Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T15:02:40.390Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The challenge of intermediary coordination in smallholder sugarcane production in Tanzania

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 February 2015

Donald Eliapenda Mmari*
Affiliation:
Senior Researcher and Director of Research on Growth and Development, REPOA, 157 Mgombani Street, Regent Estate, P.O. Box 33223, Dar es Salaam, Tanzania

Abstract

Orthodox approaches to development view the market as a key institution for driving economic transformation and for fostering innovation and competitiveness. The working of markets alone, however, does not always lead to improved outcomes such as increase in productivity or production efficiency in the context of smallholders. The role of non-market institutions, therefore, remains important. This paper examines the role of intermediary coordination in addressing constraints to efficiency and productivity of smallholder sugarcane producers in Tanzania. It also makes a contrastive analysis of a different organisational arrangement for smallholder sugarcane producers in Malawi. The key proposition is that while intermediary organisations of cane outgrowers in Tanzania have played a significant role in promoting effective market linkage, an increase in productivity required for competitiveness is limited by the lack of effective horizontal coordination.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2015 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abbot, C. 1990. Sugar. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Church, A., Groom, G. & Thomson, D.. 2008. ‘small-scale cane grower development models: some lessons from Sub-Saharan Africa', South African Sugar Technologists Association 81: 116–27.Google Scholar
Coase, R. 1937. ‘The nature of the firm’, Economica 4, 16: 386405.Google Scholar
Commons, J. 1951. The Economics of Collective Action. New York, NY: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Dorward, A., Kydd, J., Morrison, J. & Poulton, C.. 2005. ‘institutions, markets and economic development: linking development policy to theory and praxis’, Development and Change 36, 1: 125.Google Scholar
Edquist, C. & Johnson, B.. 1997. ‘Institutions and organizations in systems of innovation’, in Edquist, C., ed. Systems of Innovations: technologies, institutions, and organizations. London: Pinter, 4163.Google Scholar
Granovetter, M. 1985. ‘Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness’, American Journal of Sociology 91, 3: 481510.Google Scholar
Hagelberg, G. & Hannah, A.. 1994. ‘The quest for order: a review of international sugar agreements’, Food Policy 19, 1: 1729.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. 1988. Economics and Institutions: a manifesto for a modern institutional economics. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. 2006. ‘What are institutions?’, Journal of Economic Issues XL, 1: 125.Google Scholar
International Sugar Organization. 2008. Sugarcane Smallholders in Sub-Saharan Africa: status, challenges, and strategies for development, MECAS (08)05.Google Scholar
Mackintosh, M. 1990. ‘Abstract markets and real needs', in Bernstein, H., Crow, B., Mackintosh, M. & Martin, C., eds. The Food Question: profits versus people? London: Earthscan, 4353.Google Scholar
Mackintosh, M. 2001. ‘Contracts, information and firms behavior’, in Himmelweit, S., Simonetti, R. & Trigg, A., eds. Microeconomics: neoclassical and institutionalist perspectives on economic behavior. London: Thomson Learning, 227–47.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. 2004. ‘The economics of hybrid organizationsJournal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 160: 345–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J.. 1992. Economics, Organizations and Management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Polanyi, K. 1957. The Great Transformation: the political and economic origins of our time. Boston, MA: Beacon.Google Scholar
Poulton, C., Dorward, A. and Kydd, J.. 2010. ‘the future of small farms: new directions for services, institutions, and intermediation’, World Development 38(10): 1413–28.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. 1950. Economics of Imperfect Competition. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. 2007. One Economics, Many Recipes: globalization, institutions, and economic growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Rondot, P. and Collion, M.. 2001. Agricultural Producer Organizations: their contribution to rural capacity building and poverty reduction. Report of a Workshop, Washington, DC, June 28–30, 1999.Google Scholar
Ton, G. and Bijman, J.. 2006. The role of producer organizations in the process of developing an integrated supply chain: experiences from Quinoa chain development in Bolivia. Paper presented at the 7th International Conference on Management in AgriFood Chains and Networks, Ede, 31 May–6 June.Google Scholar
United Republic of Tanzania. 2001. The Sugar Industry Act No. 26 of 2001, Dar es Salaam.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. 1934. The Theory of Leisure: an economic study of institutions. New York, NY: Modern Library.Google Scholar
Webber, M. and Labatse, P.. 2010. ‘Horizontal collaboration – creating and taking advantage of economies of scale’, in Webber, M. & Labatse, P., eds. Building Competitiveness in Africa's Agriculture: a guide to value chain concepts and applications. Washington, DC: The World Bank, 95–6.Google Scholar
World Development Movement. 1980. Sugar: crisis in the third world. London: World Development Movement and Birmingham: Third World Publications.Google Scholar
Williamson, O.E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: firms, markets, relational contracting. New York, NY: The Free Press.Google Scholar