Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-24T03:19:57.941Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Frank Knight and the cognitive diversity of entrepreneurship

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 May 2021

Malte F. Dold*
Affiliation:
Economics Department, Pomona College, 425 N. College Avenue, Claremont, CA91711, USA
Mario J. Rizzo
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, New York University, 19 West 4th Street, New York, NY10003, USA
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]

Abstract

In Risk, Uncertainty and Profit (RUP), Knight (1921) develops a theory of the firm that stresses the important role of entrepreneurial judgment for a firm's success. For Knight, entrepreneurial judgment is first and foremost the selection of ‘proxy entrepreneurs’ who are capable of making good judgments under uncertainty. In this sense, entrepreneurial judgment is essentially ‘judgment of judgment’. An overlooked implication of Knight's position is the fact that it leads to an endorsement of distributed entrepreneurship and responsibility. We deem this a very modern idea that challenges a completely hierarchical understanding of the firm. Knight himself does not thoroughly examine the institutional implications of the analytical framework he sets up in RUP. In this paper, we summarize the ‘philosophical vision’ of Knight's framework and illustrate his rationale behind the distribution of entrepreneurship. We conclude the paper with a discussion of potential institutional implications by referring to the danger of monocultures, the additional value created by cognitively diverse teams, and the effectiveness of venture capitalists.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Millennium Economics Ltd.

