Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-gb8f7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T05:48:44.428Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Money and its institutional substitutes: the role of exchange institutions in human cooperation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 September 2017

CAMERON HARWICK*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA, United States

Abstract

This paper offers an increasing returns model of the evolution of exchange institutions building on Smith's dictum that ‘the division of labor is limited by the extent of the market’. Exchange institutions are characterized by a tradeoff between fixed and marginal costs: the effort necessary to execute an exchange may be economized by up-front ‘investment’ in strategies to facilitate the publication and accounting of trading histories. Increases in the size of the exchange network select for higher-fixed-cost exchange institutions, beginning with autarky, through various intermediate stages, and finally to mass monetary exchange. By identifying the relevant fixed costs of money and its institutional substitutes across time, the paper both accounts for the persistence of pre-monetary exchange institutions, despite the ‘inevitability’ of monetary exchange that seems to be a feature of traditional models of the origin of money, and illuminates the forces driving the transition from one to another.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alchian, A. (1977), ‘Why money?’ Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 9 (1): 133–40.Google Scholar
Armstrong, W. E. (1924), ‘Rossel Island money: a unique monetary system’, Economic Journal, 34 (135): 423–9.Google Scholar
Bandy, M. S. (2004), ‘Fissioning, scalar stress, and social evolution in early village societies’, American Anthropologist, 106 (2): 322–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, A. and Maskin, E. S. (1996), ‘A Walrasian theory of money and barter’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111 (4): 9551005.Google Scholar
Bear, A and Rand, D. G. (2016), ‘Intuition, deliberation, and the evolution of cooperation’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 113 (4): 936–41.Google Scholar
Bear, A, Kagan, A. and Rand, D. G. (2017), ‘Co-evolution of cooperation and cognition: the impact of imperfect deliberation and context-sensitive intuition’, Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 284 (2326).Google ScholarPubMed
Bloch, M. (1966), ‘The rise of dependent cultivation and seigniorial institutions’, in Postan, M. M. (ed.), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, Vol. 1, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 235–90.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. and Gintis, H. (2004), ‘The evolution of strong reciprocity: cooperation in heterogeneous populations’, Theoretical Population Biology, 65 (1): 1728.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. and Gintis, H. (2008), ‘Cooperation’, in Blume, L. and Durlauf, S. (eds), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: MacMillan. pp. 228–34.Google Scholar
Chagnon, N. ([1968]2009), Yąnomamö, Belmont, CA: Wadsworth Cengage.Google Scholar
Clark, A. and Chalmers, D. (1998), ‘The extended mind’, Analysis, 58 (1): 719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deheane, S. (1997), The Number Sense: How The Mind Creates Mathematics, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Dittmar, J. E. and Meisenzahl, R. R. (2016), ‘State capacity and public goods: institutional change, human capital, and growth in early modern Germany’, Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 2016–028.Google Scholar
Dunbar, R. I. M. (1992), ‘Neocortex size as a constraint on group size in primates’, Journal of Human Evolution, 22 (6), 469–93.Google Scholar
Dunbar, R. I. M. (1995), ‘Neocortex size and group size in primates: a test of the hypothesis’, Journal of Human Evolution, 28 (3), 287–96.Google Scholar
Epps, P, Bowern, C., Hansen, C. A., Hill, J. H., and Zentz, J. (2012), ‘On numeral complexity in hunter–gatherer languages’, Linguistic Typology, 16 (1): 41109.Google Scholar
Everett, D. L. (2005), ‘Cultural constraints on grammar and cognition in Pirahã: another look at the design features of human language’, Current Anthropology, 46 (4): 621–46.Google Scholar
Frank, R. H. (1987), ‘If homo oeconomicus could choose his own utility function, would he want one with a conscience?’ American Economic Review, 77 (4): 593604.Google Scholar
Gangotena, S. (2016), ‘Subsistence or exchange: the emergence of money and specialization’, PhD Dissertation, George Mason University, Virginia.Google Scholar
Golla, V. (2011), California Indian languages, Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Goodhart, C. A. E. (1998), ‘The two concepts of money: implications for the analysis of optimal currency areas’, European Journal of Political Economy, 14 (3): 407–32.Google Scholar
Greenberg, J. (1978), ‘Generalizations about numeral systems’, in Greenberg, J., Ferguson, C., and Moravcsik, E. (eds), Universals of Human Language, Vol. 3: Word Structure, Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Harwick, C. (2016), ‘Cryptocurrency and the problem of intermediation’, Independent Review, 20 (4): 569–88.Google Scholar
Hauser, M; Chomsky, N. and Fitch, W. T. (2002), ‘The faculty of language: what is it, who has it, and how did it evolve?’ Science, 298 (5598): 1569–79.Google Scholar
Haxby, J. V., Hoffman, E. A., and Gobbini, M. I. (2002), ‘Human neural systems for face recognition and social communication’, Biological Psychiatry, 51 (1): 5967.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1945), ‘The use of knowledge in society’, American Economic Review, 35 (4): 519–30.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1960), The Constitution of Liberty, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R. (1935), ‘A suggestion for simplifying the theory of money’, Economica, 2 (5): 119.Google Scholar
Hoekman, B. (2015), ‘Trade and growth – the end of an era?’ in Hoekman, B. (ed.), The Global Trade Slowdown: A New Normal?, London: Centre for Economic Policy Research Press.Google Scholar
Hooper, P., Demps, K., Gurven, M., Gerney, D., and Kaplan, H. (2015), ‘Skills, division of labour, and economies of scale among Amazonian hunters and South Indian honey collectors’, Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B, 370 (0008).Google Scholar
Horwitz, S. (1992), ‘Monetary exchange as an extra-linguistic social communication process’, Review of Social Economy, 50 (2): 193214.Google Scholar
Hudson, M. (2003a), ‘The role of accounting in civilization's economic takeoff’, in Hudson, M. and Wunsch, C. (eds), Creating Economic Order: Record-Keeping, Standardization, and the Development of Accounting in the Ancient Near East, Bethesda: CDL Press, pp. 122.Google Scholar
Hudson, M. (2003b), ‘The development of money of account in Sumer's temples’, in Hudson, M. and Wunsch, C. (eds), Creating Economic Order: Record-Keeping, Standardization, and the Development of Accounting in the Ancient Near East, Bethesda: CDL Press, pp. 303–30.Google Scholar
Humphrey, C. (1985), ‘Barter and economic disintegration’, Man, 20 (1): 4872.Google Scholar
Johnson, N. and Koyama, M. (2016), ‘States and economic growth: capacity and constraints’, Explorations in Economic History, 64: 120.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1972), ‘The irrelevance of equilibrium economics’, Economic Journal, 82 (328): 1237–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiyotaki, N. and Wright, R. (1993), ‘A search-theoretic approach to monetary economics’, American Economic Review, 83 (1): 6377.Google Scholar
Klein, B., Crawford, R., and Alchian, A. (1978), ‘Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process’, Journal of Law and Economics, 21 (1): 297326.Google Scholar
Kocherlakota, N. R. (1996), ‘Money is memory’, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report, 218.Google Scholar
Kohn, M. (1999), ‘Medieval and early modern coinage and its problems’, draft chapter of Origins Of Western Economic Success: Commerce, Finance, and Government in Preindustrial Europe, Preprint.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koppl, R. (2002). Big Players and the Economic Theory of Expectations, New York: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lachmann, L. (1956), Capital and its Structure, Kansas City: Sheed Andrews and McMeel.Google Scholar
Lavoie, D. (1985), Rivalry and Central Planning: The Socialist Calculation Debate Reconsidered, London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Leeson, P. and Suarez, P. (2015), ‘Superstition and self-governance’, Advances in Austrian Economics, 19: 4766.Google Scholar
Leijonhufvud, A. (1977), ‘Costs and consequences of inflation’, in Harcourt, G. C. (ed.), The Microeconomic Foundations of Macroeconomics. London: Macmillan, pp. 265312.Google Scholar
Malinowski, B. (1922), Argonauts of the Western Pacific: An Account of Native Enterprise and Adventure in the Archipelagos of Melanesian New Guinea, New York, E. P. Dutton.Google Scholar
Malinowski, B. (1926), Crime and Custom in Savage Society, New York: Harcourt Brace.Google Scholar
Marwick, B. (2003), ‘Pleistocene exchange networks as evidence for the evolution of language’, Cambridge Archaeological Journal, 13 (1): 6781.Google Scholar
Mederos, A. and Lamberg-Karlovsky, C. C. (2004), ‘Weight systems and trade networks in the Old World (2500–1000 BC)’, in Hudson, M. and Wunsch, C. (eds), Creating Economic Order: Record-Keeping, Standardization, and the Development of Accounting in the Ancient Near East, Bethesda: CDL Press, pp. 199214.Google Scholar
Menger, C. (1892), ‘On the origins of money’, Economic Journal, 2: 239–55, translated by Foley, C. A..Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1848), Principles of Political Economy with some of their Applications to Social Philosophy, London: John W. Parker.Google Scholar
Miller, G. (1992), Managerial Dilemmas: The Political Economy of Hierarchy, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mises, L. v. ([1920]1935), ‘Economic calculation in the socialist commonwealth’, in Hayek, F. A. (ed.), Collectivist Economic Planning: Critical Studies on the Possibilities of Socialism, London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, pp. 87130.Google Scholar
Mises, L. v. (1966), Human Action: A Treatise on Economics, San Francisco: Fox and Wilkes.Google Scholar
Mitchell, W. C. (1944), ‘The role of money in economic history’, Journal of Economic History, 4: 61–7.Google Scholar
North, D. C. and Weingast, B. (1989), ‘Constitutions and commitment: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England’, Journal of Economic History, 49 (4): 803–32.Google Scholar
North, D. C., Wallis, J., and Weingast, B. (2009), Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nye, J. V. (1991), ‘The myth of Free-Trade Britain and Fortress France: tariffs and trade in the nineteenth century’, Journal of Economic History, 51 (1): 2346.Google Scholar
Polanyi, K. (1944), The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time, Boston: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Purzycki, B., Apicella, C., Atkinson, Q., Cohen, E., McNamara, R., Willard, A., Xygalatas, D., Norenzayan, A., and Heinrich, J. (2016), ‘Moralistic gods, supernatural punishment, and the expansion of human sociality’, Nature, 530: 327–30.Google Scholar
Quiggin, A. H. (1949), A Survey of Primitive Money: The Beginnings of Currency, London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Redish, A. (1990), ‘The evolution of the gold standard in England’, Journal of Economic History, 50 (4): 789805.Google Scholar
Ridgeway, W. (1892), The Origin of Metallic Currency and Weight Standards, London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Salter, A. W. and Luther, W. (2014), ‘Synthesizing state and spontaneous order theories of money’, Advances in Austrian Economics, 18: 161–78.Google Scholar
Schmandt-Besserat, D. (1992), Before Writing, Vol. 1: From Counting to Cuneiform, Austin: University of Texas Press.Google Scholar
Shariff, A. F. and Norenzayan, A. (2011), ‘Mean gods make good people: different views of God predict cheating behavior’, International Journal for the Psychology of Religion, 21 (2): 8596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmel, G. ([1907]1978), The Philosophy of Money, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1776), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, London: Strahan and Cadell.Google Scholar
Smith, D, Dyble, M., Thompson, J., Major, K., Page, A., Chaudhary, N., Salali, G., Vinicius, L., Migliano, A., and Mace, R. (2016), ‘Camp stability predicts patterns of hunter–gatherer cooperation’, Royal Society Open Science, 3 (160131).Google Scholar
Spufford, P. (1988), Money and its Use in Medieval Europe, London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stewart, A. J., Parsons, T. L., and Plotkin, J. B. (2016), ‘Evolutionary consequences of behavioral diversity’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 113 (45): E7003–E7009.Google Scholar
Szabo, N. (2002), ‘Shelling out: the origins of money’, Satoshi Nakamoto Institute.Google Scholar
Tomasello, M. (2009), Why We Cooperate, Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Wiessner, P. (1977), Hxaro: A Regional System of Reciprocity for Reducing Risk among the !Kung San, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan.Google Scholar
Wilson, D. S. and Gowdy, J. M. (2015), ‘Human ultrasociality and the invisible hand: foundational developments in evolutionary science alter a foundational concept in economics’, Journal of Bioeconomics, 17: 3752.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, E. O. (1975), Sociobiology: The New Synthesis, Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.Google Scholar
Wray, L. R. (2004), ‘The credit money, state money, and endogenous money approaches: a survey and attempted integration’, Working paper available at https://cas.umkc.edu/economics/people/facultyPages/wray/papers/Working%20Papers/CREDIT&STATE%20MONEY%20JOIE%20revised.doc (accessed 10 July 2017).Google Scholar