Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T12:11:10.747Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Education, demographics, and the economy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 November 2007

CHRISTIAN JAAG
Affiliation:
Institiute of Public Finance and Fiscal Law, University of St. Gallen, Varnbüelstrasse 19, CH-9000St. Gallen (e-mail: [email protected])

Abstract

This paper deals with two issues concerning the effects of population aging on education decisions in the presence of a PAYG pension system: We first analyze the effects of an aging population per se on individual skill choices and continuous education and the production structure. Second, we study the implications of postponed retirement, which is often proposed as a measure to cope with the economic challenges of increased longevity. Our study uses a dynamic general equilibrium framework with overlapping generations and probabilistic aging. The model allows for capital–skill complementarity in the production of final output.

As a response to population aging, in a small open economy with a fixed interest rate, our first simulation shows that GDP is depressed due to an adverse effect on skill choice and labor supply. We then introduce postponed retirement as a potentially dampening policy measure due to its encouragement of human capital formation. However, since there is less private saving in this scenario, the overall effect on GDP is even worse than in the pure aging scenario.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 2007 Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. (1998) Why do new technologies complement skills? Directed technical change and wage inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(4): 10551089.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altig, D., Auerbach, A. J., Kotlikoff, L. J., Smetters, K. A. and Walliser, J. (2001) Simulating fundamental tax reform in the United States. American Economic Review, 91(3): 574595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andersen, T. M. (2005) Social security and longevity. CESifo Working Paper 1577.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auerbach, A. J. and Kotlikoff, L. J. (1987) Dynamic Fiscal Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. (1991) Economic growth in a cross section of countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2): 407443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1962) Investment in human capital: a theoretical analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 70(5): 949.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1993) Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 3rd edn.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Porath, Y. (1967) The production of human capital and the life cycle of earnings. Journal of Political Economy, 75(4): 352365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
BFS (2001) Szenarien zur Bevölkerungsentwicklung der Schweiz 2000–2060. Neuchâtel: Bundesamt für Statistik.Google Scholar
BFS (2004) Die Schweizerische Arbeitskräafteerhebung (sake). Neuchâtel: Bundesamt für Statistik.Google Scholar
Bils, M. and Klenow, P. J. (2000) Does schooling cause growth? American Economic Review, 90(5): 11601183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blackorby, C. and Russell, R. R. (1989) Will the Real Elasticity of Substitution Please Stand Up? (A Comparison of the Allen-Uzawa and Morishima Elasticities). American Economic Review, 79(4): 882888.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. J. (1985) Debt, deficits and finite horizons. Journal of Political Economy, 93(2): 223247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blundell, R. and Bond, S. (2000) GMM estimation with persistent panel data: an application to production functions. Econometric Reviews, 19(2): 321340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blundell, R., Dias, M. C., and Meghir, C. (2003) The impact of wage subsidies: a general equilibrium. IFS Working Paper.Google Scholar
Blundell, R. and MaCurdy, T. (1999) Labor supply: a review of alternative approaches. In Ashenfelter, O. and Card, D. (eds), Handbook of Labor Economics, vol. 3. Amsterdam: Elsevier, chap. 27.Google Scholar
Börsch-Supan, A. (2000) Incentive effects of social security on labor force participation: evidence in Germany and across Europe. Journal of Public Economics, 78(1): 2549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Börsch-Supan, A. (2003) Labor market effects of population aging. Review of Labor Economics and Industrial Relations, 17(special issue): 544.Google Scholar
Börsch-Supan, A., Ludwig, A., and Winter, J. (2004) Aging, pension reform, and capital flows. University of Mannheim MEA Working Paper.Google Scholar
Börsch-Supan, A. and Winter, J. K. (2001) Population aging, savings behavior, and capital markets. NBER Working Paper 8561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucekkine, R., de la Croix, D., and Licandro, O. (2002) Vintage human capital, demographic trends, and endogenous growth. Journal of Economic Theory, 104(2): 340375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucekkine, R., de la Croix, D., and Licandro, O. (2003) Early mortality declines at the dawn of modern growth. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 105(2): 401418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bovenberg, A. L. and Knaap, T. (2005) Ageing, funded pensions and the Dutch economy. CES ifo Working Paper 1403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browning, M., Hansen, L., and Heckman, J. J. (1999) Micro data and general equilibrium models. In Taylor, J. and Woodford, M. (eds), Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 1. Amsterdam: North-Holland, chap. 8.Google Scholar
Bütler, M., Huguenin, O., and Teppa, F. (2004) What triggers early retirement? Results from Swiss Pension Funds. University of Lausanne deep-HEC Discussion Paper.Google Scholar