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Agassi, J. (1975), ‘Institutional Individualism’, The British Journal of Sociology, 26(2): 144155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asso, P. F. and Fiorito, L. (2008), ‘Was Frank Knight an Institutionalist?’, Review of Political Economy, 20(1): 5977.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brander, J. A., Amit, R. and Antweiler, W. (2002), ‘Venture-Capital Syndication: Improved Venture Selection vs. the Value-Added Hypothesis’, Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 11(3): 423452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bronk, R. and Jacoby, W. (2016), ‘Uncertainty and the Dangers of Monocultures in Regulation, Analysis, and Practice’, MPIfG Discussion Paper, No. 16/6.Google Scholar
Buskirk, E. V. (2009), ‘How the Netflix Prize was Won’, WIRED, September 22, 2009. https://www.wired.com/2009/09/how-the-netflix-prize-was-won.Google Scholar
Casson, M. C. (2000), ‘An Entrepreneurial Theory of the Firm’. in Nicolai, J. Foss and Volker, Mahn (eds), Competence, Governance and Entrepreneurship: Advances in Economic Strategy Research, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 116145.Google Scholar
De Wit, F. R., Greer, L. L. and Jehn, K. A. (2012), ‘The Paradox of Intragroup Conflict: A Meta-analysis’, Journal of Applied Psychology, 97(2): 360390.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Emmett, R. B. (2011), ‘Frank H. Knight on the Entrepreneur Function in Modern Enterprise’, Seattle UL Rev, 34(4): 11391154.Google Scholar
Feyerabend, P. K. (1975/2010), Against Method, London: Verso.Google Scholar
Fiorito, L. (2016), ‘“A Certain Amount of ‘Recantation’”: On the Origins of Frank H. Knight's Antipositivism’, History of Political Economy, 48(1): 134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, N. J. and Klein, P. G. (2012), Organizing Entrepreneurial Judgment: A New Approach to the Firm, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, N. J., Klein, P. G., Kor, Y. Y. and Mahoney, J. T. (2008), ‘Entrepreneurship, Subjectivism, and the Resource-Based View: Toward A new synthesis’, Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 2(1): 7394.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gompers, P. A., Gornall, W., Kaplan, S. N. and Strebulaev, I. A. (2020), ‘How do Venture Capitalists Make Decisions?’, Journal of Financial Economics, 135(1): 169190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hambrick, D. C., Cho, T. S. and Chen, M. J. (1996), ‘The Influence of Top Management Team Heterogeneity on Firms’ Competitive Moves’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 41(4): 659684.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harker, D. (2015), Creating Scientific Controversies: Uncertainty and Bias in Science and Society, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1945), ‘The Use of Knowledge in Society’, The American Economic Review, 35(4): 519530.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. (2001), ‘Frank Knight as Institutionalist Economist’, in Biddle, J. E., Davis, J. B. and Medema, S. G. (eds), Economics Broadly Considered: Essays in Honor of Warren J. Samuels, London: Routledge, pp. 6493.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2004), The Evolution of Institutional Economics, London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
James, W. (1890), Principles of Psychology, vol. 1 and 2 vols, New York: Henry Holt & Co.Google Scholar
James, W. (1909/1977), A Pluralistic Universe, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
James, W. (1911/1996), Some Problems of Philosophy: A Beginning of an Introduction to Philosophy, Lincoln, NE: University of Nebraska Press.Google Scholar
James, W. (1912/2003), Essays in Radical Empiricism, Mineola, NY: Dover Publications.Google Scholar
Kanchanabha, B. and Badir, Y. F. (2021). Top Management Team's Cognitive Diversity and the Firm's Ambidextrous Innovation Capability: The Mediating Role of Ambivalent Interpretation. Technology in Society, 64(8): 101499. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techsoc.2020.101499CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kilduff, M., Angelmar, R. and Mehra, A. (2000), ‘Top Management-Team Diversity and Firm Performance: Examining the Role of cognitions’, Organization Science, 11(1): 2134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1921/1933), ‘Preface to the Re-Issue’, Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, London: London School of Economics and Political Science, pp. xixxxvi.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1921/1957), ‘Preface to the Reprint of 1957’, Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, New York: Kelley & Millman, pp. liilxi.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1921), Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, Boston and New York: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1922/2011), ‘Logical Method in the Social Sciences’. in Emmett, R. B. (ed.), Frank Knight in Iowa City, 1919–1928 (Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology, vol. 29-B), Bingley, UK: Emerald Publishing, pp. 103122.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1924), ‘The Limitations of Scientific Method in Economics’, in H. Jones, M. Friedman, , G. Stigler, and , A. Wallis (eds), The Ethics of Competition and Other Essays, 1935, Freeport: Books for Libraries Press, reprinted 1969, pp. 105147.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1925), ‘Fact and Metaphysics in Economic Psychology’, The American Economic Review, 15(2): 247266.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1933), ‘Six Criticisms of “The Arbitrary as Basis for Rational Morality”’, The International Journal of Ethics, 43(2): 148151.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H. (1947), Freedom and Reform: Essays in Economics and Social Philosophy, New York: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (1991), Equilibrium and Evolution: An Exploration of Connecting Principles in Economics, Manchester, UK: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (1999), Knowledge, Institutions and Evolution in Economics, London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (2007), ‘A Cognitive Perspective on Entrepreneurship and the Firm’, Journal of Management Studies, 44(7): 10781106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lunenburg, F. C. (2011), ‘Decision Making in Organizations’, International Journal of Management, Business, and Administration, 15(1): 19.Google Scholar
March, J. G. (1994), A Primer on Decision Making: How Decisions Happen, New York, NY: The Free Press.Google Scholar
McMullen, J. S. (2015), ‘Entrepreneurial Judgment as Empathic Accuracy: A Sequential Decision-Making Approach to Entrepreneurial Action’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 11(3): 651681.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, C. C., Burke, L. M. and Glick, W. H. (1998), ‘Cognitive Diversity among Upper-Echelon Executives: Implications for Strategic Decision Processes’, Strategic Management Journal, 19(1): 3958.3.0.CO;2-A>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nowak, R. (2020), ‘Process of Strategic Planning and Cognitive Diversity as Determinants of Cohesiveness and Performance’, Business Process Management Journal, 27(1): 5574.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, B. J., Parayitam, S. and Bao, Y. (2007), ‘Strategic Decision Making: The Effects of Cognitive Diversity, Conflict, and Trust on Decision Outcomes’, Journal of Management, 33(2): 196222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, S. E. (2007), The Difference: How the Power of Diversity Creates Better Groups, Firms, Schools, and Societies, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Page, S. E. (2014), ‘Where Diversity Comes From and Why it Matters?’, European Journal of Social Psychology, 44(4): 267279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, S. E. (2017), The Diversity Bonus: How Great Teams pay off in the Knowledge Economy, Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rakow, T. (2010), ‘Risk, Uncertainty and Prophet: The Psychological Insights of Frank H. Knight’, Judgment and Decision Making, 5(6): 458–266.Google Scholar
Rizzo, M. J. (1990), ‘Hayek's Four Tendencies Toward Equilibrium’, Cultural Dynamics, 3(1): 1231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rizzo, M. J. and Dold, M. F. (forthcoming), ‘Knightian Uncertainty: Through a Jamesian Window’, Cambridge Journal of Economics.Google Scholar
Rizzo, M. J. and Whitman, G. (2020), Escaping Paternalism: Rationality, Behavioral Economics, and Public Policy, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sah, R. K. and Stiglitz, J. E. (1986), ‘The Architecture of Economic Systems: Hierarchies and Polyarchies’, The American Economic Review, 76(5): 716727.Google Scholar
Sahlman, W. A. (1990), ‘The Structure and Governance of Venture-Capital Organizations’, Journal of Financial Economics, 27(2): 473521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sautet, F. E. (2000), An Entrepreneurial Theory of the Firm, London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schoemaker, P. J. and Tetlock, P. E. (2016), ‘Superforecasting: How to Upgrade Your Company's Judgment’, Harvard Business Review, 94(5): 7278.Google Scholar
Shin, S. J., Kim, T. Y., Lee, J. Y. and Bian, L. (2012), ‘Cognitive Team Diversity and Individual Team Member Creativity: A Cross-Level Interaction’, Academy of Management Journal, 55(1): 197212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stark, D. (2009), The Sense of Dissonance: Accounts of Worth in Economic Life, Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tetlock, P. E. and Gardner, D. (2015), Superforecasting: The Art and Science of Prediction, New York: Crown.Google Scholar
Witt, U. (1998), ‘Imagination and Leadership: The Neglected Dimensions of an Evolutionary Theory of the Firm’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 35(2): 161177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar