin threshold to +10 (see Table A7 in the Online Appendix).

15 We define proportional change in total proposed funding as log (subsequent total proposed funding) – log (first referendum total proposed funding). Therefore, percent change is calculated by exponentiating the difference (Column 4) and the regression coefficient (Column 5).

16 An alternative explanation is that significance decreases because the sample size decreases.

17 Table A8 in the Online Appendix presents an alternative version of Table 5 that changes the definition of November to include both presidential and midterm elections. The change to November is no longer associated with increased approval. This set of findings suggests that municipalities that pass a referendum and try again only get a bump in support if they hold the follow-up referendum in November of presidential year and not November of a midterm year.

18 Data availability statement. Replication materials are available in the Journal of Public Policy Dataverse at https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/ISIXLR and in Lang et al Reference Lang, Carrie and Pearson-Merkowitz.2023.

References

Altonji, Matthew, Lang, Corey, and Puggioni, Gavino. 2016. “Can Urban Areas Help Sustain the Preservation of Open Space? Evidence from Statewide Referenda.” Ecological Economics 130: 8291.Google Scholar
Anzia, Sarah F. 2011. “Election Timing and the Electoral Influence of Interest Groups.” The Journal of Politics 73 (2): 412–27.Google Scholar
Augenblick, Ned, and Nicholson, Scott. 2016. “Ballot Position, Choice Fatigue, and Voter Behaviour.” The Review of Economic Studies 83 (2): 460–80.Google Scholar
Banaszak, Lee Ann. 1996. 52 Why Movements Succeed or Fail: Opportunity, Culture, and the Struggle for Woman Suffrage. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer, Oates, Wallace E., and Sanchirico, James N.. 2010. “Success and Design of Local Referenda for Land Conservation.” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 29 (4): 769798.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R., and Jones, Bryan D.. 2010. Agendas and Instability in American Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Bechard, Andrew, Lang, Corey, and Pearson-Merkowitz, Shanna. Forthcoming. Voter Approval of Bond Referendums: The Role of Bond Amount and Ballot Characteristics. State Politics & Policy Quarterly.Google Scholar
Berry, Christopher R., and Gersen, Jacob E.. 2010. “The Timing of Elections.” The University of Chicago Law Review 77: 3764.Google Scholar
Bowler, Shaun, and Donovan, Todd. 2000. Demanding Choices: Opinion, Voting, and Direct Democracy. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Bowler, Shaun, and Donovan, Todd. 2004. “Measuring the Effect of Direct Democracy on State Policy: Not All Initiatives Are Created Equal.” State Politics & Policy Quarterly 4 (3): 345–63.Google Scholar
Brunner, Eric J., Robbins, Mark D., and Simonsen, Bill. 2021. “Property Tax Information and Support for School Bond Referenda: Experimental Evidence.” Public Administration Review 81 (3): 488–99.Google Scholar
Buffardi, Anne L., Pekkanen, Robert J., and Rathgeb Smith, Steven. 2015. “Shopping or Specialization? Venue Targeting among Nonprofits Engaged in Advocacy.” Policy Studies Journal 43 (2): 188206.Google Scholar
Burns, Nancy. 1994. The Formation of American Local Governments: Private Values in Public Institutions. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Calonico, Sebastian, Cattaneo, Matias D., and Titiunik, Rocio. 2014. “Robust nonparametric confidence intervals for regression-discontinuity designs.” Econometrica 82 (6): 22952326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cattaneo, Matias D., Jansson, Michael, and Ma, Xinwei. 2018. “Manipulation testing based on density discontinuity.” The Stata Journal, 18 (1): 234261.Google Scholar
Cellini, Stephanie Riegg, Ferreira, Fernando, and Rothstein, Jesse. 2010. “The Value of School Facility Investments: Evidence from a Dynamic Regression Discontinuity Design*.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (1): 215–61.Google Scholar
Cozza, Joseph Francesco, Elkins, Zachary, and Hudson, Alexander. 2021. “Reverse Mortgages and Aircraft Parts: The Arcane Referendum and the Limits of Citizen Competence.” Electoral Studies 74: 102408.Google Scholar
Donovan, Todd, and Bowler, Shaun. 1998. “Direct Democracy and Minority Rights: An Extension.” American Journal of Political Science 42, 10201024.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dyck, Joshua J., and Lascher, Edward L.. 2019. Initiatives without Engagement: A Realistic Appraisal of Direct Democracy’s Secondary Effects. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Dyck, Joshua J., and Pearson-Merkowitz, Shanna. 2019. “Ballot Initiatives and Status Quo Bias.” State Politics & Policy Quarterly 19 (2): 180207.Google Scholar
Dynes, Adam M., Hartney, Michael T., and Hayes, Sam D.. 2021. “Off-Cycle and Off Center: Election Timing and Representation in Municipal Government.” American Political Science Review 115 (3): 10971103.Google Scholar
Gerber, Elisabeth R., Bowler, Shaun, Donovan, Todd, and Tolbert, Caroline J.. 1998. “Pressuring Legislatures through the Use of the Initiatives: Two Forms of Indirect Influence.” Citizens as legislators: Direct democracy in the United States 191: 191.Google Scholar
Gray, Virginia, and Lowery, David. 2000. The Population Ecology of Interest Representation: Lobbying Communities in the American States. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Guber, Deborah L., 2003. The Grassroots of a Green Revolution: Polling America on the Environment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Heintzelman, Martin D., Walsh, Patrick J., and Grzeskowiak, Dustin J.. 2013. “Explaining the Appearance and Success of Open Space Referenda.” Ecological Economics 95: 108–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Imbens, Guido W., and Lemieux, Thomas 2008. “Regression discontinuity designs: A guide to practice.” Journal of Econometrics, 142 (2): 615635. Google Scholar
Karch, Andrew, and Rosenthal, Aaron. 2016. “Vertical Diffusion and the Shifting Politics of Electronic Commerce.” State Politics & Policy Quarterly 16 (1): 2243.Google Scholar
Kathlene, Lyn, Clarke, Susan E., and Fox, Barbara A.. 1991. “Ways Women Politicians Are Making a Difference.” In Debra L. Dodson Gender and Policymaking: Studies of Women in Office, 31–38.Google Scholar
Kingdon, John. 1994. Issues, Agendas, and Alternatives. Boston, MA: Little Brown Google Scholar
Kogan, Vladimir, Lavertu, Stéphane, and Peskowitz, Zachary. 2017. “Direct Democracy and Administrative Disruption.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 27 (3): 381–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kogan, Vladimir, Lavertu, Stéphane, and Peskowitz, Zachary. 2018. “Election Timing, Electorate Composition, and Policy Outcomes: Evidence from School Districts.” American Journal of Political Science 62 (3): 637–51.Google Scholar
Kotchen, Matthew J., and Powers, Shawn M.. 2006. “Explaining the Appearance and Success of Voter Referenda for Open-Space Conservation.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 52 (1): 373–90.Google Scholar
Lang, Corey. 2018. Assessing the Efficiency of Local Open Space Provision.” Journal of Public Economics, 158: 1224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lang, Corey, Carrie, Gill, Pearson-Merkowitz., Shanna 2023. “Replication Data for: The Aftermath of Ballot Box Success and Failure: Evidence from Land Preservation Referendums.” Mar 15, 2023. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/ISIXLR, Harvard Dataverse, V1, UNF:6:LcYQTeDfnAvqw+Che2ssNw== [fileUNF] (accessed 19 July 2023).Google Scholar
Lang, Corey, and Pearson-Merkowitz, Shanna. 2022. “Aggregate data yield biased estimates of voter preferences.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 111, 102604.Google Scholar
Lang, Corey, Prendergast, Patrick, and Pearson-Merkowitz, Shanna. 2018. “How Does Municipal Policy Affect State and Local Actions? Evidence from Land Conservation Spending.” Resource and Energy Economics 54: 2336.Google Scholar
Lang, Corey, Wichman, Casey J., Weir, Michael J., and Pearson-Merkowitz, Shanna. 2022. “Cost Misperception and Voting for Public Goods.” Working Paper. Available at: https://digitalcommons.uri.edu/enre_working_papers/5/ (accessed 19 July 2023).Google Scholar
Ley, Aaron J. 2016. “Vested Interests, Venue Shopping, and Policy Stability: The Long Road to Improving Air Quality in Oregon’s Willamette Valley.” Review of Policy Research 33 (5): 506–25.Google Scholar
Ley, Aaron J., and Weber, Edward P.. 2015. “The Adaptive Venue Shopping Framework: How Emergent Groups Choose Environmental Policymaking Venues.” Environmental Politics 24 (5): 703–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lowry, William R. 2018. “The Exceptionalism of the Open Space Issue in American Politics.” Social Science Quarterly 99 (4): 1363–76.Google Scholar
Lowry, William R., and Scott Krummenacher, W.. 2017. “Coalitions and Conservation: Conditional Impacts of Coalitions on Ballot Measures for Open Space.” Review of Policy Research 34 (3): 357–77.Google Scholar
Lupia, Arthur. 1994. “The Effect of Information on Voting Behavior and Electoral Outcomes: An Experimental Study of Direct Legislation.” Public Choice 78 (1): 6586.Google Scholar
Matsusaka, John G. 2008. For the Many or the Few: The Initiative, Public Policy, and American Democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Matsusaka, John G. 2018. “Public Policy and the Initiative and Referendum: A Survey with Some New Evidence.” Public Choice 174 (1): 107–43.Google Scholar
Meredith, Marc. 2009. “The Strategic Timing of Direct Democracy.” Economics & Politics 21 (1): 159–77.Google Scholar
Mintrom, Michael, and Norman, Phillipa. 2009. “Policy Entrepreneurship and Policy Change.” Policy studies journal 37 (4): 649–67.Google Scholar
Morisi, Davide. 2018. “Choosing the Risky Option: Information and Risk Propensity in Referendum Campaigns.” Public Opinion Quarterly 82 (3): 447–69.Google Scholar
Nelson, Erik, Uwasu, Michinori, and Polasky, Stephen. 2007. “Voting on Open Space: What Explains the Appearance and Support of Municipal-Level Open Space Conservation Referenda in the United States?Ecological Economics 62 (3): 580–93.Google Scholar
Pearson-Merkowitz, Shanna, and Lang, Corey. 2020. “Smart Growth at the Ballot Box: Understanding Voting on Affordable Housing and Land Management Referendums.” Urban Affairs Review 56 (6): 1848–75.Google Scholar
Petridou, Evangelia, and Mintrom, Michael. 2021. “A Research Agenda for the Study of Policy Entrepreneurs.” Policy Studies Journal 49 (4): 943–67.Google Scholar
Prendergast, Patrick, Pearson-Merkowitz, Shanna, and Lang, Corey. 2019. “The Individual Determinants of Support for Open Space Bond Referendums.” Land Use Policy 82: 258–68.Google Scholar
Roberts, Nancy C., and King, Paula J.. 1991. “Policy Entrepreneurs: Their Activity Structure and Function in the Policy Process.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 1 (2): 147–75.Google Scholar
Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1978. “Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas, and the Status Quo.” Public Choice 33 (4): 2743.Google Scholar
Smith, Daniel A., and Tolbert, Caroline. 2009. Educated by Initiative: The Effects of Direct Democracy on Citizens and Political Organizations in the American States. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Sundberg, Jeffrey O. 2006. Voting for Public Funding of Open Space. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.Google Scholar
Weissert, Carol S. 1991. “Policy Entrepreneurs, Policy Opportunists, and Legislative Effectiveness.” American Politics Quarterly 19 (2): 262–74.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Socioeconomic and demographic descriptive statistics

Figure 1

Figure 1. Intuition behind regression discontinuity design.Notes: Each graph hypothesizes the number of future referendums held (vertical axis) as a function of vote margin for an initial referendum (horizontal axis). Points to the left of the vertical dashed line represent a failed initial referendum, while those to the right represent a passed first referendum. The left graph represents a scenario with no discontinuity around a zero-vote margin and the upward slope could be interpreted as preference-based sorting. The middle graph represents a scenario where municipalities that pass a referendum are encouraged to hold more in the future, while those that fail a referendum are discouraged from holding future referendums. The right graph represents a scenario where municipalities that just barely fail a referendum are more likely to hold future referendums to try again, while those that just barely pass a referendum are satiated and less likely to hold future referendums.

Figure 2

Figure 2. Number of future referendums held and passed following an initial referendum.Notes: Each graph displays the number of future referendums held (top row) and passed (bottom row) 1 year (left column), 3 years (middle column), and 5 years (right column) following an initial referendum. The vertical axis is number of referendums (note that y-axes vary in scale) and the horizontal axis is vote margin; points to the left of the dashed line represent a failed first referendum and points to the right of the dashed line represent a passed first referendum. Referendum vote margins are binned in 2% intervals and only vote margins between [-14, 34] are displayed, representing 95% of the dataset. Data are fitted flexibly using a locally weighted regression to illustrate the magnitude of the discontinuity around a vote margin of zero. Data are for municipality-level referendums in the coterminous USA 1988–2012 from the Trust for Public Land’s LandVote database.

Figure 3

Table 2. The effect of a marginal vote for an initial referendum on referendums within 5 years

Figure 4

Table 3. The effect of a marginal vote for an initial referendum on future referendums

Figure 5

Table 4. Revisions to subsequent referendum characteristics

Figure 6

Table 5. Effects of revisions on vote margin of subsequent referendums

Supplementary material: File

Gill et al. supplementary material

Gill et al. supplementary material

Download Gill et al. supplementary material(File)
File 274.4 KB