Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T00:03:55.497Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Re-feudalizing democracy: an approach to authoritarian populism taken from institutional economics

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 June 2019

Zoltán Ádám*
Affiliation:
Corvinus University of Budapest, Department of Comparative and Institutional Economics, Budapest, Hungary.

Abstract

Research on populism has gained importance in the light of the recent global populist surge. Political scientists have become concerned with the problem of authoritarian populism, examining how illiberal, anti-pluralist populist parties have degraded liberal democracies. Economic research on recent forms of populism, although also growing, lack a comprehensive conceptual approach. This paper reduces this gap by conceptualizing authoritarian populism in terms of political transaction costs, arguing that its primary function is to vertically integrate political exchange under conditions of general franchise. If successful, authoritarian populist regimes internalize a large share of political transaction costs inherent in decentralized democratic political exchange. This entails a degraded version of democracy, eliminating a significant part of substantial electoral choice. Through weakening impersonal collective political contracting, authoritarian populists bring back private political contracting as a dominant political coordination mechanism, effectively re-feudalizing democracy.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the departmental seminar of Central European University's Department of Political Science (Budapest) in 2017 and at the Kornai'90 conference at Corvinus University of Budapest in 2018. Comments by seminar and conference participants, especially by András Bozóki, Zsolt Enyedi, Geoffrey Hodgson and Andrea Szalavetz, are gratefully acknowledged. Anikó Bakonyi, Rogers Brubaker, György Petőcz, András Simonovits and the anonymous reviewers also provided a useful critique, and helped improve the text.

