Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-q99xh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T22:06:21.314Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Globalisation, the Terms of Trade, and Argentina's Expansion in the Long Nineteenth Century

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 March 2017

Abstract

Following Tulio Halperín Donghi's pioneering work, historians have tried to explain why Argentina experienced a dramatic export-led expansion in the first half of the nineteenth century despite a lack of price incentives. This paradox is resolved by a new estimate of Argentina's terms of trade. It suggests that they probably improved by at least 2,000 per cent from the 1780s to the first decade of the twentieth century, so there were considerable price incentives for export-led growth. Labour and capital moved into the export sector, bringing into production the country's Pampean land – a previously under-utilised resource. This suggests that Argentina's expansion in the long nineteenth century was less a result of internal factors than a response to globalisation.

Spanish abstract

Siguiendo al trabajo pionero de Tulio Halperín Donghi, los historiadores han tratado de explicar por qué Argentina experimentó una dramática expansión de las exportaciones en la primera mitad del siglo XIX a pesar de los pocos incentivos a los precios de los productos. Esta paradoja se resuelve por una nueva evaluación sobre los términos comerciales de Argentina. Los datos sugieren que estos probablemente mejoraron en al menos 2.000 por ciento desde los años 1780s hasta la primera década del siglo XX, así que hubo considerables incentivos en los precios para el crecimiento de las exportaciones. Trabajo y capital se movilizaron hacia el sector exportador, llevando las tierras de la Pampa –un recurso previamente subutilizado– hacia la producción. Lo anterior sugiere que la expansión Argentina en el largo siglo XIX fue menos el resultado de factores internos que una respuesta a la globalización.

Portuguese abstract

A partir do trabalho pioneiro de Tulio Halperín Donghi, historiadores têm buscado explicar as razões pelas quais a Argentina, apesar da falta de uma política de incentivo de preços, passou por uma impressionante expansão baseada na exportação durante a primeira metade do século XIX. Este paradoxo é resolvido por uma nova estimativa dos termos de troca argentinos. Tal estimativa sugere um aumento provável de pelo menos 2.000% entre a década de 1780 e a primeira década do século XX, demonstrando haver consideráveis incentivos de preços para um crescimento baseado na exportação. Capital e trabalho moveram-se em direção ao setor exportador, fazendo com que as terras da região pampeana argentina, previamente subutilizadas, fossem engajadas na produção. Isto sugere que a expansão argentina no longo século XIX foi menos resultado de fatores internos que uma resposta à globalização.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 An accompanying workbook is available online at www.joefrancis.info/data/Francis_Arg_tots.xlsx (accessed 23 Dec. 2016).

2 For example, Donghi, Tulio Halperín, ‘La expansión ganadera en la campaña de Buenos Aires (1810–1852)’, Desarrollo Económico, 3: 1/2 (1963), pp. 61–5Google Scholar; Chiaramonte, José Carlos, ‘Mercado de mercancías, mercado monetario y mercado de capitales en el litoral argentino de la primera mitad del XIX: el caso de Corrientes’, Siglo XIX: Revista de Historia, 2: 4 (1987), pp. 91, 93Google Scholar; Sabato, Hilda, Agrarian Capitalism and the World Market: Buenos Aires in the Pastoral Age, 1840–1890 (Albuquerque, NM: University of New Mexico Press, 1990), pp. 204–8Google Scholar; Amaral, Samuel, The Rise of Capitalism on the Pampas: The Estancias of Buenos Aires, 1785–1870 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998), pp. 232–41Google Scholar; and Garavaglia, Juan Carlos, ‘La economía rural de la campaña de Buenos Aires vista a través de sus precios: 1756–1852’, in Fradkin, Raúl O. and Garavaglia, Juan Carlos (eds.), En busca de un tiempo perdido: la economía de Buenos Aires en el país de la abundancia, 1750–1865 (Buenos Aires: Prometeo, 2004), pp. 107–58Google Scholar.

3 Donghi, Halperín, ‘Expansión ganadera’; and ‘La expansión de la frontera de Buenos Aires (1810–1852)’, in Jara, A. (ed.), Tierras nuevas: expansión territorial y ocupación del suelo en América (siglos xvi–xix) (Mexico, DF: Colegio de México, 1969), pp. 7791 Google Scholar.

4 Halperín Donghi, ‘Expansión de la frontera’, p. 82, author's translation.

5 Halperín Donghi, ‘Expansión ganadera’, p. 61, author's translation.

6 For summaries of the literature, see Schmit, Roberto, ‘Conceptos, herramientas y resultados recientes sobre la historia económica rioplatense de la primera mitad del siglo XIX’, in Bragoni, Beatriz and Barbero, María Inés (eds.), Microanálisis: ensayos de historiografía argentina (Buenos Aires: Prometeo, 2004), pp. 5579 Google Scholar; and Fradkin, Raúl O., ‘Caminos abiertos en la pampa: dos décadas de renovación de la historia rural rioplatense desde mediados del siglo XVIII a mediados del XIX’, in Gelman, Jorge (ed.), La historia económica argentina en la encrucijada (Buenos Aires: Prometeo, 2006), pp. 189208 Google Scholar.

7 See Donghi, Halperín, ‘Expansión ganadera’, pp. 72–3; and ‘The Buenos Aires Landed Class and the Shape of Argentine Politics (1820–1930)’, in Huber, Evelyne and Safford, Frank (eds.), Agrarian Structure and Political Power: Landlord and Peasant in the Making of Latin America (Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1995), p. 42 Google Scholar.

8 Robinson, Karla, ‘The Merchants of Post-Independence Buenos Aires’, in Moorhead, Max L. and Coker, William S. (eds.), Hispanic-American Essays in Honor of Max Leon Moorhead (Pensacola, FL: Perdido Bay Press, 1979), p. 116 Google Scholar, Table 2.

9 Land sold in the Buenos Aires countryside for around 8 British pennies per hectare in the 1780s, but it had risen to roughly £6 (that is, 1,440 pennies) by the 1900s. Land prices from Conde, Roberto Cortés, El progreso argentino: 1880–1914 (Buenos Aires: Editorial Sudamericana, 1979), pp. 164 Google Scholar, 166, Cuadros 3.8 and 3.10; and Gelman, Jorge and Santilli, Daniel, ‘Salarios y precios de los factores en Buenos Aires, 1770–1880: una aproximación a la distribución funcional del ingreso en el largo plazo’, Revista de Historia Económica, 33: 1 (2015), pp. 179–80Google Scholar, Cuadro A-1. For the exchange rates, see the Appendix.

10 Amaral, Rise of Capitalism, esp. chap. 1.

11 Irigoin, Maria Alejandra, ‘Inconvertible Paper Money, Inflation and Economic Performance in Early Nineteenth Century Argentina’, Journal of Latin American Studies, 32: 2 (2000), pp. 333–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

12 Beginning, of course, with Singer, Hans W., ‘The Distribution of Gains between Investing and Borrowing Countries’, American Economic Review, 40: 2 (1950), pp. 473–85Google Scholar; and Prebisch, Raúl, ‘The Economic Development of Latin America and Its Principal Problems’, Economic Bulletin for Latin America, 7: 1 (1962), pp. 122 Google Scholar. For overviews of the debate, see Spraos, John, Inequalising Trade? A Study of Traditional North/South Specialisation in the Context of Terms of Trade Concepts (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1983)Google Scholar, chap. 3; Diakosavvas, Dimitris and Scandizzo, Pasquale L., ‘Trends in the Terms of Trade of Primary Commodities, 1900–1982: The Controversy and Its Origins’, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 39: 2 (1991), pp. 232–46Google Scholar; and Ocampo, José Antonio and Parra, María Angela, ‘The Continuing Relevance of the Terms of Trade and Industrialization Debates’, in Pérez-Caldentey, Esteban and Vernengo, Matías (eds.), Ideas, Policies and Economic Development in the Americas (London: Routledge, 2007), pp. 163–6Google Scholar.

13 See Williamson, Jeffrey G., Trade and Poverty: When the Third World Fell Behind (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2011), esp. chap. 4CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

14 Newland, Carlos, ‘Exports and Terms of Trade in Argentina, 1811–1870’, Bulletin of Latin American Research, 17: 3 (1998), p. 412 CrossRefGoogle Scholar, Table 2.

15 Ibid ., p. 412.

16 Newland, Carlos and Ortiz, Javier, ‘The Economic Consequences of Argentine Independence’, Cuadernos de Economía, 38: 115 (2001), p. 279 Google Scholar, Table 1.

17 Salvatore, Ricardo D. and Newland, Carlos, ‘Between Independence and the Golden Age: The Early Argentine Economy’, in Paolera, Gerardo della and Taylor, Alan M. (eds.), A New Economic History of Argentina (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003), pp. 21–2Google Scholar; emphasis added by author.

18 For an overview, see Federico, Giovanni, ‘How Much Do We Know About Market Integration in Europe?’, Economic History Review, 65: 2 (2012), pp. 470–97Google Scholar.

19 On this problem for the periphery's terms of trade in general, see Francis, Joseph A., ‘The Periphery's Terms of Trade in the Nineteenth Century: A Methodological Problem Revisited’, Historical Methods: A Journal of Quantitative and Interdisciplinary History, 48: 1 (2015), pp. 5265 Google Scholar.

20 Donghi, Tulio Halperín, ‘La apertura mercantil en el Río de la Plata: impacto global y desigualdades regionales, 1800–1850’, in Liehr, Reinhard (ed.), América Latina en la época de Simón Bolívar: la formación de las economías nacionales y los intereses económicos europeos 1800–1850 (Berlin: Colloquium, 1989), pp. 115–38Google Scholar. A version of this metanarrative can already be found in Mitre, B., Historia de Belgrano y la independencia argentina, 4th edn, vol. 1 (Buenos Aires: Feliz Lajouane, 1887)Google Scholar, chap. 1.

21 Halperín Donghi, ‘Apertura mercantil’, p. 122.

22 See, for example, Schmit, ‘Conceptos, herramientas', pp. 74–8; and Fradkin, ‘Caminos abiertos’, pp. 198–9.

23 Cuenca-Esteban, Javier, ‘Statistics of Spain's Colonial Trade, 1747–1820: New Estimates and Comparisons with Great Britain’, Revista de Historia Económica, 26: 3 (2008), p. 328 CrossRefGoogle Scholar, Figure 3.

24 Barbier, Javier A. and Klein, Herbert S., ‘Revolutionary Wars and Public Finance: The Madrid Treasury, 1784–1807’, Journal of Economic History, 41: 2 (1981), pp. 327–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Marichal, Carlos, ‘Beneficios y costes fiscales del colonialismo: las remesas americanas a España, 1760–1814’, Revista de Historia Económica, 15: 3 (1997), p. 480 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Cuenca-Esteban, Javier, ‘Was Spain a Viable Fiscal-Military State on the Eve of the French Wars?’, in Conway, Stephen and Sánchez, Rafael Torres (eds.), The Spending of States: Military Expenditure During the Long Eighteenth Century: Patterns, Organisation, and Consequences, 1650–1815 (Saarbrucken: VDM Publishing, 2011), pp. 247–56Google Scholar.

25 For a late eighteenth-century example, see the case of the government bonds known as vales reales. de Lorca, P. Tedde, El Banco de San Carlos (1782–1829) (Madrid: Banco de España, 1988)Google Scholar, chap. 2.

26 Hence, Grafe and Irigoin find that the Spanish authorities in the Americas directed treasury funds to ports. Regina Grafe and Maria Alejandra Irigoin, ‘The Spanish Empire and Its Legacy: Fiscal Redistribution and Political Conflict in Colonial and Post-Colonial Spanish America’, Journal of Global History, 1: 2 (2006), p. 256. Their interpretation of this finding – that fiscal transfers sought to promote development in poorer regions – is, however, erroneous because they ignore the way in which the trade monopoly extracted resources from the Americas.

27 On the geography of the colonial River Plate, see Donghi, Tulio Halperín, Politics, Economics and Society in Argentina in the Revolutionary Period (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1975), pp. 616 Google Scholar; and Tandeter, Enrique, ‘El eje Potosí–Buenos Aires en el imperio español’, in Ganci, Massimo and Romano, Ruggiero (eds.), Governare il mondo: l'imperio spagnolo dal XV al XIX secolo (Palermo: Società Storia Patria, 1991), pp. 185201 Google Scholar.

28 Marks, Patricia H., ‘Confronting a Mercantile Elite: Bourbon Reformers and the Merchants of Lima, 1765–1796’, The Americas, 60: 4 (2004), pp. 519–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Deconstructing Legitimacy: Viceroys, Merchants, and the Military in Late Colonial Peru (University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University Press, 2007), pp. 5561 Google Scholar.

29 Moutoukias, Zacarías, ‘El crecimiento en una economía colonial de antiguo régimen: reformismo y sector externo en el Río de la Plata’, Arquivos do Centro Cultural Calouste Gulbenkian, 34 (1995), pp. 771813 Google Scholar; Comercio y producción’, in de Historia, Academia Nacional (ed.), Nueva historia de la Nación Argentina, vol. 3 (Buenos Aires: Planeta, 2000), pp. 7281 Google Scholar; Marks, ‘Confronting a Mercantile Elite’, pp. 535–58; and Deconstructing Legitimacy, pp. 75–105.

30 For a useful summary, see Newland and Ortiz, ‘Economic Consequences’, pp. 276–8.

31 Socolow, Susan M., The Merchants of Buenos Aires, 1778–1810 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1978), p. 60 Google Scholar.

32 Saguier, Eduardo R., ‘El mercado del cuero y su rol como fuente alternativa de empleo: el caso del trabajo a destajo en las vaquerías de la Banda Oriental durante el siglo XVIII’, Revista de Historia Económica, 9: 1 (1991), pp. 111–12CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Amaral, Rise of Capitalism, pp. 241–2.

33 Socolow, Merchants of Buenos Aires, pp. 58–60.

34 Amaral, Rise of Capitalism, p. 234, Table 11.1.

35 Mayo, Carlos A., ‘Landed but not Powerful: The Colonial Estancieros of Buenos Aires (1750–1810)’, Hispanic American Historical Review, 71: 4 (1991), pp. 769–70Google Scholar; and Estancia y sociedad en la Pampa 1740–1820 (Buenos Aires: Editorial Biblos, 1995), pp. 60–1Google Scholar.

36 The formation of this dominant class is described in Moutoukias, Zacarías, ‘Power, Corruption, and Commerce: The Making of the Local Administrative Structure in Seventeenth-Century Buenos Aires’, Hispanic American Historical Review, 68: 4 (1988), pp. 771801 Google Scholar. On the merchants' commercial networks, see Garavaglia, Juan Carlos, Mercado interno y economía colonial (México: Grijalbo, 1983), pp. 457–81Google Scholar; Gelman, Jorge D., ‘Venta al contado, venta a crédito y crédito monetario en América colonial: acerca de un gran comerciante del virreinato del Río de la Plata’, Jahrbuch für Geschichte von Staat, Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft Lateinamerikas, 27 (1990), pp. 101–26Google Scholar; and Tandeter, ‘Eje Potosí–Buenos Aires’.

37 Gelman, Jorge and Santilli, Daniel, De Rivadavia a Rosas: desigualdad y crecimiento económico (Buenos Aires: Siglo Veintiuno Editores, 2006), p. 152 Google Scholar, Cuadro 7.

38 Garavaglia, Juan Carlos, Pastores y labradores de Buenos Aires: una historia agraria de la campaña bonaerense 1700–1830 (Buenos Aires: Ediciones de la Flor, 1999), p. 150 Google Scholar, fn. 29.

39 Lynch, John, The Spanish American Revolutions, 1808–1826, 2nd edn (London: W. W. Norton & Company, 1986), pp. 4950 Google Scholar.

40 Moreno, D. Mariano, Representación que el apoderado de los hacendados de las campañas del Río de la Plata dirigió al Exmo. Sr. virrey D. Baltasar Hidalgo de Cisneros (Buenos Aires: Imprenta Especial para Obras de Pablo E. Coni, 1874), p. 29 Google Scholar, author's translation.

41 Adelman, Jeremy, Republic of Capital: Buenos Aires and the Legal Transformation of the Atlantic World (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, chap. 3; also, for Latin America as a whole, see Sovereignty and Revolution in the Iberian Atlantic (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2006)Google Scholar, chap. 4.

42 Costeloe, Michael P., ‘Spain and the Latin American Wars of Independence: The Free Trade Controversy, 1810–1820’, Hispanic American Historical Review, 61: 2 (1981), pp. 209–34Google Scholar.

43 Lynch, Spanish American Revolutions, pp. 49–50.

44 Ferns, H. S., Britain and Argentina in the Nineteenth Century (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1960), p. 65 Google Scholar.

45 Moutoukias, ‘Crecimiento en una economía’, p. 803, Cuadro 2.

46 Llorca-Jaña, M., The British Textile Trade in South America in the Nineteenth Century (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2012), p. 341 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

47 Halperín Donghi, ‘Buenos Aires Landed Class’, pp. 44–5.

48 Newland and Ortiz, ‘Economic Consequences’; also see Eduardo Míguez, ‘Reforma y primitivismo: tierra y fiscalidad en El Río de la Plata, de la colonia a la independencia’, in Michel Bertrand and Zacarías Moutoukias (eds.), Changement institutionnel et fiscalité dans le monde hispanique, forthcoming.

49 Llorca-Jaña, Manuel, ‘To Be Waterproof or to Be Soaked: Importance of Packing in British Textile Exports to Distant Markets: The Cases of Chile and the River Plate, c.1810–1859’, Revista de Historia Económica, 29: 1 (2011), pp. 1137 Google Scholar.

50 Gazeta de Buenos Ayres, 1 (1810), p. 6.

51 Calculated from Broide, Julio, ‘La evolución de los precios pecuarios argentinos en el período 1830–1850’ (Buenos Aires: Facultad de Ciencias Económicas, 1951), p. 41 Google Scholar; also published in Revista de la Facultad de Ciencias Económicas, 4: 32 (1951), pp. 113–83Google Scholar; and Maria Alejandra Irigoin, ‘Finance, Politics and Economics in Buenos Aires, 1820s–1860s: The Political Economy of Currency Stabilisation’, unpubl. PhD diss., University of London, 2000, p. 126, Table II.1.6. Export taxes were eroded by inflation because they were in fixed paper money amounts that were only sporadically adjusted for rising prices. See ibid., pp. 129–30.

52 In-bond prices are those prior to the payment of any applicable import taxes. For hide prices in Buenos Aires, see Anon, ., ‘Report on the Trade of the River Plate’, reproduced in Humphreys, R. A., British Consular Reports on the Trade and Politics of Latin America 1824–26 (London: Offices of the Royal Historical Society, 1940), p. 33 Google Scholar; Anon, ., ‘Precios corrientes de productos en Buenos Aires en los años 1821, 1822 y 1823’, in Barba, Enrique M. (ed.), Informes sobre el comercio exterior de Buenos Aires durante el gobierno de Martín Rodríguez (Buenos Aires: Academia Nacional de la Historia, 1978), p. 60 Google Scholar; Broide, ‘Evolución de los precios’, p. 41, Cuadro 16; and Moutoukias, ‘Crecimiento en una economía’, p. 804, Cuadro 3. For Buenos Aires hide prices in London, see Gayer, Arthur D., Rostow, W. W. and Schwartz, A. J., microfilmed supplement to The Growth and Fluctuation of the British Economy 1790–1850 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1953)Google Scholar, as compiled by Jacks, David S., O'Rourke, Kevin H. and Williamson, Jeffrey G., ‘Commodity Price Volatility and World Market Integration since 1700’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 93: 3 (2011), pp. 800–13Google Scholar; with the database available online at www.sfu.ca/~djacks/data/publications/Britain,%20Commodity%20Prices,%201790-1850,%20monthly.xlsx (accessed23 Dec. 2016); and Halperín Donghi, ‘Expansión ganadera’, p. 65. The differential varies according to which series of hide prices in Britain is used.

53 An Englishman [G. T. Love], A Five Years' Residence in Buenos Ayres, during the Years 1820 to 1825, 2nd edn (London: G. Herbert, 1827), p. 93 Google Scholar.

54 Llorca-Jaña, British Textile Trade, p. 341.

55 Harley, C. Knick, ‘Ocean Freight Rates and Productivity, 1740–1913: The Primacy of Mechanical Invention Reaffirmed’, Journal of Economic History, 48: 4 (1988), pp. 851–76Google Scholar; and Mohammed, Saif I. Shah and Williamson, Jeffrey G., ‘Freight Rates and Productivity Gains in British Tramp Shipping 1869–1950’, Explorations in Economic History, 41: 2 (2004), pp. 172203 Google Scholar.

56 Angier, E.A. V., Fifty Years' Freights: 1869–1919 (London: Fairplay, 1920), pp. 6 Google Scholar, 140. Also see Stemmer, Juan E. Oribe, ‘Freight Rates in the Trade between Europe and South America, 1840–1914’, Journal of Latin American Studies, 21: 1 (1989), pp. 2359 Google Scholar; and Llorca-Jaña, British Textile Trade, pp. 219–20.

57 C. Knick Harley, ‘Prices and Profits in Cotton Textiles during the Industrial Revolution’, Discussion Paper in Economic and Social History 81, Oxford University, 2010.

58 Estimated from Sandberg, Lars G., ‘Movements in the Quality of British Cotton Textile Exports, 1815–1913’, Journal of Economic History, 28: 1 (1968), pp. 8 Google Scholar, 10, Tables 1 and 2; Esteban, Javier Cuenca, ‘British Textile Prices, 1770–1831: Are British Growth Rates Worth Revising Once Again?’, Economic History Review, 47: 1 (1994), pp. 101–2Google Scholar, Table A3; and Harley, C. Knick, ‘Cotton Textile Prices and the Industrial Revolution’, Economic History Review, 51: 1 (1998), p. 78 Google Scholar, Table A2.1.

59 Parish, Woodbine, Buenos Ayres and the Provinces of the Rio de la Plata, 2nd edn (London: W. Clowes & Sons, 1852), p. 362 Google Scholar.

60 Llorca-Jaña, British Textile Trade, App. L.

61 See footnote 2.

62 See Newland, ‘Exports and Terms of Trade’; also Llorca-Jaña, British Textile Trade, p. 195, Figure 7.4.

63 Francis, ‘Periphery's Terms of Trade’, esp. pp. 53–56.

64 Ferreres, Orlando J., Dos siglos de economía argentina, 1810–2004: historia argentina en cifras (Buenos Aires: Editorial El Ateneo, 2005)Google Scholar, Cuadro 8.1.7.

65 On this problem in such ‘part-proxy’ estimates of peripheral countries' terms of trade, see Francis, ‘Periphery's Terms of Trade’, esp. pp. 57–8.

66 In the 1780s paper – the only imported good for which there is currently sufficient data – sold for around 100 per cent more in Buenos Aires than in Spain. Cuesta, Eduardo Martín, Precios, población, impuestos y producción: la economía de Buenos Aires en el siglo XVIII (Buenos Aires: Temas, 2009)Google Scholar, Anexo 2. A price difference of 30 per cent in 1913 seems reasonable, given that the price gap for exports was around 10 per cent but imports paid, on average, a tariff rate of around 18–20 per cent before the First World War. The latter figure is from Dirección General de Estadística, Síntesis Estadística Mensual de la República Argentina, 1: 2 (1947), p. 3 Google Scholar.

67 Caution should be exercised in interpreting the volatility during the 1810s because hide prices for this decade are reported as several-year averages. Nonetheless, even if the 1810s are excluded from the picture, the impression of declining volatility remains.

68 Hence, in the 1810s prices were given for three grades of River Plate dry hides in London, whereas only one generic price is given in the source used for Buenos Aires. See respectively Barba, Fernando Enrique, Frontera ganadera y guerra con el indio: la frontera y la ocupación ganadera en Buenos Aires entre los siglos XVIII y XIX (Buenos Aires: Editorial de la Universidad de la Plata, 1997), p. 119 Google Scholar; and Anon., ‘Report on the Trade’, p. 33.

69 The parallel would be the much greater terms-of-trade boom experienced in the western United States than on its eastern seaboard. See North, Douglass C., The Economic Growth of the United States 1790–1860 (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall, Inc., 1961), pp. 255 Google Scholar, 280 and Tables I–9 and 1.

70 Even within the Province of Buenos Aires there would have been considerable variations. When measured in the capital city, the terms of trade for wheat, for example, deteriorated in the late nineteenth century, which initially seems surprising, given the rapid growth in wheat exports during this period. Were the terms of trade measured in the wheat producing regions, by contrast, an improvement would be seen owing to the reduction of internal transportation costs following the arrival of the railways.

71 Halperín Donghi, ‘Expansión ganadera’ and ‘Expansión de la frontera’.

72 Chiaramonte, ‘Mercado de mercancías’, pp. 91, 93.

73 Sabato, Agrarian Capitalism, pp. 204–8.

74 Amaral, Rise of Capitalism, pp. 232–41.

75 Garavaglia, ‘Economía rural’.

76 Newland, ‘Exports and Terms of Trade’; also see Newland and Ortiz, ‘Economic Consequences’.

77 For a useful summary, see Llorca-Jaña, British Textile Trade, pp. 257–67.

78 Including the following occupations: blanqueadores; cordeleros, hiladores e hiladoras; tejedores y tejedoras; pelloneros; tintoreros; torcedores de lana, seda, etc. Calculated from Argentina, República, Primer censo de la República Argentina (Buenos Aires: Porvenir, 1872), pp. 642–69Google Scholar.

79 Including the following occupations: cardadores de lana; cordeleros; fabricantes de tejidos; hiladores, tejedores, tellaristas; tintoreros. Calculated from Argentina, República, Tercer censo nacional, vol. 4, Población (Buenos Aires: Rosso, 1916), pp. 201329 Google Scholar.

80 Salvatore, Ricardo D. and Brown, Jonathan C., ‘Trade and Proletarianization in Late Colonial Banda Oriental: Evidence from the Estancia de las Vacas, 1791–1805’, Hispanic American Historical Review, 67: 3 (1987), pp. 431–59Google Scholar; Slatta, Richard W., Gauchos and the Vanishing Frontier (Lincoln, NE: University of Nebraska Press, 1983)Google Scholar; Salvatore, Ricardo D., ‘Reclutamiento militar, disciplinamiento y proletarización en la era de Rosas’, Boletín del Instituto de Historia Argentina y Americana ‘Dr Emilio Ravignani’, 3: 5 (1992), pp. 2547 Google Scholar; Wandering Paysanos: State Order and Subaltern Experience in Buenos Aires during the Rosas Era (Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2003)Google Scholar; and Santilli, Daniel, ‘De proletarización, clientelismo y negociación: la perseverancia de los campesinos de la campaña de Buenos Aires (1780–1840)’, in Alabart, Mónica, Fernández, María Alejandra and Pérez, Mariana A. (eds.), Buenos Aires: una sociedad que se transforma: entre la colonia y la Revolución de Mayo (Buenos Aires: Prometeo, 2011), pp. 93130 Google Scholar.

81 Guy, Donna J., ‘Women, Peonage, and Industrialization: Argentina, 1810–1914’, Latin American Research Review, 16: 3 (1981), pp. 6589 Google Scholar; Salvatore, Ricardo D., ‘Labor Control and Discrimination: The Contratista System in Mendoza, Argentina, 1880–1920’, Agricultural History, 60: 3 (1986), pp. 5280 Google Scholar; Campi, Daniel, ‘Captación y retención de la mano de obra por endeudamiento: El caso de Tucumán en la segunda mitad del siglo XIX’, in Campi, Daniel (ed.), Estudios sobre la historia de la industria azucarera argentina, vol. 1 (San Salvador de Jujuy: Universidad Nacional de Jujuy and Universidad Nacional de Tucumán, 1991), pp. 129–52Google Scholar; Notas sobre la gestación del mercado de trabajo en Tucumán (1800–1870)’, Población y Sociedad, 5 (1998), pp. 133–63Google Scholar; and Tell, Sonia, Córdoba rural, una sociedad campesina (1750–1850) (Buenos Aires: Prometeo, 2008), pp. 418–25Google Scholar.

82 Hora, Roy, ‘Landowning Bourgeoisie or Business Bourgeoisie? On the Peculiarities of the Argentine Economic Elite, 1880–1945’, Journal of Latin American Studies, 34: 3 (2002), pp. 587623 Google Scholar; and El perfil económico de la elite de Buenos Aires en las décadas centrales del siglo XIX’, Revista de Historia Económica, 24: 2 (2006), pp. 297332 CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Important case studies are found in Hora, Roy, ‘The Making and Evolution of the Buenos Aires Economic Elite in the Nineteenth Century: The Example of the Senillosa’, Hispanic American Historical Review, 83: 3 (2003), pp. 451–86Google Scholar; Del comercio a la tierra y más allá: los negocios de Juan José y Nicolás de Anchorena (1810–1856)’, Desarrollo Económico, 44: 176 (2005), pp. 567600 Google Scholar; and Los Anchorena: patrones de inversión, fortuna y negocios (1760–1950)’, América Latina en la Historia Económica, 19: 1 (2012), pp. 3966 Google Scholar.

83 This largely applies to the estimates used by, for instance, de la Escosura, Leandro Prados, ‘The Economic Consequences of Independence in Latin America’, in Bulmer-Thomas, Victor, Coatsworth, John H. and Conde, Roberto Cortés (eds.), The Economic History of Latin America, vol. 1, The Colonial Era and the Short Nineteenth Century (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006), p. 495 Google Scholar, Table 13.8 and Lost Decades? Economic Performance in Post-Independence Latin America’, Journal of Latin American Studies, 41: 2 (2009), p. 289 Google Scholar, Table 1; Bértola, Luis and Ocampo, José Antonio, The Economic Development of Latin America since Independence (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2012), pp. 92–3Google Scholar; and Victor Bulmer-Thomas, The Economic History of Latin America since Independence (3rd ed., New York: Cambridge University Press, 2014), App. 2. For the origins of the main estimates used by these authors, see Francis, ‘Periphery's Terms of Trade’, pp. 63–5.

84 For case studies of the privatisation of communal lands, see Boixados, M. Christina, ‘Expropiación de tierras comunales indígenas en la provincia de Córdoba a fines del siglo XIX: el caso del pueblo de La Toma’, Cuadernos de Historia: Serie Economía y Sociedad, 2 (1999), pp. 87113 Google Scholar; and Paz, Gustavo L., ‘Encomienda, hacienda y orden rural en el norte argentino: Jujuy 1850–1900’, Anuario de Estudios Americanos, 61: 2 (2004), pp. 551–70Google Scholar. For the debate about deindustrialisation in the Interior, again see Llorca-Jaña, British Textile Trade, pp. 257–67.

85 See, for example, Klarén, Peter F., ‘The Origins of Modern Peru, 1880–1930’, in Bethell, Leslie (ed.), The Cambridge History of Latin America, vol. 5, c. 1870–1930 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986), pp. 616–26Google Scholar; and Herbert S. Klein, ‘Bolivia from the War of the Pacific to the Chaco War, 1880–1932’, in Bethell, ed., Cambridge History, vol. 5, pp. 554–9.

86 See Friedrich Katz, ‘Mexico: Restored Republic and Porfiriato, 1867–1910’, in Bethell, ed., Cambridge History, vol. 5, pp. 48–53. On the decline of the cottage textiles industry, see Salvucci, Richard J., Textiles and Capitalism in Mexico: An Economic History of the Obrajes, 1539–1840 (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1987)Google Scholar, chap. 5.

87 Frank, Andre Gunder, Latin America: Underdevelopment or Revolution (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1969)Google Scholar, chap. 1.

88 The accompanying workbook is available online at www.joefrancis.info/data/Francis_Arg_tots.xlsx (accessed 23 Dec. 2016). For a longer account of its contents, see Joseph A. Francis, ‘The Terms of Trade and the Rise of Argentina in the Long Nineteenth Century’, unpubl. PhD diss., London School of Economics, 2013, pp. 174–92; and a more detailed analysis of the methodological issues discussed here can be found in Francis, ‘Periphery's Terms of Trade’.

89 Prebisch, ‘Economic Development’; and Singer, ‘Distribution of Gains’.

90 The standard series for Argentina for 1810–70 comes from Newland, ‘Exports and Terms of Trade’, pp. 413–15; for the underlying data, see Newland, ‘Puramente animal: Exportaciones y crecimiento en Argentina 1810–1870’, mimeo, 1990, available online at https://www.scribd.com/doc/93245804/PURAMENTE-ANIMAL-EXPORTACIONES-Y-CRECIMIENTO-EN-ARGENTINA-1810-1870 (accessed 31 Dec. 2016). Newland mainly used wholesale prices and unit values from the core countries. There is no canonical series for 1870–86, so the gap is filled by various means. Williamson, for example, relies on a series calculated using British commodity prices for exports and US wholesale price indices for imports. Williamson, Jeffrey G., ‘Globalization and the Great Divergence: Terms of Trade Booms, Volatility and the Poor Periphery, 1782–1913’, European Review of Economic History, 12: 3 (2008), p. 390 Google Scholar; also see Blattman, Christopher, Hwang, Jason and Williamson, Jeffrey G., ‘Winners and Losers in the Commodity Lottery: The Impact of Terms of Trade Growth and Volatility in the Periphery 1870–1939’, Journal of Development Economics, 82: 1 (2007), pp. 156–79Google Scholar. Ferreres, meanwhile, chose a domestic wholesale export price index divided by Britain's export prices. Ferreres, Dos siglos, p. 588. For 1886–1913, an index originally calculated by Ford is the standard series. He used a mixture of prices from Argentina's trade statistics and British wholesale prices that he corrected for changes in transportation costs. Ford, A. G., ‘Export Price Indices for the Argentine Republic, 1881–1914’, Inter-American Economic Affairs, 9: 2 (1955), pp. 4254 Google Scholar. This correction procedure should make Ford's estimates more accurate than those of Newland or Williamson, although his use of Argentina's official trade statistics is problematic because the statistical authorities did not use market prices for much of this period. See Roberto Cortés Conde, Tulio Halperin and Haydée Gorostegui de Torres, ‘Evolución del comercio exterior argentino: Tomo I: Exportaciones: Parte primera 1864–1930’, mimeo, 1965, available at the Biblioteca di Tella, Buenos Aires.

91 Francis, ‘Periphery's Terms of Trade’, p. 58.

92 Tena-Junguito, Antonio and Willebald, Henry, ‘On the Accuracy of Export Growth in Argentina, 1870–1913’, Economic History of Developing Regions, 28: 1 (2013), pp. 2868 Google Scholar.

93 Jacks, David, ‘Intra- and International Commodity Market Integration in the Atlantic Economy, 1800–1913’, Explorations in Economic History, 42: 3 (2005), pp. 381413 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and What Drove 19th Century Commodity Market Integration?’, Explorations in Economic History, 43: 3 (2006), pp. 383412 Google Scholar.

94 Moutoukias, ‘Crecimiento en una economía’, p. 804, Cuadro 3.

95 Anon., ‘Report on the Trade’, p. 33; and ‘Precios corrientes’, p. 60.

96 Broide, ‘Evolución de los precios’, pp. 41–3, 50, Cuadros 16–18 and 22.

97 Álvarez, Julio, Temas de historia económica argentina (Buenos Aires: El Ateneo, 1929), pp. 208–26Google Scholar.

98 Cortés Conde, Halperin Donghi and Gorostegui de Torres, ‘Evolución del comercio’, pp. 73–9.

99 As compiled in Dirección General de Estadística de la Nación, Extracto estadístico de la República Argentina correspondiente al año 1915 (Buenos Aires: Compañía Sud-Americana de Billetes de Banco, 1916), pp. 204–17Google Scholar; Bunge, Alejandro, Intercambio económico de la República, 1910–1917 (Buenos Aires: Talleres Gráficos Argentinos de L. J. Rosso y Cía, 1919)Google Scholar, chap. 11; and Vázquez-Presedo, Vicente, Estadísticas históricas argentinas (comparadas), vol. 2, Segunda parte 1914–1939 (Buenos Aires: Ediciones Macchi, 1971), pp. 194221 Google Scholar.

100 For 1780–1822, it was necessary to estimate the exchange rate based on the silver content of the peso and the price of silver in London. From Álvarez, Temas de historia, pp. 80–124; as compiled by Rodolfo G. Frank, online at www.anav.org.ar/sites_personales/5/MONEDA.xls (accessed 23 Dec. 2016); and Roy W. Jastram, Silver: The Restless Metal (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1981), Table 15 and App. C; reproduced by Greg Clark and Peter Lindert, online at http://gpih.ucdavis.edu/files/England_1209-1914_(Clark).xls (accessed 23 Dec. 2016). From 1816 onward, the exchange rate was compiled from Anon., ‘Precios corrientes’, p. 60; Schneider, Jürgen, Schwarzer, Otto and Denzel, Markus A., Währungen der Welt, vol. 7, Lateinamerikanische Devisenkurse im 19. und 20. Jahrhundert (Stuttgart: Franz Steiner Verlag, 1997), pp. 212–18Google Scholar; and Balboa, Manuel, ‘La evolución del balance de pagos de la República Argentina, 1913–1950’, Desarrollo Económico, 12: 45 (1972), p. 160 Google Scholar.

101 Weights and measures come from Tornquist, Ernesto, The Economic Development of the Argentine Republic in the Last Fifty Years (Buenos Aires: Ernesto Tornquist & Co., 1919), pp. 325–8Google Scholar.

102 International Monetary Fund, Producer Price Index: Theory and Practice (Washington, DC: World Bank, International Labour Organisation, International Monetary Fund, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, and United Nations, 2004), pp. 566 Google Scholar, 593.

103 The geometric mean has been preferred owing to its mathematical properties. See Hill, Robert J. and Fox, Kevin J., ‘Splicing Index Numbers’, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 15: 3 (1997), pp. 387–9Google Scholar.

104 When a series was not available for part of a subperiod, these weights were adjusted accordingly.

105 Bullion exports have been excluded from the index because they were essentially financial flows used to cover a merchandise trade deficit with Europe. Including them would, in any case, make little difference to the finding of a long terms-of-trade boom, given that bullion exports became insignificant by mid-century.

106 Moutoukias, ‘Crecimiento en una economía colonial’, pp. 805, 808, Cuadros 4 and 7.

107 Parish, Buenos Ayres, p. 353, Table 1.

108 Nine goods were included in Brazil's export price index. They were reweighted every 10 years according to their export value. Calculated from Fundação Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística, Estatísticas históricas do Brasil: Séries econômicas demográficas e sociais de 1550 a 1988, 2nd edn (Rio de Janeiro: IBGE, 1990), pp. 345–56Google Scholar.

109 Britain: Imlah, Albert H., Economic Elements in the Pax Britannica: Studies in British Foreign Trade in the Nineteenth Century (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1958), pp. 94–8Google Scholar, Table 8; Feinstein, Charles H., National Income, Expenditure and Output of the United Kingdom, 1855–1965 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Pres, 1972)Google Scholar, p. T132, Table 61; and Esteban, Javier Cuenca, ‘The Rising Share of British Industrial Exports in Industrial Output, 1700– 1851’, Journal of Economic History, 57: 4 (1997), p. 901 Google Scholar, App. Table 1. France: United Nations, ‘International Trade Statistics 1900–1960’, mimeo, 1962, Table 11, online at http://unstats.un.org/unsd/trade/imts/Historical%20data%201900-1960.pdf (accessed 24 Dec. 2016); and Maurice Lévy-Leboyer, ‘L'héritage de Simiand: Prix, profit et termes d'échange au XIX e siècle’, Revue Historique, 243 (1970), pp. 108–11, Tableau 5. Germany: Walther G. Hoffmann, Das Wachstum der deutschen Wirtschaft seit der Mitte des 19. Jahrhunderts (Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 1965), pp. 606–9, Table 151. Italy: Giovanni Federico, Sandra Natoli, Giuseppe Tattara and Michelangelo Vasta, Il commercio estero italiano 1862–1950 (Rome: Editori Laterza, 2011), pp. 228–9, Tabella 7b. United States: various series compiled in Irwin, Douglas A., ‘Exports and Imports of Merchandise – Price Indexes and Terms of Trade: 1790–2002’, in Carter, Susan B., Gartner, Scott Sigmund, Haines, Michael R., Olmstead, Alan L., Sutch, Richard and Wright, Gavin (eds.), Historical Statistics of the United States: Earliest Times to the Present: Millennial Edition (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2006)Google Scholar, online at http://hsus.cambridge.org/HSUSWeb/HSUSEntryServlet (accessed 24 Dec. 2016).

110 Using exchange rates from Lawrence H. Officer, ‘Dollar–Sterling Exchange Rates: 1791–1914’ and ‘Bilateral Exchange Rates – Europe: 1913–1999’, in Carter et al., Historical Statistics, Series Ee618, Ee625, Ee626, Ee629 and Ee636; and Denzel, Markus A., Handbook of World Exchange Rates, 1590–1914 (Farnham: Ashgate, 2010), pp. 1528 Google Scholar, 42–3.

111 In theory, Newland's proxy import price index for 1810–70 should be superior to the one used here. It consists of five goods that cover 50–60 per cent of imports for the 1820s, but less than 40 per cent for the 1860s. Dividing the new export price index with his import price index results in terms of trade with an annual trend of 1.4 per cent, compared to a 2 per cent annual trend when the new proxy import price index is used for the same period. This difference is largely due, however, to Newland's arbitrary downward adjustment of the share of cotton textiles in his index, from around 56 per cent to 32 per cent of the total. Had he used the higher figure, which his own numbers suggest is more accurate, his index would be far closer to the new one. See Newland, ‘Puramente animal’, Apéndices D and E.