Card, D. and Lemieux, T. (2000) Dropout and enrollment trends in the post-war period: what went wrong in the 1970s? NBER Working Paper 7658.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cervellati, M. and Sunde, U. (2005) Human capital formation, life expectancy and the process of development. American Economic Review, 95(5): 16531672.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Conesa, J. C. and Krueger, D. (1999) Social security reform with heterogeneous agents. Review of Economic Dynamics, 2(4): 757795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crémer, H. and Pestieau, P. (2003) The double dividend of postponing retirement. International Tax and Public Finance, 10(4): 419434.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cunha, F., Heckman, J. J., and Navarro, S. (2005) Separating uncertainty from heterogeneity in life cycle earnings. Oxford Economic Papers, 57(2): 191261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de la Croix, D. and Licandro, O. (1999) Life expectancy and endogenous growth. Economics Letters, 65(2): 255263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffy, J., Papageorgiou, C., and Perez-Sebastian, F. (2004) Capital–skill complementarity? Evidence from a panel of countries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(1): 327344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dupor, B., Lochner, L., Taber, C., and Wittekind, M. B. (1996) Some effects of taxes on schooling and training. American Economic Review, 86(2): 340346.Google Scholar
Echevarría, C. A. (2004) Life expectancy, schooling time, retirement, and growth. Economic Inquiry, 42(4): 602617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farmer, R. E. A. (1990) Rince preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(1): 4360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferreira, P. C. and Pessôa, de Abreu S. (2005) The effects of longevity and distortions on education and retirement. mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. and Weil, D. N. (2000) Population, technology, and growth: from malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. American Economic Review, 90(4): 806828.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gertler, M. (1999) Government debt and social security in a life-cycle economy. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 50: 61110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldin, C. and Katz, L. (1998) The origins of technology-skill complementarity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(3): 693732.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grafenhofer, D., Jaag, C., Keuschnigg, C., and Keuschnigg, M. (2005) Probabilistic aging. University of St. Gallen Department of Economics Discussion Paper 2005-8.Google Scholar
Griliches, Z. (1969) Capital–skill complementarity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 51(4): 465468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gruber, J. and Wise, D. A. (1999) Social Security and Retirement Around the World. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Gruber, J. and Wise, D. A. (2005) Social security programs and retirement around the world: fiscal implications. NBER Working Paper 11290.Google Scholar
Guvenen, F. (2003) Reconciling conflicting evidence on the elasticity of intertemporal substitution: a macroeconomic perspective. University of Rochester RCER Working Paper 491.Google Scholar
Haley, W. J. (1976) Estimation of the earnings profile from optimal human capital accumulation. Econometrica, 44(6): 12231238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, R. E. (1988) Intertemporal substitution in consumption. Journal of Political Economy, 96(2): 339357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamermesh, D. S. (1993) Labor Demand. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansson, I. and Stuart, C. (1985) Tax revenue and the marginal cost of public funds in Sweden. Journal of Public Economics, 27(3): 331353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckman, J. J. (1976) A life-cycle model of earnings, learning, and consumption. The Journal of Political Economy, 84(4): S11S44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckman, J. J. and Honoré, B. E. (1990) The empirical content of the Roy model. Econometrica, 58(5): 11211149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckman, J. J., Lochner, L., and Taber, C. (1998) Explaining rising wage inequality: explorations with a dynamic general equilibrium model of labor earnings with heterogeneous agents. Review of Economic Dynamics, 1(1): 158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, R., Fulginiti, L. E., and Peterson, E. W. F. (2003) Investing in hope: AIDS, life expectancy, and human capital accumulation. University of Nebraska-Lincoln Discussion Paper.Google Scholar
İmrohoroǧlu, A., İmrohoroǧlu, S., and Joines, D. H. (1995) A life cycle analysis of social security. Economic Theory, 6(1): 83114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
İmrohoroǧlu, A., İmrohoroǧlu, S., and Joines, D. H. (1999) Social security in an overlapping generations economy with land. Review of Economic Dynamics, 2(3): 638665.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaag, C., Keuschnigg, C., and Keuschnigg, M. (2005) Skill formation with labor market frictions. University of St. Gallen IFF Discussion Paper.Google Scholar
Johnson, G. E. (1997) Changes in earnings inequality: the role of demand shifts. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(2): 4154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalemli-Ozcan, S. (2002) Does the mortality decline promote economic growth? Journal of Economic Growth, 7(4): 411439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalemli-Ozcan, S., Ryder, H. E., and Weil, D. N. (2000) Mortality decline, human capital investment, and economic growth. Journal of Development Economics, 62(1): 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kane, T. J. (1994) College entry by blacks since 1970: the role of college costs, family background, and the returns to education. Journal of Political Economy, 105(5): 878911.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keuschnigg, C. and Keuschnigg, M. (2004) Aging, labor markets and pension reform in Austria. Finanzarchiv, 60(3): 359392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krusell, P., Ohanian, L. E., Rios-Rull, J.-V., and Violante, G. L. (2000) Capital–skill complemetarity and inequality: a macroeconomic analysis. Econometrica, 68(5): 10291053.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kydland, F. E. and Prescott, E. C. (1982) Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica, 50(6): 13451370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laitner, J. and Silverman, D. (2005) Estimating life-cycle parameters from consumption behavior at retirement. NBER Working Paper 11163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lau, M. I. and Poutvaara, P. (2000) Social security incentives and human capital investment. CEBR Discussion Paper 2000-18.Google Scholar
Lau, M. I. and Poutvaara, P. (2001) Social security rules, labor supply and human capital formation. CEBR Discussion Paper 2001–10.Google Scholar
Lechner, M. and Vazquez-Alvarez, R. (2005) Modelling active labour market policies in a life-cycle model of labour participation and human capital formation. University of St. Gallen SIAW Discussion Paper.Google Scholar
Lindquist, M. J. (2004) Capital–skill complementarity and inequality over the business cycle. Review of Economic Dynamics, 7(3): 519540.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lord, W. (1989) The transition from payroll to consumption receipts with endogenous human capital. Journal of Public Economics, 38(1): 5373.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, R. E. (1990) Supply-side economics: an analytical review. Oxford Economic Papers, 42(2): 293316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martín, A. R. S. (2003) Endogenous retirement and public pension system reform in Spain. Cebtro Atlántico de Estudios Ríos Pérez Working Paper 17.Google Scholar
Miles, D. (1999) Modelling the impact of demographic change upon the economy. Economic Journal, 109(452): 136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mincer, J. A. (1974) Schooling, Experience and Earnings. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Mincer, J. A. (1991) Job training: costs, returns, and wage profiles. In Stern, D. and Ritzen, J. M. (eds), Market Failure in Training? Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
Mincer, J. A. (1997) The production of human capital and the life cycle of earnings: variations on a theme. Journal of Labor Economics, 15(1): S26S47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, O. S. and Phillips, J. W. (2000) Retirement responses to early social security benefit reductions. NBER Working Paper 7963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Papageorgiou, C. and Chmelarova, V. (2005) Nonlinearities in capital–skill complementarity. Journal of Economic Growth, 33(1): 5989.Google Scholar
Perroni, C. (1995) Assessing the dynamic efficiency gains of tax reform when human capital is endogenous. International Economic Review, 36(4): 907925.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ramsey, F. (1928) A Mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal, 38(152): 534559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Razin, A. and Sadka, E. (2001) Labor, Capital, and Finance: International Flows. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rojas, J. A. (2005) Life-cycle earnings, cohort size effects and social security: a quantitative exploration. Journal of Public Economics, 89(2–3): 465485.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roy, A. (1951) Some thoughts on the distribution of earnings. Oxford Economic Papers, 3(2): 135146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sánchez-Martín, A. R. (2003) Endogenous Retirement and Public Pension System Reform in Spain, Centro Atlántico de Estudios Ríos Pérez Working Paper 17.Google Scholar
Sato, K. (1967) A Two-Level Constant-Elasticity-of-Substitution Production Function. Review of Economic Studies, 34(2): 201218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soares, R. R. (2005) Mortality reductions, educational attainment, and fertility choice. American Economic Review, 95(3): 580601.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Swanson, C. E. and Kopecky, K. J. (1999) Lifespan and output. Economic Inquiry, 37(2): 213225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Topel, R. (1999) Labor markets and economic growth. In Ashenfelter, O. and Card, D. (eds), Handbook of Labor Economics, vol. 3. Amsterdam: Elsevier, chap. 44, pp. 29432984.Google Scholar
Trostel, P. A. (1993) The Effect of Taxation on Human Capital. Journal of Political Economy, 101(2): 327350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weil, P. (1989) The equity premium puzzle and the risk-free rate puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 24(3): 401421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weil, P. (1990) Nonexpected utility in macroeconomics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(1): 2942.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weiss, Y. (1986) The determinants of life cycle earnings: a survey. In Ashenfelter, O. and Layard, R. (eds), Handbook of Labor Economics, vol. I. Amsterdam: Elsevier, chap. 11, pp. 603639.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Willis, R. J. and Rosen, S. (1979) Education and self-selection. Journal of Political Economy, 87(5): 736.CrossRefGoogle Scholar