Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T07:38:49.785Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Policy credibility and the political economy of reform: the case of Egypt's commodity subsidies

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 November 2013

DALIBOR ROHÁČ*
Affiliation:
Cato Institute, Washington DC, USA, and King's College London, United Kingdom

Abstract:

How can we account for the persistence of inefficient policies? To answer that question, this paper focuses on the issue of food and energy subsidies in Egypt. In 2012, over 13 percent of Egyptian GDP – roughly one-third of the overall government spending – was allocated to subsidies of prices of consumer goods including fuels and food. This paper offers an explanation of the resilience of commodity subsidies to reform, which relies on the inability of the government to credibly commit to a reform path. As a dictatorship, Egypt had a small number of veto players, making policy reversals easy. When opened to a competitive political process after 2011, Egypt lacked political groups that could make credible promises about policy changes. The paper provides a discussion of how appropriately designed reforms can mitigate the lack of credibility.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2013 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aboulenein, S., El-Laithy, H., and Kheir-El-Din, H. (2009), ‘The Impact of Phasing Out Subsidies of Petroleum Products in Egypt’, ECES Working Paper 145, Cairo: Egyptian Center for Economic Studies. http://www.eces.org.eg/publications/View_Pub.asp?p_id=10&p_detail_id=273#mytop (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2003), ‘Why Not a Political Coase Theorem? Social Conflict, Commitment, and Politics’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 31 (4): 620652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
African Development Bank (1999), Arab Republic of Egypt: Structural Adjustment Loan 1991–1994. Project Completion Report 1999–2001, African Development Bank, http://www.afdb.org/fileadmin/uploads/afdb/Documents/Project-and-Operations/ADB-BD-IF-99-130-EN-EGYPT-PCR-SAL.PDF (accessed 22 October 2013).Google Scholar
African Development Bank (2000), Egypt: Economic Reform and Structural Adjustment Programme. Project Performance Evaluation Report, African Development Bank, http://www.afdb.org/fileadmin/uploads/afdb/Documents/Evaluation-Reports/05092259-EN-EGYPT-ECONOMIC-REFORM-AND-SAP.PDF (accessed 22 October 2013).Google Scholar
Ahmed, A. U. and Bouis, H. E. (2002), ‘Weighing What's Practical: Proxy Means Tests for Targeting Food Subsidies in Egypt’, Food Policy 27 (5–6): 519540.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahmed, A. U., Bouis, H. E., Gutner, T., and Löfgren, H. (2001), ‘The Egyptian Subsidy System: Structure, Performance and Options for Reform’, International Food Policy Research Institute Research Report, 119. http://www.ifpri.org/sites/default/files/publications/ab119.pdf Washington DC: International Food Policy Research Institute (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
Albers, R. and Peeters, M. (2013), ‘Food and Energy prices, Government Subsidies and Fiscal Balances in South Mediterranean Countries’, Development Policy Review, 31 (3): 273290.Google Scholar
Alesina, A. and Drazen, A. (1991), ‘Why Are Stabilizations Delayed?’, American Economic Review, 81 (5): 11701188.Google Scholar
Ali, S. M. and Adams, R. H. Jr. (1996), ‘Egyptian Food Subsidy System: Operation and Effects on Income Distribution’, World Development, 24 (11): 17771791.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alissa, S. (2007), ‘The Political Economy of Reform in Egypt: Understanding the Role of Institutions’, Carnegie Papers, 5, http://carnegieendowment.org/files/cmec5_alissa_egypt_final.pdf, Washington DC: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, (accessed 22 October 2013).Google Scholar
Arvis, J.-F., Mustra, M. A., Ojala, L., Shepherd, B., and Saslavsky, D. (2010), Connecting to Compete 2010: Trade Logistics in the Global Economy. The Logistics Performance Index and Its Indicators. Washington DC: World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Åslund, A., Boone, P., and Johnson, S. (1996), ‘How to Stabilize: Lessons from Post-Communist Countries’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1996 (1): 217313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bagash, T., Pereznieto, P., and Dubai, K. (2012), Transforming Cash Transfers:Beneficiary and community perspectives on the Social Welfare Fund in Yemen, London: Overseas Development Institute, http://www.odi.org.uk/sites/odi.org.uk/files/odi-assets/publications-opinion-files/8181.pdf (accessed 22 October 2013).Google Scholar
Berry, C. R., Burden, B. C., and Howell, W. G. (2006), ‘Matters of Life and Death: The Durability of Discretionary Programs 1970–2004’, Presented at the 2006 meeting of the American Political Science Association.Google Scholar
Boettke, P. J. (1995) ‘Credibility, Commitment and Soviet Economic Reform’, in Lazear, E. (ed.), Economic Transition in Eastern Europe and Russia: Realities of Reform, Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press, pp. 247275.Google Scholar
Brazil's Ministry of Social Development (2013), Website of Brazil's Ministry of Social Development. http://www.mds.gov.br/bolsafamilia/beneficios (accessed 22 October 2013).Google Scholar
