Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-21T23:23:40.189Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Democracy and Productivity: The Glass-Steagall Act and the Shifting Discourse of Financial Regulation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 September 2012

K. Sabeel Rahman*
Affiliation:
Harvard University

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Donald Critchlow and Cambridge University Press 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

NOTES

1. See, e.g., Barack Obama, speech on financial regulation, Cooper Union, New York, 22 April 2010. Transcript available at http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2010/04/22/obamas-wall-street-speech_n_547880.html(accessed April 2011).

2. See, e.g., Johnson, Simon and Kwak, James, 13 Bankers: The Wall Street Takeover and the Next Financial Meltdown (New York, 2011).Google Scholar

3. Public Law 73-66, 48 Stat. 162, enacted 16 June 1933. The Glass-Steagall Act, which effectuated the separation of commercial and investment banking, was codified in §§16, 20, 21, and 32 of this statute.

4. Specifically, Section 16 of the bill restricts the securities activities of national banks, especially by prohibiting them from underwriting corporate securities. Section 20 prohibits member banks of the Federal Reserve system from being affiliated with any entity involved in the sale or transactions of securities. Section 32 prohibits any officer, director, or employee links between member banks and other individuals engaged in securities firms. Section 21 outlaws any person engaged in securities activities to also engage at the same time in deposit banking to any extent. The Banking Act also strengthened the regulatory powers of the Federal Reserve Bank.

5. See, e.g., Benston, George, The Separation of Commercial and Investment Banking: The Glass-Steagall Act Revisited and Reconsidered (New York, 1990).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

6. Kelly, Edward, “Legislative History of the Glass-Steagall Act,” in Derugulating Wall Street, ed. Walter, Ingo (New York, 1985), 4166Google Scholar; Perkins, Edwin, “The Divorce of Commercial and Investment Banking: A History,” Banking Law Journal 88, no. 6 (June 1971): 483528.Google Scholar

7. See, e.g., Sandel, Michael, Democracy’s Discontent: America in Search of a Public Philosophy (Cambridge, Mass., 1998)Google Scholar; Brinkley, Alan, The End of Reform: New Deal Liberalism in Recession and War (New York, 1996Google Scholar; Donohue, Kathleen, Freedom from Want: American Liberalism and the Idea of the Consumer (Baltimore, 2005).Google Scholar

8. See, e.g., Benston, The Separation of Commercial and Investment Banking; Kroszner, Randall S. and Rajan, Raghuram G., “Organization Structure and Credibility: Evidence from Commercial Bank Securities Activities Before the Glass-Steagall Act,” Journal of Monetary Economics 39 (1997): 475516CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Kroszner, and Rajan, , “Is the Glass-Steagall Act Justified? A Study of the U.S. Experience with Universal Banking Before 1933,” American Economic Review 84, no. 4 (September 1994): 810–32Google Scholar; Barth, James, Brumbaugh, R. Dan Jr., and Wilcox, James, “Policy Watch: The Repeal of Glass-Steagall and the Advent of Broad Banking,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 14, no. 2 (Spring 2000): 191204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9. See Obama, speech on financial regulation.

10. See, e.g., Johnson and Kwak, 13 Bankers.

11. Kelly, “Legislative History of the Glass-Steagall Act”; Perkins, “The Divorce of Commercial and Investment Banking.”

12. Kelly, “Legislative History of the Glass-Steagall Act,” 43.

13. Much of the following legislative history is recounted in more detail in ibid.; and Perkins, “The Divorce of Commercial and Investment Banking.”

14. Perkins, “The Divorce of Commercial and Investment Banking,” 518.

15. On FDR’s electoral campaign and strategy, see Schlesinger, Arthur, The Crisis of the Old Order, 1919–1933 (Boston, 1957).Google Scholar

16. See National Archives, Washington, D.C. Documents pertaining to Glass-Steagall Act, bill numbers S. 3215, S. 4115, S. 4412 (72nd Congress, 1932–33); S. 245, S. 1631 (73rd Congress, 1933).

17. Perkins, “The Divorce of Commercial and Investment Banking.” 520–21.

18. It was noted at the time that the president of the New York bank, Bernard Marcus, had appropriated huge sums of bank funds for his own speculative ventures, which largely failed. The result was a huge wave of public attention and criticism, generating a new distrust of affiliates. See ibid., 497.

19. I am grateful to an anonymous reviewer for pointing this out.

20. Kelly, “Legislative History of the Glass-Steagall Act,” 53.

21. “Bank Bill Held Up for Woodin Views,” New York Times, 19 April 1933; “Bank Bill Taken Up with President,” New York Times,5 May 1933.

22. “Roosevelt Favors Pushing Bank Bill,” New York Times, 6 May 1933; “Bank Reform Bill Swiftly Approved,” New York Times,14 June 1933.

23. I am grateful to an anonymous reviewer for pointing this out.

24. See Hammond, Brey, Banks and Politics in America: From the Revolution to the Civil War (Princeton, 1957)Google Scholar. As Hammond writes, “Taking advantage of the traditional agrarian aversion to banks and of President Jackson’s particularly, the entrepreneurial rebels attacked what they called the monopoly and the tyranny of the federal Bank, ended its existence, neutralized the federal government’s constitutional responsibility for the currency, made banking a business free to all, and thereby insured to enterprise an abundance of bank and credit” (740–41).

25. Brandeis, Louis, Other People’s Money and How the Bankers Use It (New York, 1967), 1213.Google Scholar

26. Ibid., 34.

27. Ibid., 46–48.

28. Ibid., 69.

29. For the cross-currents of Progressive thought more generally, and the tensions between these democratic antitrusters and more technocratic reformers, see Hofstadter, Richard, The Age of Reform (New York, 1974)Google Scholar; and Rodgers, Daniel, “In Search of Progressivism,” Reviews in American History 10, no. 4 (1982).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

30. Schlesinger, Arthur, The Coming of the New Deal (Boston, 1959), 444.Google Scholar

31. Hawley, Ellis, The New Deal and the Problem of Monopoly: A Study in Economic Ambivalence (Princeton, 1966), 306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

32. Carosso, Vincent, Investment Banking in America (Cambridge, Mass., 1970), 353.Google Scholar

33. As I will argue in Part IV, these Progressive narratives nevertheless played a vital background role in mobilizing support for the New Deal reforms.

34. Benston, The Separation of Commercial and Investment Banking,173–78. It is worth noting that Benston is in general critical of Glass-Steagall as being based on a faulty empirical understanding by the New Dealers themselves as to the nature of the 1929–33 banking crisis. Benston himself is part of the wave of studies attempting to delegitimize Glass-Steagall as a valid policy reform, arguing instead for its repeal in the 1980s and 1990s. I will address this push by Benston and others in Part V.

35. Rodgers, “In Search of Progressivism,” 413–15.

36. See, e.g., Graham, Otis, An Encore for Reform: The Old Progressives and the New Deal (New York, 1967).Google Scholar

37. See Seligman, Joel, The Transformation of Wall Street (New York, 2003), 4151.Google Scholar

38. Moley in ibid., 40.

39. Perkins, “The Divorce of Commercial and Investment Banking,” 500. Perkins bases his characterization of Glass on Glass’s own writings in letters and his statements in the Congressional Record. See 500–502 and notes 40–42.

40. It is worth noting, however, that this view mischaracterizes Brandeis’s own argument. Brandeis’s attack on bigness did not necessarily mean a celebration of localism. As Philippa Strum argues, Brandeis instead called for firms and organizations that were large enough to ensure efficiency but small enough to be controlled by a democratic public. See Strum, , Brandeis: Beyond Progressivism (Lawrence, Kans., 1995)CrossRefGoogle Scholar See also Brandeis’s written dissents in New State Ice Company v. Liebman (1931) and Liggett v. Lee (1933), in Strum, ed., Brandeis on Democracy(Lawrence, Kans., 1995), 138–53.

41. Hearings, Subcommittee of the Committee on Banking and Currency, “Operation of National and Federal Reserve Banking Systems. U.S. Senate, 71st Cong., 1st sess., 19 January 1931, 3.

42. Glass, Hearings, 4 February 1931, 365. It is worth noting that Glass took the opportunity in the hearings to castigate some witnesses who years earlier had opposed the Federal Reserve Act as a threat to individualism and commerce, but who now appeared before the subcommittee accepting of the Federal Reserve as a vital component of the national financial system. See Hearings, 17 February 1931, 417–18.

43. Glass, 9 May 1932, 75 Congressional Record,9887.

44. Ibid., 9892.

45. Buckley, 9 May 1932, 75 Congressional Record,9911.

46. Ibid.

47. Ibid., 9912.

48. Vandenberg, 9 May 1932, 75 Congressional Record,9913.

49. Norbeck, 30 April 1932, 75 Congressional Record,9300.

50. Ibid.

51. Ibid., 9301.

52. Nye, 20 January 1933, 76 Congressional Record,2153–54.

53. Wheeler, 20 January 1933, 76 Congressional Record,2146.

54. Shannon, 19 May 1933, 77 Congressional Record,3751. Congressman Shannon was a Democrat of Missouri.

55. Weideman, 19 May 1933, 77 Congressional Record,3751. Congressman Weideman was a Democrat of Michigan.

56. Shannon, 19 May 1933, 77 Congressional Record,3760.

57. Lemke, 22 May 1933, 77 Congressional Record,3907. Congressman Lemke was a populist Republican of North Dakota.

58. Keller, 22 May 1933, 77 Congressional Record,3913. Congressman Keller was a Democrat of Illinois. It is interesting to note that these opponents were also challenging the notion of central bank independence, concerned that the removal of the Treasury Secretary from Federal Reserve Board membership and the provisions enabling the Fed to retain any profits from its own reserves rather than funneling them to the Treasury would create an institution dangerously free to pursue the private, rather than public, interest. As Keller continued: “It [the Federal Reserve Bank] is entirely privately owned. It does not belong to the people of the United States or to the United States Government—not one dollar of it.”

59. Weideman, 22 May 1933, 77 Congressional Record,3922–23.

60. Steagall, 20 May 1933, 77 Congressional Record,3835.

61. Kopplemann, 22 May 1933, 77 Congressional Record,3907.

62. Luce, 22 May 1933, 77 Congressional Record,3914.

63. Wheeler, 20 January 1933, 76 Congressional Record,2146.

64. “Held Deflation Measure,” New York Times, 19 March 1932; “Bankers Denounce Glass Bill’s Terms,” New York Times, 24 March 1932; “Glass Bill Called Bar to Recovery,” New York Times, 29 March 1932; “The ABA and the Glass Bill,” Bankers’ Magazine 124, no. 4 (April 1932): 409; “Assert Recovery Waits on Congress,” New York Times, 2 May 1932; “ABA Objections to Glass Bill,” Wall Street Journal,2 May 1932.

65. “Prospective Banking Legislation,” Bankers’ Magazine 125, no. 4 (October 1932): 311; Haas, J. J., President of the American Bankers Association, “Reply to the Critics of Banking,” Bankers’ Magazine 125, no. 5 (November 1932)Google Scholar; “A Proposal for Real Banking Reform,” Bankers’ Magazine127, no. 5 (November 1933): 490.

66. See Section V.

67. Hearings, Subcommittee of the Committee on Banking and Currency, “Operation of National and Federal Reserve Banking Systems. U.S. Senate, 71st Cong., 1st sess., Appendix, 999–1058. It should be noted that actually small banks failed more and the key issue for bank stability as a policy matter was in fact the establishment of deposit insurance. But Glass used these findings to push his vision of bigger national-scale banks that were stripped of their securities affiliates—thus avoiding the conflicts of interest that arose from affiliate activities, but retaining the financial and economic benefits of larger, more centralized banks.

68. Wide Effect Seen in New Bank Law,” New York Times, 27 February 1927; “National Bank Expansion,” Wall Street Journal, 20 June 1927; “Bank Stocks Reach New Record Highs,” New York Times, 18 May 1927. National Bank Expansion,” Wall Street Journal,20 June 1927.

69. “Untermeyer Praises Aims of Glass Bill” New York Times,25 April 1932.

70. See Pecora, Ferdinand, Wall Street Under Oath: The Story of Our Modern Money Changers (New York, 1968).Google Scholar

71. Ibid., 283.

72. “Stock Exchange Practices,” Report of the Committee on Banking and Currency, June 1934, 73rd Cong., 2nd sess., Report No. 1455, 113.

73. Ibid., 186.

74. Franklin Delano Roosevelt, Campaign Address at Columbus, Ohio, 20 August 1932. Available online at http://newdeal.feri.org/speeches/1932e.htm.

75. Ibid.

76. Ibid.

77. “Says Roosevelt Is for Bank Bill,” Wall Street Journal,10 January 1933.

78. Willis, H. Parker, Chapman, John, and Robey, Ralph West, Contemporary Banking (New York, 1933)Google Scholar; see also Willis, H. Parker, “The Banks and You,” Modern Problem Series no. 17 (Columbus, Ohio, 1933).Google Scholar

79. Willis, Chapman, and Robey, Contemporary Banking,12.

80. See Hearings, Subcommittee of the Committee on Banking and Currency, “Operation of National and Federal Reserve Banking Systems. U.S. Senate, 71st Cong., 1st sess., 23 February 1931, 479–96.

81. Glass, 9 May 1932, 75 Congressional Record, 9883. Simon Johnson, “Why Don’t the Community Banks Get It?” Baseline Scenario, 3 August 2009, http://baselinescenario.com/2009/08/03/why-dont-the-community-banks-get-it/.

82. Ibid.

83. Ibid., 9891.

84. Ibid.

85. Glass, 17 January 1933, 76 Congressional Record,1937.

86. See, e.g., National Archives, Washington, D.C. Documents pertaining to Glass-Steagall Act, bill numbers S. 3215, S. 4115, S. 4412 (72nd Congress, 1932–33); S. 245, S. 1631 (73rd Congress, 1933).

87. See, for example, Sandel, Democracy’s Discontent; Brinkley, The End of Reform; Donohue, Freedom from Want,2005.

88. Benston, The Separation of Commercial and Investment Banking.

89. Kroszner and Rajan, “Organization Structure and Credibility,” and “Is the Glass-Steagall Act Justified?”

90. See Barth et al., “Policy Watch,” 2000. It is remarkable how the arguments for the repeal of Glass-Steagall echoed those offered by the banking sector in 1932–33: it was argued that combining commercial and investment banking was safe, would provide greater consumer choice and options, while further regulation would simply constrain the ability of banks to help finance productive economic development.

91. See, e.g., Labaton, “Antitrust Chief Hits Resistance in Crackdown,” New York Times,25 July 2009.

92. Simon Johnson, “Why Don’t the Community Banks Get It?”

93. “ABA Testifies on Proposal to Create a Consumer Financial Protection Agency,” News Release, 24 June 2009, http://www.aba.com/Press+Room/062409ABATestifiesCFPA.htm. 2009; Johnson, “Why Don’t the Community Banks Get It?

94. See Ramirez, Carlos D. and De Long, J. Bradford, “Understanding America’s Hesitant Steps Toward Financial Capitalism: Politics, the Depression, and the Separation of Commercial and Investment Banking,” Public Choice 106 (2001): 93116CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Perkins, “The Divorce of Commercial and Investment Banking,” 516; “Roosevelt Seeks Law to Regulate Securities,” New York Times,17 March 1933.

95. Lavaque-Manty, Mika, Arguments with Fists: Political Agency and Justification in Liberal Theory (New York, 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, Carpenter, Daniel and Sin, Gisela, “Policy Tragedy and the Emergence of Regulation: The Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act of 1938,” Studies in American Political Development 21 (Fall 2007): 149–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Stone, Deborah, “Causal Stories and the Formation of Policy Agendas,” Political Science Quarterly 104, no. 2 (Summer 1989): 281300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

96. See Hall, Peter, “Conclusion: The Politics of Keynesian Ideas,” in The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism Across Nations, ed. Hall (Princeton, 1989).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

97. Indeed, a cursory look at some of the empirical literature building up to the repeal of Glass-Steagall in 1999 exhibits a preoccupation with the explicit economic arguments offered by Glass-Steagall proponents in 1933, rather than the underlying democratic accountability arguments offered by Brandeis and others. The arguments for the repeal of Glass-Steagall seem to echo those offered by the banking sector in 1932–33: it was argued that combining commercial and investment banking was safe, would provide greater consumer choice and options, while further regulation would simply constrain the ability of banks to help finance productive economic development. Some studies in the 1990s suggested that securities affiliates were not in fact selling risky assets, and were less likely to fail. Market pressures, it was argued, forced banks to self-regulate by offering higher-quality securities, rather than engaging in risky speculation. If Glass-Steagall is premised on the need to prevent such speculation and bank failure through regulation, then it would seem that on economic grounds, regulation had become a constraint rather than enabler of productivity. See Benston, The Separation of Commercial and Investment Banking; Kroszner and Rajan, “Organization Structure and Credibility,” and “Is the Glass-Steagall Act Justified?”; and Barth et al., “Policy Watch.”

98. Pecora, Wall Street Under Oath,303.