References

Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2000), ‘Why Did the West Extend the Franchise? Democracy, Inequality, and Growth in Historical Perspective’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(4): 11671199.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2006), The Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2012), Why Nations Fail? The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty, New York: Crown Publishers.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson, J. (2005), ‘The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change and Economic Growth’, American Economic Review, 95(2): 546579.Google Scholar
Ádám, Z. (2018), ‘What Is Populism? An Institutional Economics Approach with Reference to Hungary’, in Ádám, Z. (ed.), Varieties of Transition. Papers presented at The Second International Economic Forum on Reform, Transition and Growth, Budapest: Corvinus University of Budapest, pp. 8398, available at http://unipub.lib.uni-corvinus.hu/3744/ (accessed 20 May 2019).Google Scholar
Algan, Y., Guriev, S., Papaioannou, E., and Passari, E. (2017), ‘The European Trust Crisis and the Rise of Populism’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall.Google Scholar
Antal, A. (2017), “The Political Theories, Preconditions and Dangers of the Governing Populism in Hungary”. Czech Journal of Political Science/Politologicky Casopis, 24(1): pp. 520.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. (1958), ‘Competition and Democracy’, Journal of Law & Economics, 1(1): 105109.Google Scholar
Bermeo, N. (2016), ‘On Democratic Backsliding’, Journal of Democracy, 27(1): 519.Google Scholar
Boeri, T., Mishra, P., Papageorgiou, C. and Spilimbergo, A. (2018), ‘Economic Effects of Populism: A Dialogue between a Populist and an Economist’, AEA Papers and Proceedings, 108: 191195.Google Scholar
Bozóki, A. and Hegedűs, D. (2018), ‘An Externally Constrained Hybrid Regime: Hungary in the European Union’, Democratization, 25(7): 11731189.Google Scholar
Brubaker, R. (2017), ‘Between Nationalism and Civilizationism: The European Populist Moment in Comparative Perspective’, Ethnic and Racial Studies, 40(8): 11911226.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1986), Liberty, Market and State. Political Economy in the 1980s, New York, NY: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. and Tullock, G. (1962), The Calculus of Consent. Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Chang, H. (2002), Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical Perspective, London and New York: Anthem Press.Google Scholar
Chang, H. (2011), ‘Institutions and Economic Development: Theory, Policy and History’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 7(4): 473498. DOI: 10.1017/S1744137410000378.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1937), ‘The Nature of the Firm’, Economica (new series), 4(16): 386405.Google Scholar
Collier, R. B. (1999), Paths toward Democracy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Crain, M. W. (1977), ‘On the Structure and Stability of Political Markets’. Journal of Political Economy, 85(4): 829842.Google Scholar
Csigó, P. (2017), The Neopopular Bubble: Speculating on ‘the People’ in Late Modern Democracy, Budapest: Central European University Press.Google Scholar
De Vries, C. (2017), ‘The Cosmopolitan–Parochial Divide: Changing Patterns of Party and Electoral Competition in the Netherlands and Beyond’, Journal of European Public Policy, 25(11): 15411565.Google Scholar
Diamond, L. (2002), ‘Elections without Democracy: Thinking about Hybrid Regimes’, Journal of Democracy, 13(2): 2135.Google Scholar
Downs, A. (1957), An Economic Theory of Democracy, New York, NY: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Enyedi, Z. (2016), ‘Paternalist Populism and Illiberal Elitism in Central Europe’. Journal of Political Ideologies, 21(1): 925.Google Scholar
Epstein, D. L., Bates, R., Goldstone, J., Kristensen, I. and O'Halloran, S. (2006), ‘Democratic Transitions’, American Journal of Political Science, 50(3): 551569.Google Scholar
Fazekas, M. and Tóth, I. J. (2016), ‘From Corruption to State Capture. A New Analytical Framework with Empirical Applications from Hungary’, Political Research Quarterly, 69(2): 320334.Google Scholar
Finchelstein, F. (2014), ‘Returning Populism to History’, Constellations, 21(4): 467482.Google Scholar
Frye, T. (2002), ‘The Perils of Polarization: Economic Performance in the Postcommunist World’, World Politics, 54(3): 308337.Google Scholar
Furubotn, E. G. and Richter, R. (2005), Institutions and Economic Theory. The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics (2nd edn), Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Gidron, N. and Hall, P. A. (2017), ‘The Politics of Social Status: Economic and Cultural Roots of the Populist Right’, British Journal of Sociology, 68(S1): S57S84.Google Scholar
Guriev, S. (2018), ‘Economic Drivers of Populism’, AEA Paper and Proceedings, 108: 200203 (May 2018).Google Scholar
Gurov, B. and Zankina, E. (2013), ‘Populism and the Construction of Political Charisma: Post-transition Politics in Bulgaria’, Problems of Post Communism, 60(1): 317.Google Scholar
Győrffy, D. (2018), Trust and Crisis Management in the European Union. And Institutionalist Account of Success and Failure in Program Countries, Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Himmelfarb, G. (1966), ‘The Politics of Democracy: The English Reform Act of 1867’, Journal of British Studies, 6(1): 97138.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2017), ‘1688 and all that: property rights, the Glorious Revolution and the rise of British capitalism’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 13(1): 79107.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2019), ‘How Mythical Markets Mislead Analysis: An Institutionalist Critique of Market Universalism’. Socio-Economic Review, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Horkheimer, M. and Adorno, T. W. (2002 [1944]), Dialectic of Enlightenment. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Huntington, S. (1991), The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century, Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press.Google Scholar
Inglehart, R. and Norris, P. (2017), ‘Trump and the Populist Authoritarian Parties: The Silent Revolution in Reverse’. Perspectives on Politics, 15(2): 443454.Google Scholar
Jacobson, G. C. (2016), ‘Polarization, Gridlock, and Presidential Campaign Politics in 2016’, Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 667(1): 226246.Google Scholar
Kis, J. (2003), Constitutional Democracy, Budapest: Central European University Press.Google Scholar
Kornai, J. (2016), ‘The System Paradigm Revisited. Clarification and Additions in the Light of Experiences in the Post-Socialist Region’, Acta Oeconomica, 66(4): 547596.Google Scholar
Körösényi, A. (2013), ‘Political polarization and its consequences on democratic accountability’, Corvinus Journal of Sociology and Social Policy, 4(2): 330.Google Scholar
Krekó, P. and Enyedi, Zs. (2018), ‘Explaining Eastern Europe: Orbán's Laboratory of Illiberalism’. Journal of Democracy, 29(3): 3951.Google Scholar
Kriesi, H. and Pappas, T. S. (eds) (2015), European Populism in the Shadow of the Great Recession, Colchester, UK: ECPR Press.Google Scholar
Laclau, E. (2005), On Populist Reason, London and New York: Verso.Google Scholar
Levitsky, S. and Way, L. A. (2010), Competitive Authoritarianism. Hybrid Regimes after the Cold War, New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lipset, S. M. (1959), ‘Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy’, American Political Science Review, 53(1): 69105.Google Scholar
Magyar, B. (2016), Post-Communist Mafia State: The Case of Hungary, Budapest: CEU Press.Google Scholar
Martin, J. P. (2017), ‘Continuity or disruption? Changing elites and the emergence of cronyism after the great recession – The case of Hungary’, Corvinus Journal of Sociology and Social Policy, 8(3S): 255281.Google Scholar
Mather, R. D. and Jefferson, K. W. (2016), ‘The Authoritarian Voter? The Psychology and Values of Donald Trump and Bernie Sanders Support’, Journal of Scientific Psychology, available at www.socialautomaticity.net/images/JSP_May_2016.pdf (accessed 20 May 2019).Google Scholar
Meseznikov, G. and Gyárfásová, O. (2018), ‘Explaining Eastern Europe: Slovakia's Conflicting Camps’, Journal of Democracy, 29(3): 7890.Google Scholar
Mudde, C. (2004), ‘The Populist Zeitgeist’, Government and Opposition, 39(4): 541563.Google Scholar
Mudde, C. and Kaltwasser, C. R. (2017), Populism: A Very Short Introduction, Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Müller, J.-W. (2016), What is Populism? Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Mutz, D. C. (2018), ‘Status Threat, Not Economic Hardship, Explains the 2016 Presidential Vote’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 115(19): E4330E4339.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (2005), Understanding the Process of Economic Change, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. and Thomas, R. P. (1973), The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. and Weingast, B. R. (1989), ‘Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England’, Journal of Economic History, 49(4): 803832.Google Scholar
North, D. C., Wallis, J. J. and Weingast, B. R. (2009), Violence and Social Orders. A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1965), The Logic of Collective Action. Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, Cambridge, MA and London: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1993), ‘Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development’, American Political Science Review, 87(3): 567576.Google Scholar
Pakulski, J. and Waters, M. (1996), ‘The reshaping and dissolution of social class in advanced society’, Theory and Society, 25(5): 667691.Google Scholar
Pappas, T. S. and Aslanidis, P. (2015), ‘Greek Populism: A Political Drama in Five Acts’, in Kriesi, H. and Pappas, T. S. (eds), European Populism in the Shadow of the Great Recession, Colchester, UK: ECPR Press, pp. 181196.Google Scholar
Pehe, Jiri (2018), ‘Explaining Eastern Europe: Czech Democracy Under Pressure’, Journal of Democracy, 29(3): 6577.Google Scholar
Pirro, A. L. P. (2015), The Populist Radical Right in Central and Eastern Europe, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Przeworski, A. (2009), ‘Conquered or Granted? A History of Suffrage Extensions’, British Journal of Political Science, 39(2): 291321.Google Scholar
Przybylski, W. (2018), ‘Explaining Eastern Europe: Can Poland's Backsliding Be Stopped?Journal of Democracy, 29(3): 5264.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. (2018a), ‘Is Populism Necessarily Bad Economics?AEA Papers and Proceedings, 108: 196199.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. (2018b), ‘Populism and the Economics of Globalization’, Journal of International Business Policy, available at https://drodrik.scholar.harvard.edu/publications/populism-and-economics-globalization (accessed 20 May 2019).Google Scholar
Stanley, B. (2018), ‘A New Populist Divide? Correspondences of Supply and Demand in the 2015 Polish Parliamentary Elections’, East European Politics and Societies and Cultures, 20(10): 127.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. (1972), ‘Economic Competition and Political Competition’, Public Choice, 13: 91106.Google Scholar
Swank, D. and Betz, H-G. (2018), ‘Globalization, Institutions of Social Solidarity, and Radical Right-Wing Populism in Western Europe’, paper prepared for presentation at the 2018 Annual Meetings of the American Political Science Association, 30 August–2 September, Boston, MA.Google Scholar
Tóth, I. J. and Hajdu, M. (2018), ‘How does the Kleptocratic State Work in Hungary? A Research Note Based on Hungarian Public Procurement Data’, Budapest: Corruption Research Center Budapest (26 January 2018).Google Scholar
Tworzecki, H. (2019), ‘Poland: A Case of Top-Down Polarization’, Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 681(1): 97119.Google Scholar
Verbeek, B. and Zaslove, A. (2016), ‘Italy. A Case of Mutating Populism?Democratization, 23(2): 304323.Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1978 [1922]), Economy and Society, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1973), ‘Markets and Hierarchies: Some Elementary Considerations’, American Economic Review, 63(2): 316325.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York, NY: Free Press.Google Scholar
Zakaria, F. (2003), The Future of Freedom: Illiberal Democracy at Home and Abroad, New York, NY: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Zankina, Emilia (2016), ‘Theorizing the New Populism in Eastern Europe. A Look at Bulgaria’, Czech Journal of Political Science, 23(2): 182199.Google Scholar
Ziblatt, D. (2006), ‘How Did Europe Democratize?World Politics, 58(1): 311338.Google Scholar