Campos, J. E. and Salehi Esfahani, H. (2000), ‘Credible Commitment and Success with Public Enterprise Reform’, World Development, 28 (2): 221243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caplan, B. (2007), The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Castel, V. (2012), Reforming Energy Subsidies in Egypt, Tunis: African Development Bank.Google Scholar
Coady, D., El-Said, M., Gillingham, R., Kpodar, K., Medas, P., and Newhouse, D. (2006), ‘The Magnitude and Distribution of Fuel Subsidies: Evidence from Bolivia, Ghana, Jordan, Mali, and Sri Lanka’, IMF Working Paper 06/247, Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2006/wp06247.pdf (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
Coady, D., Gillingham, R., Ossowski, R., Piotrowski, J., Tareq, S., and Tyson, J. (2010), ‘Petroleum Product Subsidies: Costly, Inequitable, and Rising’, IMF Staff Position Note 10/05, Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1005.pdf (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
Coate, S. and Morris, S. (1999), ‘Policy Persistence’, American Economic Review, 89 (5): 13271336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commander, S. (2012), ‘A Guide to the Political Economy of Reforming Energy Subsidies’, IZA Policy Paper 52, Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labour. http://ftp.iza.org/pp52.pdf (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
Coyne, C. J. and Boettke, P. J. (2009), ‘The Problem of Credible Commitment in Reconstruction’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 5 (1): 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coyne, C. J. and Leeson, P. T. (2009), Media, Development, and Institutional Change (New Thinking in Political Economy), Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daragahi, B. (2013), ‘Diesel Shortages Fuel Egypt's Challenges’, Financial Times, http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/bd6d84b0–979c-11e2-97e0-00144feabdc0.html (accessed 1 April 2013).Google Scholar
De Moor, A. and Calamai, P. (1997), Subsidizing Unsustainable Development, Earth Council and Institute for Research on Public Expenditure, Washington DC: Earth Council and The Hague. http://www.cbd.int/doc/case-studies/inc/cs-inc-earthcouncil-unsustainable-en.pdf (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
Del Granado, J. A., Coady, D., and Gillingham, R. (2010), ‘The Unequal Benefits of Fuel Subsidies: A Review of Evidence for Developing Countries’, IMF Working Paper 10/202, Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2010/wp10202.pdf (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
De Soto, H. (2000), The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Downs, A. (1957), An Economic Theory of Democracy, New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Drábek, Z., Janáček, K., and Tůma, Z. (1993), ‘Inflation in Czechoslovakia, 1985–1991’, Working Paper 1135, World Bank.Google Scholar
Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs (2009), Market Survey Egypt: Oil and Gas. Market Survey by EVD and Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
Egypt Human Development Report 2010. (2010), United Nations Development Programme and Institute of National Planning, Egypt.Google Scholar
Egyptian Center for Economic Studies (2010), ‘The Subsidy System in Egypt: Alternatives for Reform’, Policy Viewpoint, 25, Cairo: Egyptian Center for Economic Studies. http://www.eces.org.eg/Uploaded_Files/%7B10D14532-9640-4DCE-A76E-EBAD724A51D4%7D_PVP25-Eng.pdf (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
Egyptian Ministry of Finance (2012), Financial Statement of State's General Budget for Fiscal year 2012/2013. Ministry of Finance, Arab Republic of Egypt.Google Scholar
Fang, S. and Owen, E. (2011), ‘International Institutions and Credible Commitment of Non-Democracies’, Review of International Organizations, 6 (2): 141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fattouh, B. and El-Kattiri, L. (2012), ‘Energy Subsidies in the Arab World’, Arab Human Development Report Research Paper, United Nations Development Programme, http://www.undp.org/content/dam/undp/library/Environment%20and%20Energy/UNDP-EE-AHDR-Energy-Subsidies-2012-Final.pdf (accessed 22 October 2013).Google Scholar
Fernandez, R. and Rodrik, D. (1991), ‘Resistance to Reform: Status Quo Bias in the Presence of Individual-Specific Uncertainty’, American Economic Review, 81 (5): 11461155.Google Scholar
Frye, T. (2004), ‘Credible Commitment and Property Rights: Evidence from Russia’, American Political Science Review, 98 (3): 453466.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghoneim, A. F. (2012), ‘The Political Economy of Food Price Policy in Egypt’, United Nations University Working Paper 2012/96, http://www.wider.unu.edu/publications/working-papers/2012/en_GB/wp2012-096/ (accessed 22 October 2013).Google Scholar
Gutner, T. (2002), ‘The Political Economy of Food Subsidy Reform: The Case of Egypt’, Food Policy, 27: 455476.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halime, F. (2013), ‘Reinventing Egypt's Energy Subsidies’, Rebel Economy (blog), http://rebeleconomy.com/economy/reinventing-egypts-energy-subsidies/ (accessed 21 May 2013).Google Scholar
International Labour Organisation (2013), National aid fund: Jordan. http://www.ilo.org/dyn/ilossi/ssimain.viewScheme?p_lang=en&p_geoaid=400&p_scheme_id=1665 (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
International Monetary Fund (2013), Energy Subsidy Reform: Lessons and Implications. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Keefer, P. and Knack, S. (2007), ‘Boondoggles, Rent-Seeking, and Political Checks and Balances: Public Investment under Unaccountable Governments’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 89 (3): 566572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keefer, P. and Stasavage, D. (2001), Bureacratic Delegation and Political Institutions: When are Independent Central Banks Irrelevant? World Bank Policy Research Paper 2356, Washington DC: World Bank. http://elibrary.worldbank.org/content/workingpaper/10.1596/1813-9450-2356 (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
Keefer, P. and Vlaicu, R. (2008), ‘Democracy, Credibility and Clientelism’, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 24 (2): 371406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kydland, F. E. and Prescott, E. C. (1977), ‘Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans’, Journal of Political Economy, 85 (3): 473492.Google Scholar
Maltzman, F. and Shipan, C. R. (2008), ‘Change, Continuity, and the Evolution of the Law’, American Journal of Political Science, 52 (2): 252267.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansour, S. (2012), ‘Egypt Grain and Feed Annual Wheat and Corn Production on the Rise’, GAIN Report, Washington DC: USDA Foreign Agricultural Service. http://gain.fas.usda.gov/Recent%20GAIN%20Publications/Grain%20and%20Feed%20Annual_Cairo_Egypt_4-2-2012.pdf (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
Moe, T. M. (1989), ‘The Politics of Bureaucratic Structure’, in Chubb, John E. and Peterson, P. E. (eds.), Can the Government Govern? Washington DC: Brookings, pp. 267329.Google Scholar
Patashnik, E. M. (2000), Putting Trust in the U.S. Budget: Federal Trust Funds and the Politics of Commitment,. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patashnik, E. M. (2003), ‘After the Public Interest Prevails: The Political Sustainability of Policy Reform’, Governance, 16 (2): 203234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patashnik, E. M. (2008), Reforms at Risk: What Happens after Major Policy Changes are Enacted, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Pelham, N. (2012), ‘Gaza's Tunnel Phenomenon: The Unintended Dynamics of Israel's Siege’, Journal of Palestine Studies, 41 (4): 631.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D. (1988), ‘Promises, Promises: Credible Policy Reform via Signaling’, NBER Working Paper, 2600, Cambridge MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. http://www.nber.org/papers/w2600 (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
Roháč, D. (2013a), ‘Religion as a Commitment Device: The Economics of Political Islam’, Kyklos, 66 (2): 256274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roháč, D. (2013b), ‘What Are the Lessons from Post-Communist Transitions?’, Economic Affairs, 33 (1): 6577.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roháč, D. (2013c), Solving Egypt's Subsidy Problem. Cato Institute Policy Analysis, Washington DC: Cato Institute, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Schneider, R. R. (1988), ‘A Framework for Analyzing Food Subsidies’, World Development, 16 (7): 835845.Google Scholar
Soliman, A. M. (2004), A Possible Way Out: Formalizing Housing Informality in Egyptian Cities, Lanham: University Press of America.Google Scholar
Talercio, J. R. (2004), ‘Administrative Reform as Credible Commitment: The Impact of Autonomy on Revenue Authority Performance in Latin America’, World Development, 32 (2): 213232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, D. W. (2009), ‘Deregulation Despite Transitional Gains: The Brewers Guild of Cologne 1461’, Public Choice, 140 (3): 329340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tollison, R. D. and Wagner, R. E. (1991), ‘Romance, Realism, and Economic Reform’, Kyklos, 44 (1): 5770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, G. (1967), ‘The Welfare Cost of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft’, Western Economic Journal, 5 (3): 224232.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1975), ‘The Transitional Gains Trap’, Bell Journal of Economics, 6 (2): 671678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vagliasindi, M. (2012), ‘Implementing Energy Subsidy Reforms: An Overview of the Key Issues’, Policy Research Working Paper 6122, Washington DC: World Bank. http://elibrary.worldbank.org/content/workingpaper/10.1596/1813-9450-6122 (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
Weingast, B. R. (1997), ‘The Political Foundations of Limited Government: Parliament and Sovereign Debt in 17th and 18th Century England’ in John, V. C. Nye and Drobak, J. N. (eds.), Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, Academic Press, New York, NY, pp. 213246.Google Scholar
World Bank (2005), Egypt – Toward a More Effective Social Policy: Subsidies and Social Safety Net. Washington DC: World Bank Document. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTPSIA/Resources/490023-1120841262639/Egypt_Safety_Nets.pdf (accessed 22 October, 2013).Google Scholar
World Bank (2010), ‘Egypt's Food Subsidies: Benefit Incidence and Leakages', Document of the World Bank, 57446, Washington DC: World Bank.Google Scholar