Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dsjbd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T17:45:56.425Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Two notions of conventions: an experimental analysis

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 December 2008

LUIS M. MILLER*
Affiliation:
Max Planck Institute of Economics, Jena, Germany
*
*Correspondence to: Strategic Interaction Group, Max Planck Institute of Economics, Kahlaische Straße 10, 07745 Jena, Germany. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

This paper aims at analyzing the interaction between both economic and sociological notions of convention. To this end, it starts by distinguishing conceptually between specific convention, i.e. an arbitrary but stable social regularity, and general convention, i.e. a principle of action prescribing how to behave in a certain class of situations. A game theoretical framework to represent the interrelation between both concepts is then introduced. Finally, this relation is studied experimentally. The main results of the experiment are: (1) general conventions have to be commonly known and adopted among subjects in order to work as guides to coordinate on specific conventions; (2) once subjects follow a general convention they are highly consistent with it in a repeated environment; (3) efficiency concerns are focal in the class of games studied in this paper.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The JOIE Foundation 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Batifoulier, Philippe (2001), Théorie des conventions, Paris: Economica.Google Scholar
Bicchieri, Cristina (2006), The Grammar of Society, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Biggart, Nicole W. and Beamish, Thomas D. (2003), ‘The Economic Sociology of Conventions: Habit, Custom, Practice, and Routine in Market Order’, Annual Review of Sociology, 29: 443464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Ken (1992), Fun and Games: A Text on Game Theory, Lexington: D.C. Health.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken (1998), Just Playing. Game Theory and the Social Contract, Cambridge: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken (2005), Natural Justice, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Büchner, Susane, Güth, Werner and Miller, Luis M. (2005), ‘Conventions for Selecting among Conventions: An Evolutionary and Experimental Analysis’, Discussion Papers on Strategic Interaction, Jena: Max Planck Institute of Economics.Google Scholar
Cachon, Gerard P. and Camerer, Colin (1996), ‘Loss-avoidance and Forward Induction in Experimental Coordination Games’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111: 165194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, Kenneth, Kay, Stephen, and Sefton, Martin (2000), ‘When are Nash Equilibria Self-Enforcing? An Experimental Analysis’, International Journal of Game Theory, 29: 495515.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, James (1990), Foundations of Social Theory, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Cubitt, Robin P. and Sugden, Robert (2003), ‘Common Knowledge, Salience and Convention: A reconstruction of David Lewis’ Game Theory’, Economics and Philosophy, 19: 175210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dequech, David (2005), ‘Cognition and Valuation: Some Similarities and Contrasts between Institutional Economics and the Economics of Convention’, Journal of Economic Issues, 39: 465473.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. and Selten, Reinhard (1988), A General Theory of Equilibrium Selection in Games, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hume, David (1975 [1777]), An Enquiry Concerning the Principles of Morals, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hume, D. (1978 [1740]), A Treatise on Human Nature, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Favereau, Olivier (1986), ‘La formalisation du rôle des conventions dans l'allocation des ressources’, in Thévenot, Robert Salais y. Laurent (eds), Le Travail Marchés, règles, conventions, Paris : Economica.Google Scholar
Favereau, Olivier and Lazega, Emmanuel (eds) (2002), Conventions and Structures in Economic Organization, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, Urs (2007), ‘z-Tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-made Economic Experiments’, Experimental Economics, 10: 171178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, Margaret (1989), On Social Facts, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Greiner, Ben (2004), ‘An Online Recruitment System for Economic Experiments’, in Kremer, K. and Macho, V. (eds), Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen 2003: GWDG Bericht 63, Göttingen: Ges. für Wiss.Google Scholar
Lewis, David (1969), Conventions: A Philosophical Study, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Orléan, André (1999), Le pouvoir de la finance, Paris: Odile Jacob.Google Scholar
Orléan, André (2004), Analyse économique des conventions, Paris: Quadrige/Presses Universitaires de France.Google Scholar
Rankin, Frederick W., Huyck, John B. Van, and Battalio, Raymond C. (2000), ‘Strategic Similarity and Emergent Conventions: Evidence from Similar Stag Hunt Games’, Games and Economic Behavior, 32: 315337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rydval, Ondrej and Ortmann, Andreas (2005), ‘Loss Avoidance as Selection Principle: Evidence from Simple Stag-hunt Games’, Economics Letters, 88: 101107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schotter, Andrew (1981), The Economic Theory of Social Institutions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schotter, Andrew and Sopher, Barry (2003), ‘Social Learning and Coordination Conventions in Intergenerational Games: An Experimental Study’, Journal of Political Economy, 111: 498529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sillari, Giacomo (2005), ‘A Logical Framework for Convention’, Synthese, 147: 379400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, Brian (1996), The Evolution of the Social Contract, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert (1986), The Economics of Welfare, Rights and Co-operation, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert (1989), ‘Spontaneous Order’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3: 8597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert (1998), ‘Conventions’, in Newman, P. (eds), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, New York: Palgrave.Google Scholar
Ullmann-Margalit, Edna (1977), The Emergence of Norms, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Van Damme, Eric (1987), Stability and Perfection of Nash Equilibria, London: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van HuyckJ., R. C. Battalio J., R. C. Battalio, and Beil, R. O. (1990), ‘Tacit Coordination Games, Strategic Uncertainty, and Coordination Failure’, American Economic Review, 80 (1), 234248.Google Scholar
Van Huyck, John, Battalio, Raymond C., and Beil, Richard O. (1991), ‘Strategic Uncertainty, Equilibrium Selection, and Coordination Failure in Average Opinion Games’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106: 885911.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Huyck, John, Battalio, Raymond C., and Rankin, Frederick W. (1997), ‘On the Origin of Conventions: Evidence from Coordination Games’, The Economic Journal, 107: 576596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanderschraaf, Peter (1998), ‘Knowledge, Equilibrium and Convention’, Erkenntnis, 49: 337369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, Max (1978 [1922]), Economy and Society, Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Young, H. Peyton (1996), ‘The Economics of Convention’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10: 105122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar